全球税收公平:一个讨论

IF 2.2 3区 经济学 Q2 BUSINESS, FINANCE
Anne Brockmeyer, David Phillips
{"title":"全球税收公平:一个讨论","authors":"Anne Brockmeyer,&nbsp;David Phillips","doi":"10.1111/1475-5890.12342","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>In his paper ‘Globalisation, taxation and inequality’ in this issue, Gabriel Zucman argues that the current tax system is not appropriate for our times. In particular, the system heavily taxes labour and consumption and largely exempts capital and capital income from taxation. This tax structure is at odds with rising inequality and the high capital share of income for the rich.</p><p>Zucman acknowledges that the international community has made progress towards limiting international tax competition and evasion and avoidance, thereby facilitating the taxation of capital. This includes the automatic exchange of information about financial accounts and investments, and the OECD/G20-mediated ‘Pillar 2’ agreement on a global minimum tax on the profits of the largest multinational corporations. However, he argues that these recent global measures on tax avoidance and evasion do not go far enough.</p><p>First, Zucman advocates for an improvement and extension of the automatic exchange of information. The system should be expanded to other assets, most importantly real estate, and countries should more systematically deploy the information they receive through the automatic exchange of information in tax enforcement. In addition, the system should expand to cover more countries, especially developing countries, and have an inbuilt mechanism to ensure accurate reporting.</p><p>The case for expanding the exchange of information to real estate is clear: the ownership of foreign real estate is a form of wealth that is extremely concentrated at the very top and growing in importance since the automatic exchange of banking information. However, exchanging real-estate information internationally in a coherent manner could be hugely challenging. The exchange of banking information requires information from banks, which are typically thought of as well-organised and technically advanced institutions, that have long had to adhere to international norms, standards and IT systems. Records of real-estate ownership, in contrast, are maintained by local government agencies which typically have less capacity than central governments. Besides, in the context of decentralisation, the format of these local property registers and the manner in which they are maintained can vary widely across municipalities or states.</p><p>While it may seem worthwhile to start an exchange of information focused on high-income countries and/or large cities that are attractive targets for real-estate investment, investors are likely to respond by diverting some of their investment towards assets in locations not covered by the exchange of information. After all, Bomare and Le Guern Herry (<span>2022</span>) have shown investors respond to the exchange of banking information by shifting into real estate, so they are likely to also be able to shift across real assets in different locations. The exchange of information on real estate would also need to be combined with a ban on the use of shell companies, so that ownership information actually allows governments to identify the ultimate owners of properties. To be clear, we do not think the challenges we outline are good reasons to stick to the status quo of exchanging only banking information. If anything, the challenges involved in exchanging real-estate information mean that the international community should attempt to tackle them sooner rather than later. We are merely suggesting to be mindful of the length of the process required and cautious about the potential tax revenue gains.</p><p>In addition, Zucman highlights that it is important for countries to use the information they already have in their tax enforcement strategies. Several studies document evidence for increased tax compliance in response to the exchange of information.1 But how large the revenue gains can be once the information is fully exploited and investors’ responses have been realised, and how much lower-income countries in particular can gain, is still uncertain. The cost of using the information in enforcement is likely higher in lower-capacity administrations, hence limiting the potential net revenue gains for them.</p><p>In the second part of his paper, Zucman advocates for the design and adoption of modern wealth taxes. The predominant form of wealth taxation is currently the property tax, an ‘archaic and regressive wealth [tax]’. Zucman argues that countries should instead adopt a tax that covers all forms of wealth, at its market value, and that allows taxpayers to deduct debt. Conditional on having a wealth tax, it makes sense that the base for this tax includes all sources of wealth, at market value. However, it is worth pointing to the ongoing debate about the desirability of a wealth tax. The UK Wealth Tax Commission website2 and the <i>Fiscal Studies</i> symposium on the wealth tax3 provide a fantastic set of evidence papers on wealth tax design in theory and in practice, drawing on the experience of seven different countries. In particular, Adam and Miller (<span>2021</span>) discuss the economic arguments for and against a wealth tax. They conclude that the case for the one-off wealth tax is simple to make (because the opportunities for a one-off tax, implemented promptly, to distort economic activity are limited), but the case for an annual wealth tax is more difficult – though not impossible – to make based on economic theory (in part, because of the greater scope for economic distortions in response to a recurrent tax).</p><p>Zucman also argues that the (annual) wealth tax should have a progressive schedule with high exemption thresholds. He contrasts this progressive wealth tax with the ‘archaic’ property tax typically levied at a flat (or even regressive) rate. While the property tax may be archaic in many ways, it is worth keeping in mind that some jurisdictions have property taxes that – at least on paper, and for the tax base they cover – are mildly progressive. For instance, the property tax in Mexico City is progressive for high-end properties.4</p><p>While wealth taxes in the past had ceiling mechanisms, such that the wealth tax liability could not exceed a fraction of income, Zucman suggests that such mechanisms are not needed if the wealth tax is applied only above a very high exemption threshold. However, even very wealthy individuals may face constraints on their ability to pay an (increased) wealth tax if they have committed consumption and illiquid forms of wealth. If these constraints render them unable (or less willing) to pay, the success of the wealth tax and the political support for it could be undermined. It is hence important to think through the details of how to ensure liquidity to pay and hence the enforceability of a wealth tax.</p><p>Finally, Zucman argues that the use of pre-populated returns for the modern wealth tax could dramatically reduce the scope for tax evasion. While we think that pre-filling returns is a worthwhile policy to experiment with, we would caution that pre-filling does not necessarily increase tax payment.5 The effect of pre-populated returns may depend on how complete the government's information set is. If it is very incomplete (or more incomplete than taxpayers expect), pre-populated returns might create a reference point for taxpayer reporting that could be lower than what they would have otherwise voluntarily reported. In a way, a pre-filled return can reveal to the taxpayer how much (or how little) a government knows about the tax base. The automatic exchange of banking information, and hopefully of real-asset information in the future, will be crucial in helping to populate the returns.</p><p>A key tenet of Zucman's article is that ‘tax competition, tax evasion and tax avoidance are not laws of nature’, but instead ‘policy choices’, and that alternative choices are possible. This makes sense, but one might ask how technically and legislatively complicated it would be to implement these policy choices, and what political and economic costs they are associated with. For example, Zucman argues that financial assets are not necessarily highly elastic (internationally mobile) to tax rates, as ‘elasticities are not immutable parameters: they are affected by tax design’. While we agree with this view, which has also been documented in numerous studies,6 we think it is important to also take into account the trade-offs that arise when designing policy with the aim that ‘elasticities can be reduced, possibly to very low levels’. A welfare-maximising policymaker would adopt such a policy if the benefits from reduced tax evasion and avoidance, and hence increased public spending, outweigh potentially adverse real effects. It is possible that these real effects are small, but it may not necessarily always be optimal to drive elasticities to ‘very low levels’.</p><p>Before concluding, it is worth briefly touching upon Zucman's comment that the global minimum corporate income tax is a ‘first and important’ step towards the international regulation of globalisation and the setting of tax rates (as opposed to simply tax bases). We agree that the commitment to a global minimum tax is an exciting achievement. But it remains to be seen how significant the revenue gains are, and to what extent they benefit low- and middle-income countries.</p><p>As discussed in Perry (<span>2023</span>) in a recent <i>Fiscal Studies</i> symposium on the global minimum tax, many low- and middle-income countries (LMICs) have structured their economic development and investment promotion strategies around tax incentives and exemptions for multinational corporations and enterprises (MNEs). Honduras's development model is one example, as discussed in the recent World Bank conference and in a TaxDev blogpost.7 A concern with the early proposal for a global minimum tax (GMT) was that it would prevent competition on real economic location choices. In response to this, the current version of the global minimum corporate income tax allows ‘carve-outs’, i.e. reductions from profits based on payroll costs and tangible (capital) assets. The countries where MNEs within scope of the GMT are headquartered have the first right to impose a top-up tax on affiliates of these MNEs that have an effective tax rate below the global minimum. This means that LMICs that currently rely on tax incentives to attract investment may lose out if they take no action to reform their tax system: if they host the affiliates but not the headquarters of MNEs in scope, they would be less likely to attract investment and would not benefit from the top-up tax payments. Countries are hence working to adapt their development strategies and tax systems. Planned reforms in Honduras under its ‘Tax Justice Bill’, for example, partially replace profit-based incentives with double deductions for payroll costs for permanent workers and accelerated depreciation for capital investment to more closely align its tax incentives regime with the structure of the global minimum tax. Countries will also need to consider whether to implement a qualified domestic minimum top-up tax (QDMTT). The aim of a QDMTT is to ensure that countries that host MNE affiliates, rather than the countries where the parent MNE is located, receive the top-up tax payments.</p><p>Zucman's reference to the global minimum corporate income tax being a ‘first step’ also begs the question as to whether there is scope for international coordination on tax rates applied to other tax bases. In the case of wealth, our view is that the greater diversity of opinion on whether wealth should be taxed on an annual basis at all, and major differences in wealth distributions across countries, will preclude the forging of a consensus on a minimum tax rate.</p><p>None of the above is to question the importance of the issues and debates that are raised by Zucman. The recent World Bank conference on global tax equity, and the papers from participating policymakers in this symposium, illustrate the action a growing number of countries are taking, and the challenges and opportunities they are facing, as they seek to increase the contribution of MNEs and high-net-worth individuals to revenues, and tackle tax avoidance and evasion. An increased focus on international cooperation, both on high-level policy (such as the global minimum corporate income tax) and administration and enforcement activities (such as automatic exchange of information) may be the foundation for further change. However, with regard to some of the more far-reaching proposals in Zucman's paper, our view is that more research, and particularly more empirical evidence on quantifying the key trade-offs involved, is still needed in order to allow policy to be as informed as possible about the full potential consequences on behaviour and, in turn, revenues.</p>","PeriodicalId":51602,"journal":{"name":"Fiscal Studies","volume":"44 3","pages":"237-241"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2000,"publicationDate":"2023-09-13","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/1475-5890.12342","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Tax equity around the world: a discussion\",\"authors\":\"Anne Brockmeyer,&nbsp;David Phillips\",\"doi\":\"10.1111/1475-5890.12342\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p>In his paper ‘Globalisation, taxation and inequality’ in this issue, Gabriel Zucman argues that the current tax system is not appropriate for our times. In particular, the system heavily taxes labour and consumption and largely exempts capital and capital income from taxation. This tax structure is at odds with rising inequality and the high capital share of income for the rich.</p><p>Zucman acknowledges that the international community has made progress towards limiting international tax competition and evasion and avoidance, thereby facilitating the taxation of capital. This includes the automatic exchange of information about financial accounts and investments, and the OECD/G20-mediated ‘Pillar 2’ agreement on a global minimum tax on the profits of the largest multinational corporations. However, he argues that these recent global measures on tax avoidance and evasion do not go far enough.</p><p>First, Zucman advocates for an improvement and extension of the automatic exchange of information. The system should be expanded to other assets, most importantly real estate, and countries should more systematically deploy the information they receive through the automatic exchange of information in tax enforcement. In addition, the system should expand to cover more countries, especially developing countries, and have an inbuilt mechanism to ensure accurate reporting.</p><p>The case for expanding the exchange of information to real estate is clear: the ownership of foreign real estate is a form of wealth that is extremely concentrated at the very top and growing in importance since the automatic exchange of banking information. However, exchanging real-estate information internationally in a coherent manner could be hugely challenging. The exchange of banking information requires information from banks, which are typically thought of as well-organised and technically advanced institutions, that have long had to adhere to international norms, standards and IT systems. Records of real-estate ownership, in contrast, are maintained by local government agencies which typically have less capacity than central governments. Besides, in the context of decentralisation, the format of these local property registers and the manner in which they are maintained can vary widely across municipalities or states.</p><p>While it may seem worthwhile to start an exchange of information focused on high-income countries and/or large cities that are attractive targets for real-estate investment, investors are likely to respond by diverting some of their investment towards assets in locations not covered by the exchange of information. After all, Bomare and Le Guern Herry (<span>2022</span>) have shown investors respond to the exchange of banking information by shifting into real estate, so they are likely to also be able to shift across real assets in different locations. The exchange of information on real estate would also need to be combined with a ban on the use of shell companies, so that ownership information actually allows governments to identify the ultimate owners of properties. To be clear, we do not think the challenges we outline are good reasons to stick to the status quo of exchanging only banking information. If anything, the challenges involved in exchanging real-estate information mean that the international community should attempt to tackle them sooner rather than later. We are merely suggesting to be mindful of the length of the process required and cautious about the potential tax revenue gains.</p><p>In addition, Zucman highlights that it is important for countries to use the information they already have in their tax enforcement strategies. Several studies document evidence for increased tax compliance in response to the exchange of information.1 But how large the revenue gains can be once the information is fully exploited and investors’ responses have been realised, and how much lower-income countries in particular can gain, is still uncertain. The cost of using the information in enforcement is likely higher in lower-capacity administrations, hence limiting the potential net revenue gains for them.</p><p>In the second part of his paper, Zucman advocates for the design and adoption of modern wealth taxes. The predominant form of wealth taxation is currently the property tax, an ‘archaic and regressive wealth [tax]’. Zucman argues that countries should instead adopt a tax that covers all forms of wealth, at its market value, and that allows taxpayers to deduct debt. Conditional on having a wealth tax, it makes sense that the base for this tax includes all sources of wealth, at market value. However, it is worth pointing to the ongoing debate about the desirability of a wealth tax. The UK Wealth Tax Commission website2 and the <i>Fiscal Studies</i> symposium on the wealth tax3 provide a fantastic set of evidence papers on wealth tax design in theory and in practice, drawing on the experience of seven different countries. In particular, Adam and Miller (<span>2021</span>) discuss the economic arguments for and against a wealth tax. They conclude that the case for the one-off wealth tax is simple to make (because the opportunities for a one-off tax, implemented promptly, to distort economic activity are limited), but the case for an annual wealth tax is more difficult – though not impossible – to make based on economic theory (in part, because of the greater scope for economic distortions in response to a recurrent tax).</p><p>Zucman also argues that the (annual) wealth tax should have a progressive schedule with high exemption thresholds. He contrasts this progressive wealth tax with the ‘archaic’ property tax typically levied at a flat (or even regressive) rate. While the property tax may be archaic in many ways, it is worth keeping in mind that some jurisdictions have property taxes that – at least on paper, and for the tax base they cover – are mildly progressive. For instance, the property tax in Mexico City is progressive for high-end properties.4</p><p>While wealth taxes in the past had ceiling mechanisms, such that the wealth tax liability could not exceed a fraction of income, Zucman suggests that such mechanisms are not needed if the wealth tax is applied only above a very high exemption threshold. However, even very wealthy individuals may face constraints on their ability to pay an (increased) wealth tax if they have committed consumption and illiquid forms of wealth. If these constraints render them unable (or less willing) to pay, the success of the wealth tax and the political support for it could be undermined. It is hence important to think through the details of how to ensure liquidity to pay and hence the enforceability of a wealth tax.</p><p>Finally, Zucman argues that the use of pre-populated returns for the modern wealth tax could dramatically reduce the scope for tax evasion. While we think that pre-filling returns is a worthwhile policy to experiment with, we would caution that pre-filling does not necessarily increase tax payment.5 The effect of pre-populated returns may depend on how complete the government's information set is. If it is very incomplete (or more incomplete than taxpayers expect), pre-populated returns might create a reference point for taxpayer reporting that could be lower than what they would have otherwise voluntarily reported. In a way, a pre-filled return can reveal to the taxpayer how much (or how little) a government knows about the tax base. The automatic exchange of banking information, and hopefully of real-asset information in the future, will be crucial in helping to populate the returns.</p><p>A key tenet of Zucman's article is that ‘tax competition, tax evasion and tax avoidance are not laws of nature’, but instead ‘policy choices’, and that alternative choices are possible. This makes sense, but one might ask how technically and legislatively complicated it would be to implement these policy choices, and what political and economic costs they are associated with. For example, Zucman argues that financial assets are not necessarily highly elastic (internationally mobile) to tax rates, as ‘elasticities are not immutable parameters: they are affected by tax design’. While we agree with this view, which has also been documented in numerous studies,6 we think it is important to also take into account the trade-offs that arise when designing policy with the aim that ‘elasticities can be reduced, possibly to very low levels’. A welfare-maximising policymaker would adopt such a policy if the benefits from reduced tax evasion and avoidance, and hence increased public spending, outweigh potentially adverse real effects. It is possible that these real effects are small, but it may not necessarily always be optimal to drive elasticities to ‘very low levels’.</p><p>Before concluding, it is worth briefly touching upon Zucman's comment that the global minimum corporate income tax is a ‘first and important’ step towards the international regulation of globalisation and the setting of tax rates (as opposed to simply tax bases). We agree that the commitment to a global minimum tax is an exciting achievement. But it remains to be seen how significant the revenue gains are, and to what extent they benefit low- and middle-income countries.</p><p>As discussed in Perry (<span>2023</span>) in a recent <i>Fiscal Studies</i> symposium on the global minimum tax, many low- and middle-income countries (LMICs) have structured their economic development and investment promotion strategies around tax incentives and exemptions for multinational corporations and enterprises (MNEs). Honduras's development model is one example, as discussed in the recent World Bank conference and in a TaxDev blogpost.7 A concern with the early proposal for a global minimum tax (GMT) was that it would prevent competition on real economic location choices. In response to this, the current version of the global minimum corporate income tax allows ‘carve-outs’, i.e. reductions from profits based on payroll costs and tangible (capital) assets. The countries where MNEs within scope of the GMT are headquartered have the first right to impose a top-up tax on affiliates of these MNEs that have an effective tax rate below the global minimum. This means that LMICs that currently rely on tax incentives to attract investment may lose out if they take no action to reform their tax system: if they host the affiliates but not the headquarters of MNEs in scope, they would be less likely to attract investment and would not benefit from the top-up tax payments. Countries are hence working to adapt their development strategies and tax systems. Planned reforms in Honduras under its ‘Tax Justice Bill’, for example, partially replace profit-based incentives with double deductions for payroll costs for permanent workers and accelerated depreciation for capital investment to more closely align its tax incentives regime with the structure of the global minimum tax. Countries will also need to consider whether to implement a qualified domestic minimum top-up tax (QDMTT). The aim of a QDMTT is to ensure that countries that host MNE affiliates, rather than the countries where the parent MNE is located, receive the top-up tax payments.</p><p>Zucman's reference to the global minimum corporate income tax being a ‘first step’ also begs the question as to whether there is scope for international coordination on tax rates applied to other tax bases. In the case of wealth, our view is that the greater diversity of opinion on whether wealth should be taxed on an annual basis at all, and major differences in wealth distributions across countries, will preclude the forging of a consensus on a minimum tax rate.</p><p>None of the above is to question the importance of the issues and debates that are raised by Zucman. The recent World Bank conference on global tax equity, and the papers from participating policymakers in this symposium, illustrate the action a growing number of countries are taking, and the challenges and opportunities they are facing, as they seek to increase the contribution of MNEs and high-net-worth individuals to revenues, and tackle tax avoidance and evasion. An increased focus on international cooperation, both on high-level policy (such as the global minimum corporate income tax) and administration and enforcement activities (such as automatic exchange of information) may be the foundation for further change. However, with regard to some of the more far-reaching proposals in Zucman's paper, our view is that more research, and particularly more empirical evidence on quantifying the key trade-offs involved, is still needed in order to allow policy to be as informed as possible about the full potential consequences on behaviour and, in turn, revenues.</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":51602,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Fiscal Studies\",\"volume\":\"44 3\",\"pages\":\"237-241\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":2.2000,\"publicationDate\":\"2023-09-13\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/1475-5890.12342\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Fiscal Studies\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"96\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/1475-5890.12342\",\"RegionNum\":3,\"RegionCategory\":\"经济学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q2\",\"JCRName\":\"BUSINESS, FINANCE\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Fiscal Studies","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/1475-5890.12342","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"BUSINESS, FINANCE","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

Gabriel Zucman在其关于这一问题的论文《全球化、税收和不平等》中认为,目前的税收制度不适合我们的时代。特别是,该制度对劳动力和消费征收重税,并在很大程度上免除资本和资本收入的税收。这种税收结构与日益加剧的不平等和富人在收入中的高资本份额不一致。祖克曼承认,国际社会在限制国际税收竞争和逃税避税方面取得了进展,从而为资本征税提供了便利。这包括自动交换有关金融账户和投资的信息,以及经合组织/二十国集团调解的关于对最大跨国公司利润征收全球最低税的“支柱2”协议。然而,他认为,最近这些针对避税和逃税的全球措施还不够。首先,Zucman主张改进和扩展信息的自动交换。该系统应扩展到其他资产,最重要的是房地产,各国应更系统地部署通过税务执法信息自动交换获得的信息。此外,该系统应扩大到覆盖更多国家,特别是发展中国家,并有一个确保准确报告的内置机制。将信息交流扩大到房地产的理由很清楚:外国房地产的所有权是一种财富形式,这种财富极为集中在最高层,自银行信息自动交换以来,其重要性不断增加。然而,以连贯的方式在国际上交换房地产信息可能具有巨大的挑战性。银行信息的交换需要来自银行的信息,这些银行通常被认为是组织良好、技术先进的机构,长期以来必须遵守国际规范、标准和IT系统。相比之下,房地产所有权记录由地方政府机构保存,这些机构的能力通常低于中央政府。此外,在权力下放的背景下,这些地方财产登记册的格式和维护方式可能因市镇或州而异。尽管开始以高收入国家和/或大城市为重点进行信息交流似乎是值得的,但投资者可能会将部分投资转向信息交流未涵盖的地区的资产。毕竟,Bomare和Le Guern Herry(2022)已经表明,投资者对银行信息交换的反应是转向房地产,因此他们也可能能够在不同地点的房地产之间进行转移。房地产信息交换还需要与禁止使用空壳公司相结合,这样所有权信息才能真正让政府确定房产的最终所有者。需要明确的是,我们不认为我们概述的挑战是坚持只交换银行信息的现状的充分理由。如果说有什么不同的话,那就是房地产信息交流所涉及的挑战意味着国际社会应该尽早解决这些问题。我们只是建议注意所需程序的长度,并对潜在的税收收益持谨慎态度。此外,Zucman强调,各国在税收执法战略中使用现有信息很重要。几项研究记录了信息交流提高税收合规性的证据。1但一旦信息被充分利用,投资者的反应得以实现,收入收益会有多大,尤其是低收入国家能获得多少收益,仍不确定。在能力较低的行政部门,在执法中使用信息的成本可能更高,因此限制了他们潜在的净收入收益。在论文的第二部分,祖克曼主张设计和采用现代财富税。目前,财富税的主要形式是财产税,这是一种“过时且累退的财富[税]”。祖克曼认为,各国应该采取一种以市场价值涵盖所有形式财富的税收,并允许纳税人扣除债务。以征收财富税为条件,该税的基础包括按市场价值计算的所有财富来源,这是有道理的。然而,值得指出的是,关于财富税可取性的争论仍在继续。英国财富税委员会网站2和财富税财政研究研讨会3借鉴了七个不同国家的经验,为财富税的理论和实践设计提供了一套极好的证据文件。 特别是,Adam和Miller(2021)讨论了支持和反对财富税的经济论点。他们得出的结论是,一次性财富税的理由很简单(因为及时实施一次性财富税扭曲经济活动的机会有限),但根据经济理论,年度财富税的情况更难——尽管并非不可能——(部分原因是,因应经常性税收,经济扭曲的范围更大)。祖克曼还认为,(年度)财富税应该有一个累进的时间表,有很高的免税门槛。他将这种累进财富税与通常以统一(甚至递减)税率征收的“过时”财产税进行了对比。虽然财产税在很多方面可能已经过时,但值得记住的是,一些司法管辖区的财产税——至少在纸面上,就其涵盖的税基而言——是温和的累进税。例如,墨西哥城的房产税对高端房产是累进的。4虽然过去的财富税有上限机制,因此财富税负债不能超过收入的一小部分,但Zucman建议,如果财富税仅在非常高的免税门槛以上适用,就不需要这种机制。然而,即使是非常富有的个人,如果他们有消费和非流动形式的财富,他们缴纳(增加的)财富税的能力也可能受到限制。如果这些限制使他们无法(或不太愿意)支付,财富税的成功及其政治支持可能会受到损害。因此,重要的是要仔细考虑如何确保支付的流动性,从而确保财富税的可执行性。最后,Zucman认为,在现代财富税中使用预先填充的申报表可以大大减少逃税的范围。虽然我们认为预先填写报税表是一项值得尝试的政策,但我们要提醒,预先填写报税单并不一定会增加纳税额。5预先填写的报税表的效果可能取决于政府信息集的完整程度。如果信息集非常不完整(或比纳税人预期的更不完整),预先填充的申报表可能会为纳税人的报告创建一个参考点,该参考点可能低于他们原本自愿报告的水平。在某种程度上,预先填写的纳税申报表可以向纳税人揭示政府对税基的了解程度。银行信息的自动交换,以及未来真实资产信息的自动交流,将对帮助填充回报至关重要。Zucman文章的一个关键原则是,“税收竞争、逃税和避税不是自然规律”,而是“政策选择”,替代选择是可能的。这是有道理的,但人们可能会问,实施这些政策选择在技术和立法上会有多复杂,以及它们与什么样的政治和经济成本有关。例如,Zucman认为,金融资产对税率不一定具有高度弹性(国际流动性),因为“弹性不是一成不变的参数:它们受到税收设计的影响”。虽然我们同意这一观点,这一观点也在许多研究中得到了证明,6但我们认为,在设计旨在“弹性可以降低,可能降低到非常低的水平”的政策时,也必须考虑到出现的权衡。如果减少逃税和避税,从而增加公共支出的好处超过潜在的不利实际影响,那么福利最大化的决策者就会采取这样的政策。这些实际影响可能很小,但将弹性驱动到“非常低的水平”并不一定总是最佳的。在结束之前,值得简要谈谈Zucman的评论,即全球最低企业所得税是朝着全球化和税率设定(而不是简单的税基)的国际监管迈出的“第一步,也是重要的一步”。我们同意,对全球最低税收的承诺是一项令人兴奋的成就。但收入收益有多大,以及在多大程度上惠及中低收入国家,还有待观察。正如Perry(2023)在最近一次关于全球最低税收的财政研究研讨会上所讨论的那样,许多中低收入国家围绕跨国公司和企业的税收优惠和豁免制定了经济发展和投资促进战略。洪都拉斯的发展模式就是一个例子,正如最近的世界银行会议和TaxDev博客文章所讨论的那样。7对早期提出的全球最低税(GMT)的担忧是,这将阻止在实际经济地点选择上的竞争。对此,当前版本的全球最低企业所得税允许“例外”,即。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Tax equity around the world: a discussion

In his paper ‘Globalisation, taxation and inequality’ in this issue, Gabriel Zucman argues that the current tax system is not appropriate for our times. In particular, the system heavily taxes labour and consumption and largely exempts capital and capital income from taxation. This tax structure is at odds with rising inequality and the high capital share of income for the rich.

Zucman acknowledges that the international community has made progress towards limiting international tax competition and evasion and avoidance, thereby facilitating the taxation of capital. This includes the automatic exchange of information about financial accounts and investments, and the OECD/G20-mediated ‘Pillar 2’ agreement on a global minimum tax on the profits of the largest multinational corporations. However, he argues that these recent global measures on tax avoidance and evasion do not go far enough.

First, Zucman advocates for an improvement and extension of the automatic exchange of information. The system should be expanded to other assets, most importantly real estate, and countries should more systematically deploy the information they receive through the automatic exchange of information in tax enforcement. In addition, the system should expand to cover more countries, especially developing countries, and have an inbuilt mechanism to ensure accurate reporting.

The case for expanding the exchange of information to real estate is clear: the ownership of foreign real estate is a form of wealth that is extremely concentrated at the very top and growing in importance since the automatic exchange of banking information. However, exchanging real-estate information internationally in a coherent manner could be hugely challenging. The exchange of banking information requires information from banks, which are typically thought of as well-organised and technically advanced institutions, that have long had to adhere to international norms, standards and IT systems. Records of real-estate ownership, in contrast, are maintained by local government agencies which typically have less capacity than central governments. Besides, in the context of decentralisation, the format of these local property registers and the manner in which they are maintained can vary widely across municipalities or states.

While it may seem worthwhile to start an exchange of information focused on high-income countries and/or large cities that are attractive targets for real-estate investment, investors are likely to respond by diverting some of their investment towards assets in locations not covered by the exchange of information. After all, Bomare and Le Guern Herry (2022) have shown investors respond to the exchange of banking information by shifting into real estate, so they are likely to also be able to shift across real assets in different locations. The exchange of information on real estate would also need to be combined with a ban on the use of shell companies, so that ownership information actually allows governments to identify the ultimate owners of properties. To be clear, we do not think the challenges we outline are good reasons to stick to the status quo of exchanging only banking information. If anything, the challenges involved in exchanging real-estate information mean that the international community should attempt to tackle them sooner rather than later. We are merely suggesting to be mindful of the length of the process required and cautious about the potential tax revenue gains.

In addition, Zucman highlights that it is important for countries to use the information they already have in their tax enforcement strategies. Several studies document evidence for increased tax compliance in response to the exchange of information.1 But how large the revenue gains can be once the information is fully exploited and investors’ responses have been realised, and how much lower-income countries in particular can gain, is still uncertain. The cost of using the information in enforcement is likely higher in lower-capacity administrations, hence limiting the potential net revenue gains for them.

In the second part of his paper, Zucman advocates for the design and adoption of modern wealth taxes. The predominant form of wealth taxation is currently the property tax, an ‘archaic and regressive wealth [tax]’. Zucman argues that countries should instead adopt a tax that covers all forms of wealth, at its market value, and that allows taxpayers to deduct debt. Conditional on having a wealth tax, it makes sense that the base for this tax includes all sources of wealth, at market value. However, it is worth pointing to the ongoing debate about the desirability of a wealth tax. The UK Wealth Tax Commission website2 and the Fiscal Studies symposium on the wealth tax3 provide a fantastic set of evidence papers on wealth tax design in theory and in practice, drawing on the experience of seven different countries. In particular, Adam and Miller (2021) discuss the economic arguments for and against a wealth tax. They conclude that the case for the one-off wealth tax is simple to make (because the opportunities for a one-off tax, implemented promptly, to distort economic activity are limited), but the case for an annual wealth tax is more difficult – though not impossible – to make based on economic theory (in part, because of the greater scope for economic distortions in response to a recurrent tax).

Zucman also argues that the (annual) wealth tax should have a progressive schedule with high exemption thresholds. He contrasts this progressive wealth tax with the ‘archaic’ property tax typically levied at a flat (or even regressive) rate. While the property tax may be archaic in many ways, it is worth keeping in mind that some jurisdictions have property taxes that – at least on paper, and for the tax base they cover – are mildly progressive. For instance, the property tax in Mexico City is progressive for high-end properties.4

While wealth taxes in the past had ceiling mechanisms, such that the wealth tax liability could not exceed a fraction of income, Zucman suggests that such mechanisms are not needed if the wealth tax is applied only above a very high exemption threshold. However, even very wealthy individuals may face constraints on their ability to pay an (increased) wealth tax if they have committed consumption and illiquid forms of wealth. If these constraints render them unable (or less willing) to pay, the success of the wealth tax and the political support for it could be undermined. It is hence important to think through the details of how to ensure liquidity to pay and hence the enforceability of a wealth tax.

Finally, Zucman argues that the use of pre-populated returns for the modern wealth tax could dramatically reduce the scope for tax evasion. While we think that pre-filling returns is a worthwhile policy to experiment with, we would caution that pre-filling does not necessarily increase tax payment.5 The effect of pre-populated returns may depend on how complete the government's information set is. If it is very incomplete (or more incomplete than taxpayers expect), pre-populated returns might create a reference point for taxpayer reporting that could be lower than what they would have otherwise voluntarily reported. In a way, a pre-filled return can reveal to the taxpayer how much (or how little) a government knows about the tax base. The automatic exchange of banking information, and hopefully of real-asset information in the future, will be crucial in helping to populate the returns.

A key tenet of Zucman's article is that ‘tax competition, tax evasion and tax avoidance are not laws of nature’, but instead ‘policy choices’, and that alternative choices are possible. This makes sense, but one might ask how technically and legislatively complicated it would be to implement these policy choices, and what political and economic costs they are associated with. For example, Zucman argues that financial assets are not necessarily highly elastic (internationally mobile) to tax rates, as ‘elasticities are not immutable parameters: they are affected by tax design’. While we agree with this view, which has also been documented in numerous studies,6 we think it is important to also take into account the trade-offs that arise when designing policy with the aim that ‘elasticities can be reduced, possibly to very low levels’. A welfare-maximising policymaker would adopt such a policy if the benefits from reduced tax evasion and avoidance, and hence increased public spending, outweigh potentially adverse real effects. It is possible that these real effects are small, but it may not necessarily always be optimal to drive elasticities to ‘very low levels’.

Before concluding, it is worth briefly touching upon Zucman's comment that the global minimum corporate income tax is a ‘first and important’ step towards the international regulation of globalisation and the setting of tax rates (as opposed to simply tax bases). We agree that the commitment to a global minimum tax is an exciting achievement. But it remains to be seen how significant the revenue gains are, and to what extent they benefit low- and middle-income countries.

As discussed in Perry (2023) in a recent Fiscal Studies symposium on the global minimum tax, many low- and middle-income countries (LMICs) have structured their economic development and investment promotion strategies around tax incentives and exemptions for multinational corporations and enterprises (MNEs). Honduras's development model is one example, as discussed in the recent World Bank conference and in a TaxDev blogpost.7 A concern with the early proposal for a global minimum tax (GMT) was that it would prevent competition on real economic location choices. In response to this, the current version of the global minimum corporate income tax allows ‘carve-outs’, i.e. reductions from profits based on payroll costs and tangible (capital) assets. The countries where MNEs within scope of the GMT are headquartered have the first right to impose a top-up tax on affiliates of these MNEs that have an effective tax rate below the global minimum. This means that LMICs that currently rely on tax incentives to attract investment may lose out if they take no action to reform their tax system: if they host the affiliates but not the headquarters of MNEs in scope, they would be less likely to attract investment and would not benefit from the top-up tax payments. Countries are hence working to adapt their development strategies and tax systems. Planned reforms in Honduras under its ‘Tax Justice Bill’, for example, partially replace profit-based incentives with double deductions for payroll costs for permanent workers and accelerated depreciation for capital investment to more closely align its tax incentives regime with the structure of the global minimum tax. Countries will also need to consider whether to implement a qualified domestic minimum top-up tax (QDMTT). The aim of a QDMTT is to ensure that countries that host MNE affiliates, rather than the countries where the parent MNE is located, receive the top-up tax payments.

Zucman's reference to the global minimum corporate income tax being a ‘first step’ also begs the question as to whether there is scope for international coordination on tax rates applied to other tax bases. In the case of wealth, our view is that the greater diversity of opinion on whether wealth should be taxed on an annual basis at all, and major differences in wealth distributions across countries, will preclude the forging of a consensus on a minimum tax rate.

None of the above is to question the importance of the issues and debates that are raised by Zucman. The recent World Bank conference on global tax equity, and the papers from participating policymakers in this symposium, illustrate the action a growing number of countries are taking, and the challenges and opportunities they are facing, as they seek to increase the contribution of MNEs and high-net-worth individuals to revenues, and tackle tax avoidance and evasion. An increased focus on international cooperation, both on high-level policy (such as the global minimum corporate income tax) and administration and enforcement activities (such as automatic exchange of information) may be the foundation for further change. However, with regard to some of the more far-reaching proposals in Zucman's paper, our view is that more research, and particularly more empirical evidence on quantifying the key trade-offs involved, is still needed in order to allow policy to be as informed as possible about the full potential consequences on behaviour and, in turn, revenues.

求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
Fiscal Studies
Fiscal Studies Multiple-
CiteScore
13.50
自引率
1.40%
发文量
18
期刊介绍: The Institute for Fiscal Studies publishes the journal Fiscal Studies, which serves as a bridge between academic research and policy. This esteemed journal, established in 1979, has gained global recognition for its publication of high-quality and original research papers. The articles, authored by prominent academics, policymakers, and practitioners, are presented in an accessible format, ensuring a broad international readership.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信