{"title":"金融专业人士与独资思想的形成","authors":"Atiba Pertilla","doi":"10.1111/hic3.12717","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>This review essay on economist Thomas Piketty's <i>Capital and Ideology</i> argues that the role of financial professionals as ideologues is a necessary yet missing component of Piketty's analysis. Using the history of capitalism in the United States as a connective thread, the essay synthesizes examples from a broad array of studies to trace the role of financial professionals from the counting houses of early republic New Orleans and New York through the professionalization of stockbrokers and investment bankers in the late-19th century Gilded Age to modern-day Wall Street white-collar workers. Throughout U.S. history financial professionals and their allied media institutions have been ubiquitous and essential advocates for a “proprietarian” ideology which prioritizes the sanctity of property rights over ameliorating inequality.</p><p>Thomas Piketty's <i>Capital and Ideology</i> offers a sprawling history of how conditions of economic inequality advance or constrain human progress. Casting aside arguments that economic growth lifts all boats, Piketty urges looking instead to political and ideological structures for a robust explanation of social development. The book's 17 chapters seek to establish a unified theory of social evolution at the nation-state level, developing a chronology and a terminology that proceeds from “ternary” systems of nobles, clerics, and peasants (a model Piketty fits to medieval and early modern societies from Western Europe to Japan) through the bourgeois capitalist regimes established in the eighteenth century and the social-democratic societies that arose in the wake of World War I, finally ending in a present-day surge in oligarchic populism that decries inequality while doing little, he argues, to reverse it. Particularly tragic, in Piketty's eyes, is that in recent history this shift has been accompanied by a “distinctive” meritocratic ideology which “blame[s] the poor for their poverty.” (Piketty, <span>2020</span>, p. 710) Given Piketty's sociopolitical goals, <i>Capital and Ideology</i>'s political vision suffers from often being free of ideologues. I argue that we might fill this gap by examining financial sector professionals as critical actors in establishing and defending “inequality regimes” (as Piketty terms them) throughout the past two centuries. Tracing the ideological work of financial professionals' in the United States from the early republic forward, I suggest we might discover fruitful continuities linking the development of new systems of capitalist knowledge in the Age of Revolutions with the social role of the present-day meritocracy.<sup>1</sup></p><p>While Piketty's earlier book <i>Capital in the Twenty-First Century</i> was built on the argument that unregulated capitalism “automatically generates arbitrary and unsustainable inequalities,” (Piketty, <span>2014</span>, p. 1) the villain of the sequel is not capitalism per se but “proprietarian” ideology, a way of making sense of the world and shaping a given political regime to justify these inequalities whose first premise is “the sacralization of property rights,” as explained in the new book's brief glossary (1044). The first section of the book traces a long tradition of political arguments in many parts of the world devoted to refuting the idea that elites held unique responsibilities to the polity as a whole under the social contract. The third section of <i>Capital and Ideology</i> describes the “Great Transformation” which saw most of the North Atlantic democracies abandon the nineteenth-century liberal variation in the face of World War I and the Great Depression, followed by the steady return of inequality under neoliberal auspices from the 1970s onward. In the present day, Piketty is anxious about a possible move to a more malevolent “market nativism” which exploits xenophobia to dampen the appeal of redistributionist policy while entrenching tax systems which privilege existing wealth. In the final chapters, Piketty seeks to argue that only “exceptional taxes on private capital” can fund the reinvigoration of social democracy and ensure progress (886–891).</p><p>Piketty, in other words, is interested in capital—whether vested in control over economic outputs through ownership rights or represented in the (usually monetized) returns on those outputs, rather than capitalism—the systems of extraction, negotiation, coercion, and cooperation that produce those returns and ownership structures (Levy, <span>2017</span>). Piketty devotes particular attention to French history to examine the intertwining of income inequality and the defense of property rights. In the fourth chapter, he offers a counterintuitive argument that the French Revolution, notwithstanding the toppling of the monarchy and the landowning nobility, entrenched property relationships more firmly than they had ever been before by severing ownership (particularly of land) from civil authority, enhancing the legitimacy of “modern property rights.” (105) The removal of “privileges and charges” and “establish[ing] equal access to different occupations and to property rights” were considered sufficient to ensure the desired goal of an egalitarian society (118). Changes in the sources of wealth of the country's largest fortunes, and the absence of political pressure to redistribute the country's prosperity through the tax code, however, meant that by the late nineteenth century income inequality had already risen to levels like those of the pre-revolutionary era. Nonetheless it was important for Third Republic politicians to insist that France was “a country of ‘smallholders’” (139) yet Piketty's detailed quantitative studies of income and property show the distribution of wealth barely budged for the poorest 90% of the country from 1780 until 1910, and that their cumulative total rarely reached above 50% of income or 20% of property (130–131).</p><p>In shifting focus from capitalism to property, Piketty seeks to trace the longer history of the ideological argument that the social conditions capitalism creates can be justified by the resulting distribution of property. Piketty describes ideology as “attempts… to impose meaning” from above. To study ideology, he focuses on formal political speech, found in party platforms and governmental debates; he also turns to “theorists and political actors to see how inequalities were justified.” (14) His attention is drawn most, as in the 11th chapter (the book's longest), to those political parties which were in the vanguard of creating the “incomplete equality” regimes that triumphed in Western democracies in the mid-twentieth century, from the German Social Democratic Party to the Democratic Party in the United States to the workers' parties of Scandinavia (486–508). Piketty is clearly more sympathetic to these political groups, and seems fascinated, for example, by the transformations that have taken the Democrats from a party dominated by southern slaveholders to the vehicle for supplanting the inequality regime of industrial ownership societies through the New Deal to, eventually, a party of the “brahmin left” identified with “serving the interests of the highly educated rather than the disadvantaged.” (834).</p><p>This choice of focus, however, means that attentiveness to the conditions of inequality proprietarian ideology creates in everyday life, and how these conditions hold together a broad coalition of supporters, is largely missing. The lack of this analysis seems to be an important gap in Piketty's mission to overturn inequality in mass-suffrage societies. At the end of the book, he offers an outline of a new “participatory socialism” (1016–1022) operating through government action alongside transformations in workforce relationships, judicial systems, and global institutions to overturn the prevailing inequality regime. An analysis of how what might be called “proprietarian” coalitions” are assembled would seem to be an important task to determine what set of political conditions might overturn proprietarian ideology. Without understanding how political movements which prioritize the preservation of the wealth and privilege of a tiny elite organize larger followings, it seems likely Piketty's political mission will fail.</p><p>Building political power and momentum for proprietarian coalitions depends, in other words, on ideologues. I would argue that we can find these ideologues who are so important for Piketty's argument if we focus on the financial professionals and clerks who mediated global and local exchange. By “financial professionals” I mean actors as varied as the attorneys of the bankruptcy bar, the stockbrokers who developed new genres of literature to reach potential investors, the real estate agents who facilitated international property development schemes and pioneered local housing markets, and the mortgage bankers who created new forms of securitized finance (Coffee, <span>2006</span>; Glotzer, <span>2020</span>; Hornstein, <span>2005</span>; Hyman, <span>2011</span>; Knight, <span>2016</span>; Ott, <span>2011</span>; Skeel, <span>2001</span>). Financial professionals' livelihood depended on innovation with respect to property: they were ever developing new instruments to represent claims on property and new ways of negotiating, verifying, and asserting these claims. Self-interest led them to be the vanguard of the proprietarian coalition. Financial professionals' reliance on income from intangible services and fees for dealing in abstract negotiable instruments paradoxically reinforced their devotion to proprietarian ideology.</p><p>The appeal of proprietarian ideology to financial professionals can be traced back to the information problems of bourgeois capitalism in the Atlantic world. Absentee ownership of slave plantations, long-distance trade relationships, and interregional land development schemes all required investors to place significant trust in their partners and subordinates. Under these conditions, information asymmetries acted as a form of property; the ability to sell or trade “secrets” was an important element of building trust relationships that might lead to future profitable cooperation. The expertise necessary to keep accurate, reliable accounts, and the use of account books as a form of oversight, created a precarious dependence between business collaborators who might be separated by thousands of miles and communicated only over the course of weeks or months (Ditz, <span>2000</span>; Rosenthal, <span>2018</span>). Global reputation networks built on hierarchies of place knit together global ports and backwater outposts, ranging in scale from multi-branch banking houses to solitary speculators. From the circulation of information hierarchies of merit in turn emerged, adhering to individuals and eventually quantified in the records of credit agencies (Baskin, <span>1988</span>; Beckert, <span>2014</span>; Olegario, <span>2006</span>).</p><p>An account of proprietarian meritocracy in the United States might begin with considering how the early American republic, like the post-French revolution political settlement, sought to preserve property rights while removing “privileges and charges” and equalizing occupational opportunities. In practice, this depended on protecting investors who financed capitalist projects while encouraging a new cadre of risk-bearing entrepreneurs. Investors benefited from what Woody Holton has described as the “procreditor” Constitution, which ensured they would be able to recoup their loans by emboldening federal courts to strike down debtors' relief legislation (Holton, <span>2018</span>). The launching of the new political system crystallized meritocracy along racial lines; in other words, rather than Piketty's argument that meritocracy arose in the industrial era “to justify social differences on the basis of individual abilities,” (710) the intertwining of ideas about racial capacity and economic capacity shaped a hierarchical vision of society which could encompass a wide range of prejudices from the individual merchant to the debt practices of foreign nations (Flandreau, <span>2016</span>; Garrett-Scott, <span>2019</span>; O’Malley, <span>2012</span>; White, <span>2015</span>).</p><p>In the borderlands of bourgeois capitalism, ideologies of personal and financial risk were intertwined with the implantation of an economic culture arranged around finance. Opportunistic speculators in the Deep South benefited from the willingness of investors from Boston to Britain to fund land speculation and benefited from social hierarchies in the early republic that eased their infiltration as economic actors, enabling them to swindle native Creek families and other Indians who obtained little redress from the federal government (Saunt, <span>2019</span>). The availability of credit and access to social networks to negotiate problems and overcome business stumbles were deeply rooted in ideologies which favored white, Protestant men, yet even among white men merit could be framed in embodied terms: as Kathryn Olivarius explains, “immunocapital” accrued to New Orleans businessmen who had survived yellow fever and served as “an explanatory tool for success or failure in commodity capitalism.” Northern clerks similarly measured their physical and digestive health against their peers to index their chances for success, with institutions like the Young Men's Christian Association providing opportunities for physical self-improvement alongside moral improvement (Lupkin, <span>2010</span>; Olegario, <span>2006</span>; Olivarius, <span>2019</span>, quote p. 442; Zakim, <span>2018</span>). The racially embodied meritocracy would continue to be an important component of career success even as new technologies like the telegram and the stock ticker modified the geographic scope of capitalism, and the scale of the potential profits, while the types of expertise men were expected to deploy in pursuit of such opportunities became more and more specialized. Eventually, embodied meritocracy would be transformed into educational meritocracy through the propagation of the undergraduate “college man,” preferably an athlete, as the ideal “corporate professional” (Bjelopera, <span>2005</span>; Clark, <span>2010</span>; Davis, <span>2000</span>).</p><p>An increasing number and variety of experts held themselves out as agents who could help resolve principals' monitoring problems. Professional associations provided one way of overcoming the problem of a proliferating number of experts while simultaneously serving as a launchpad for proprietarian coalitions. Members of these associations sought to establish their credibility through the production of broadly-circulating representations, or “technologies of trust” as Marc Flandreau has phrased it, creating forums for demonstrating and recognizing each other as honorable, reliable men. Because questions of how knowledge would be divided amongst different experts were still up for grabs, these associations were often marked by conjunctions of expertise which seem incongruous from present-day perspective: the Anthropological Society of London, for example, also served as a nexus point for the creation of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, an organization established by “debt vultures” to win British government backing for their campaigns to restructure payments on distressed foreign debt on profitable terms. The affinity between the two associations was derived from the idea that the kind of knowledge necessary for understanding foreign cultures was congruent with the kind of knowledge necessary for understanding foreign finance (Flandreau, <span>2016</span>).</p><p>Placing the financial sector at the center of the analysis of <i>Capital and Ideology</i> would make clearer the emergence of global hierarchies of merit. The expansion of capitalism depended on agents who commanded increasingly specialized bodies of knowledge, such as geologists advising on the location of lucrative coal and oil deposits (Lucier, <span>2008</span>). The telegraph and the creation of a global communication infrastructure transformed capitalism by enabling an exponential shift in the projection of information across long distances and the scale of financial markets. It enabled communities of investors to congregate in newly imagined spaces and facilitated oversight across oceans and continents, whether British families invested in Baltimore real estate or American bankers who reshaped the Caribbean sugar industry (Glotzer, <span>2020</span>; Hudson, <span>2017</span>). New professions such as accountancy developed and the status hierarchy within existing professions, such as law, reshuffled as the most lucrative incomes were gathered by law firms whose senior partners specialized in putting together complex merger agreements and banking syndicate contracts while their entry-level associates fought to quash cases involving minimum wages, injury compensation, and social welfare more broadly in the name of protecting property rights (Auerbach, <span>1976</span>; Preda, <span>2009</span>; Wilkins, <span>1989</span>).</p><p>Economic growth within the United States also changed the hierarchy of relationships between different parts of the country. A larger number of financial centers developed but their orientation toward New York City grew over time. Increasing industrial prosperity threw off larger and larger profits, enabling the wealthiest investors and entrepreneurs to step aside from active management while generating salaries for an ever-wider range of professionals who asserted and protected claims on property. Bank directors in large cities no longer evaluated borrowers themselves but turned to credit experts; bank officials also made common cause with small-town commercial associations to win stronger creditor protections in the 1898 federal bankruptcy act. After the law's passage, credit professionals shared techniques to ensure debts were collected and that those who had not respected property rights were punished for failing “to protect the sanctity of the credit relation” (Hansen, <span>1998</span>; Lamoreaux, <span>1994</span>; Skeel, <span>2001</span>; Smith, <span>2010</span>, quotation p. 218).</p><p>The widening and deepening of financial professional communities was matched in other professional sectors, such as medicine, creating opportunities for financial professionals to make alliances and expand the proprietarian coalition. All professionals faced the fact that much or all of their “capital” was their intangible intellect. The proliferation of professional associations made it possible to convert this intellectual property (so to speak) into state-sanctioned credentialing systems (licensing authorities, medical boards, etc.) with barriers to entry that preserved their advantages. In medicine and other fields these practices typically replicated existing hierarchies of gender and race (Schafer, <span>2014</span>; Wiebe, <span>1962</span>). Many elite financiers used philanthropy to preserve white, Protestant men's places in the colleges producing the new professional meritocracy, as Susie Pak has shown using the example of Thomas Lamont of J.P. Morgan & Co.; indeed, young college men could be found intervening as strikebreakers to uphold proprietarian ideology (Norwood, <span>2002</span>; Pak, <span>2013</span>). Professionals increasingly saw themselves as part of a worldwide meritocracy and used international expositions and literature exchanges as opportunities to circulate ideas for both reform and self-protection (Rosenberg, <span>2012</span>). Financial professionals were key advocates for proprietarian ideology because its abstract premises dovetailed with their pragmatic priorities of protecting assets from taxation and promoting government policies to ensure asset liquidity—and thus transaction fees (Allen, <span>2015</span>; Hansen, <span>2009</span>).</p><p>From time to time Piketty catches sight of the importance of systems of professional knowledge for creating and justifying global systems of inequality. Examining the portfolio composition of the top 1% of French estates during the <i>belle époque</i>, for example, Piketty notes the preponderance of foreign investment, including in French colonies, and alludes to the use of the <i>mission civilisatrice</i> trope to justify the economic order undergirding these profitable extractive relationships. A discussion of the information infrastructure used to defend these arrangements, however, is largely absent. (270–287) Russia and other nations, for example, secretly subsidized Paris newspapers to pontificate on their internal stability and cheer on a friendly foreign policy to ensure a robust market for their bonds (Berenson, <span>1992</span>, p. 235). In the United States, meanwhile, alongside national publications like the <i>Commercial and Financial Chronicle</i> which celebrated proprietary ideology, newspaper publishers not only boosted local “growth machines” but also used their publications to explain and defend proprietarian ideology in their community's hinterlands, as when William Randolph Hearst in San Francisco and Harrison Otis in Los Angeles made the case for military intervention to protect their Peruvian and Mexican investments (Brechin, <span>1999</span>; Kim, <span>2019</span>).</p><p>Business journalists and publicists were an important faction of financial ideologues, generally avoiding other reporters' embrace of methodological objectivity and slipping back and forth between publishing statistics, editing financial magazines, writing advice columns, and lecturing. The weekly <i>Commercial and Financial Chronicle</i>, launched in 1865, was both the statistical supplier of choice and a steadfast advocate for “security of property.” Journalists transformed the internal rationales and assumptions of professional communities into arguments that could be explained and justified as normative in the broader culture (Ryant, <span>1989</span>; Steeples, <span>2002</span>). This ideological work became particularly important in the face of growing skepticism about proprietarian ideology's promises given the high inequality of the interwar years (Knight, <span>2016</span>; O’Sullivan, <span>2016</span>; Piketty, <span>2020</span>, esp. 291–294). Julia Ott shows, for example, how New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) leaders sought after World War I to establish the idea that widespread securities ownership was within reach and would create a “investors' democracy” whose virtues superseded and could displace government regulation of business and corporate finance (Ott, <span>2011</span>, pp. 130–136). In a more direct example, Isaac Martin's account of the 1924–1925 “tax clubs” movement describes the paid activist J. A. Arnold's creation of a coalition of small-town elites in Texas to support a significant federal tax cut whose greatest beneficiaries were wealthy Easterners. Combining “populist tactics and militant anti-egalitarian demands,” movement activists, often local bank officials, anticipated the tax cut would make their own securities more attractive than government-subsidized bonds but made their arguments on proprietarian grounds, insisting the tax cut would ensure money was “released for investment in productive enterprises.” The campaign successfully pressured Congress and rates were slashed in 1926, representing a triumph for the richest Americans (Martin, <span>2013</span>, 44–67, quote p. 58).</p><p>Despite this victory, barely a decade later the Great Depression and the rapid implementation of the New Deal created a profound shock for proprietarian ideologues, shaking them from their belief in the inevitable triumph of their goals. As Ott explains, NYSE leaders assembled a new Senate alliance between their traditional Republican backers and segregationist Southern Democrats to protect the preferential tax treatment of capital gains in the name of “a vision of freedom that centered… [on] the liquidity” of financial assets, deploying their argument widely through both print pamphlets and the new medium of radio (Ott, <span>2019</span>, p. 105). Piketty's emphasis on the New Deal rather than the proprietarian ideologues means he misses an opportunity to explain how this alliance became the launchpad for neo-proprietarian ideology. Organizers like William F. Buckley and Leonard Read built conservative media and explicitly political professional organizations that took up the cause of rolling back taxation and rescinding regulations that might inhibit profit maximization. The proprietarian coalition was able to reinvigorate and expand by making a meritocratic appeal to new professions established to meet the demands of the burgeoning government and the postwar consumer society, from management consultants and government contractors to “entrepreneurs” drawn to companies like Amway and service-industry workers at Wal-Mart who melded evangelical and “promarket” values. The invention and valorization of an American tradition of “free enterprise” was critical to this project, arguably culminating in the success of the former business spokesmen Ronald Reagan and Donald Trump in their respective presidential runs and their aggressive rollbacks of taxes on the wealthy (888–889) (Glickman, <span>2019</span>; McKenna, <span>2006</span>; Mondom, <span>2018</span>; Moreton, <span>2009</span>; Phillips-Fein, <span>2009</span>). Nonetheless financial professionals remain central to this project; indeed the <i>Wall Street Journal</i>'s editorial section today arguably fills the same role as the <i>Commercial and Financial Chronicle</i> in the past as the most prominent media advocate for proprietarian ideology.</p><p>“There is never anything ‘natural’ about social inequality,” Piketty declares after summarizing elite-dominated regimes from Japan to Iran to China. “It is always profoundly ideological and political.” (411) Just because the fall and now rise again of inequality is not a “natural” process, however, does not exclude the possibility that the professionals whose labor is at the heart of its perpetuation do not see their participation as natural. Karen Ho's ethnography of present-day financial workers, <i>Liquidated</i>, examines the worldviews of young professionals who have transitioned from elite universities into entry-level jobs on Wall Street. Poised on the lower rungs of the meritocracy, Ho notes that young workers quickly internalize the logic of “downsizing” and “rightsizing” workers laboring in retail and manufacturing in part because of their own experience of a rapidly churning job market (though with a much more comfortable safety net) (Ho, <span>2009</span>). Bringing a historically-minded approach to how such values permeate through professional cultures not as false consciousness but as a sincere response to precarious conditions may be an important step for those seeking to organize against and overturn the prevailing crisis of wealth inequality.</p>","PeriodicalId":46376,"journal":{"name":"History Compass","volume":"20 4","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.5000,"publicationDate":"2022-03-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://compass.onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/hic3.12717","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Financial professionals and the formation of proprietarian ideology\",\"authors\":\"Atiba Pertilla\",\"doi\":\"10.1111/hic3.12717\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p>This review essay on economist Thomas Piketty's <i>Capital and Ideology</i> argues that the role of financial professionals as ideologues is a necessary yet missing component of Piketty's analysis. Using the history of capitalism in the United States as a connective thread, the essay synthesizes examples from a broad array of studies to trace the role of financial professionals from the counting houses of early republic New Orleans and New York through the professionalization of stockbrokers and investment bankers in the late-19th century Gilded Age to modern-day Wall Street white-collar workers. Throughout U.S. history financial professionals and their allied media institutions have been ubiquitous and essential advocates for a “proprietarian” ideology which prioritizes the sanctity of property rights over ameliorating inequality.</p><p>Thomas Piketty's <i>Capital and Ideology</i> offers a sprawling history of how conditions of economic inequality advance or constrain human progress. Casting aside arguments that economic growth lifts all boats, Piketty urges looking instead to political and ideological structures for a robust explanation of social development. The book's 17 chapters seek to establish a unified theory of social evolution at the nation-state level, developing a chronology and a terminology that proceeds from “ternary” systems of nobles, clerics, and peasants (a model Piketty fits to medieval and early modern societies from Western Europe to Japan) through the bourgeois capitalist regimes established in the eighteenth century and the social-democratic societies that arose in the wake of World War I, finally ending in a present-day surge in oligarchic populism that decries inequality while doing little, he argues, to reverse it. Particularly tragic, in Piketty's eyes, is that in recent history this shift has been accompanied by a “distinctive” meritocratic ideology which “blame[s] the poor for their poverty.” (Piketty, <span>2020</span>, p. 710) Given Piketty's sociopolitical goals, <i>Capital and Ideology</i>'s political vision suffers from often being free of ideologues. I argue that we might fill this gap by examining financial sector professionals as critical actors in establishing and defending “inequality regimes” (as Piketty terms them) throughout the past two centuries. Tracing the ideological work of financial professionals' in the United States from the early republic forward, I suggest we might discover fruitful continuities linking the development of new systems of capitalist knowledge in the Age of Revolutions with the social role of the present-day meritocracy.<sup>1</sup></p><p>While Piketty's earlier book <i>Capital in the Twenty-First Century</i> was built on the argument that unregulated capitalism “automatically generates arbitrary and unsustainable inequalities,” (Piketty, <span>2014</span>, p. 1) the villain of the sequel is not capitalism per se but “proprietarian” ideology, a way of making sense of the world and shaping a given political regime to justify these inequalities whose first premise is “the sacralization of property rights,” as explained in the new book's brief glossary (1044). The first section of the book traces a long tradition of political arguments in many parts of the world devoted to refuting the idea that elites held unique responsibilities to the polity as a whole under the social contract. The third section of <i>Capital and Ideology</i> describes the “Great Transformation” which saw most of the North Atlantic democracies abandon the nineteenth-century liberal variation in the face of World War I and the Great Depression, followed by the steady return of inequality under neoliberal auspices from the 1970s onward. In the present day, Piketty is anxious about a possible move to a more malevolent “market nativism” which exploits xenophobia to dampen the appeal of redistributionist policy while entrenching tax systems which privilege existing wealth. In the final chapters, Piketty seeks to argue that only “exceptional taxes on private capital” can fund the reinvigoration of social democracy and ensure progress (886–891).</p><p>Piketty, in other words, is interested in capital—whether vested in control over economic outputs through ownership rights or represented in the (usually monetized) returns on those outputs, rather than capitalism—the systems of extraction, negotiation, coercion, and cooperation that produce those returns and ownership structures (Levy, <span>2017</span>). Piketty devotes particular attention to French history to examine the intertwining of income inequality and the defense of property rights. In the fourth chapter, he offers a counterintuitive argument that the French Revolution, notwithstanding the toppling of the monarchy and the landowning nobility, entrenched property relationships more firmly than they had ever been before by severing ownership (particularly of land) from civil authority, enhancing the legitimacy of “modern property rights.” (105) The removal of “privileges and charges” and “establish[ing] equal access to different occupations and to property rights” were considered sufficient to ensure the desired goal of an egalitarian society (118). Changes in the sources of wealth of the country's largest fortunes, and the absence of political pressure to redistribute the country's prosperity through the tax code, however, meant that by the late nineteenth century income inequality had already risen to levels like those of the pre-revolutionary era. Nonetheless it was important for Third Republic politicians to insist that France was “a country of ‘smallholders’” (139) yet Piketty's detailed quantitative studies of income and property show the distribution of wealth barely budged for the poorest 90% of the country from 1780 until 1910, and that their cumulative total rarely reached above 50% of income or 20% of property (130–131).</p><p>In shifting focus from capitalism to property, Piketty seeks to trace the longer history of the ideological argument that the social conditions capitalism creates can be justified by the resulting distribution of property. Piketty describes ideology as “attempts… to impose meaning” from above. To study ideology, he focuses on formal political speech, found in party platforms and governmental debates; he also turns to “theorists and political actors to see how inequalities were justified.” (14) His attention is drawn most, as in the 11th chapter (the book's longest), to those political parties which were in the vanguard of creating the “incomplete equality” regimes that triumphed in Western democracies in the mid-twentieth century, from the German Social Democratic Party to the Democratic Party in the United States to the workers' parties of Scandinavia (486–508). Piketty is clearly more sympathetic to these political groups, and seems fascinated, for example, by the transformations that have taken the Democrats from a party dominated by southern slaveholders to the vehicle for supplanting the inequality regime of industrial ownership societies through the New Deal to, eventually, a party of the “brahmin left” identified with “serving the interests of the highly educated rather than the disadvantaged.” (834).</p><p>This choice of focus, however, means that attentiveness to the conditions of inequality proprietarian ideology creates in everyday life, and how these conditions hold together a broad coalition of supporters, is largely missing. The lack of this analysis seems to be an important gap in Piketty's mission to overturn inequality in mass-suffrage societies. At the end of the book, he offers an outline of a new “participatory socialism” (1016–1022) operating through government action alongside transformations in workforce relationships, judicial systems, and global institutions to overturn the prevailing inequality regime. An analysis of how what might be called “proprietarian” coalitions” are assembled would seem to be an important task to determine what set of political conditions might overturn proprietarian ideology. Without understanding how political movements which prioritize the preservation of the wealth and privilege of a tiny elite organize larger followings, it seems likely Piketty's political mission will fail.</p><p>Building political power and momentum for proprietarian coalitions depends, in other words, on ideologues. I would argue that we can find these ideologues who are so important for Piketty's argument if we focus on the financial professionals and clerks who mediated global and local exchange. By “financial professionals” I mean actors as varied as the attorneys of the bankruptcy bar, the stockbrokers who developed new genres of literature to reach potential investors, the real estate agents who facilitated international property development schemes and pioneered local housing markets, and the mortgage bankers who created new forms of securitized finance (Coffee, <span>2006</span>; Glotzer, <span>2020</span>; Hornstein, <span>2005</span>; Hyman, <span>2011</span>; Knight, <span>2016</span>; Ott, <span>2011</span>; Skeel, <span>2001</span>). Financial professionals' livelihood depended on innovation with respect to property: they were ever developing new instruments to represent claims on property and new ways of negotiating, verifying, and asserting these claims. Self-interest led them to be the vanguard of the proprietarian coalition. Financial professionals' reliance on income from intangible services and fees for dealing in abstract negotiable instruments paradoxically reinforced their devotion to proprietarian ideology.</p><p>The appeal of proprietarian ideology to financial professionals can be traced back to the information problems of bourgeois capitalism in the Atlantic world. Absentee ownership of slave plantations, long-distance trade relationships, and interregional land development schemes all required investors to place significant trust in their partners and subordinates. Under these conditions, information asymmetries acted as a form of property; the ability to sell or trade “secrets” was an important element of building trust relationships that might lead to future profitable cooperation. The expertise necessary to keep accurate, reliable accounts, and the use of account books as a form of oversight, created a precarious dependence between business collaborators who might be separated by thousands of miles and communicated only over the course of weeks or months (Ditz, <span>2000</span>; Rosenthal, <span>2018</span>). Global reputation networks built on hierarchies of place knit together global ports and backwater outposts, ranging in scale from multi-branch banking houses to solitary speculators. From the circulation of information hierarchies of merit in turn emerged, adhering to individuals and eventually quantified in the records of credit agencies (Baskin, <span>1988</span>; Beckert, <span>2014</span>; Olegario, <span>2006</span>).</p><p>An account of proprietarian meritocracy in the United States might begin with considering how the early American republic, like the post-French revolution political settlement, sought to preserve property rights while removing “privileges and charges” and equalizing occupational opportunities. In practice, this depended on protecting investors who financed capitalist projects while encouraging a new cadre of risk-bearing entrepreneurs. Investors benefited from what Woody Holton has described as the “procreditor” Constitution, which ensured they would be able to recoup their loans by emboldening federal courts to strike down debtors' relief legislation (Holton, <span>2018</span>). The launching of the new political system crystallized meritocracy along racial lines; in other words, rather than Piketty's argument that meritocracy arose in the industrial era “to justify social differences on the basis of individual abilities,” (710) the intertwining of ideas about racial capacity and economic capacity shaped a hierarchical vision of society which could encompass a wide range of prejudices from the individual merchant to the debt practices of foreign nations (Flandreau, <span>2016</span>; Garrett-Scott, <span>2019</span>; O’Malley, <span>2012</span>; White, <span>2015</span>).</p><p>In the borderlands of bourgeois capitalism, ideologies of personal and financial risk were intertwined with the implantation of an economic culture arranged around finance. Opportunistic speculators in the Deep South benefited from the willingness of investors from Boston to Britain to fund land speculation and benefited from social hierarchies in the early republic that eased their infiltration as economic actors, enabling them to swindle native Creek families and other Indians who obtained little redress from the federal government (Saunt, <span>2019</span>). The availability of credit and access to social networks to negotiate problems and overcome business stumbles were deeply rooted in ideologies which favored white, Protestant men, yet even among white men merit could be framed in embodied terms: as Kathryn Olivarius explains, “immunocapital” accrued to New Orleans businessmen who had survived yellow fever and served as “an explanatory tool for success or failure in commodity capitalism.” Northern clerks similarly measured their physical and digestive health against their peers to index their chances for success, with institutions like the Young Men's Christian Association providing opportunities for physical self-improvement alongside moral improvement (Lupkin, <span>2010</span>; Olegario, <span>2006</span>; Olivarius, <span>2019</span>, quote p. 442; Zakim, <span>2018</span>). The racially embodied meritocracy would continue to be an important component of career success even as new technologies like the telegram and the stock ticker modified the geographic scope of capitalism, and the scale of the potential profits, while the types of expertise men were expected to deploy in pursuit of such opportunities became more and more specialized. Eventually, embodied meritocracy would be transformed into educational meritocracy through the propagation of the undergraduate “college man,” preferably an athlete, as the ideal “corporate professional” (Bjelopera, <span>2005</span>; Clark, <span>2010</span>; Davis, <span>2000</span>).</p><p>An increasing number and variety of experts held themselves out as agents who could help resolve principals' monitoring problems. Professional associations provided one way of overcoming the problem of a proliferating number of experts while simultaneously serving as a launchpad for proprietarian coalitions. Members of these associations sought to establish their credibility through the production of broadly-circulating representations, or “technologies of trust” as Marc Flandreau has phrased it, creating forums for demonstrating and recognizing each other as honorable, reliable men. Because questions of how knowledge would be divided amongst different experts were still up for grabs, these associations were often marked by conjunctions of expertise which seem incongruous from present-day perspective: the Anthropological Society of London, for example, also served as a nexus point for the creation of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, an organization established by “debt vultures” to win British government backing for their campaigns to restructure payments on distressed foreign debt on profitable terms. The affinity between the two associations was derived from the idea that the kind of knowledge necessary for understanding foreign cultures was congruent with the kind of knowledge necessary for understanding foreign finance (Flandreau, <span>2016</span>).</p><p>Placing the financial sector at the center of the analysis of <i>Capital and Ideology</i> would make clearer the emergence of global hierarchies of merit. The expansion of capitalism depended on agents who commanded increasingly specialized bodies of knowledge, such as geologists advising on the location of lucrative coal and oil deposits (Lucier, <span>2008</span>). The telegraph and the creation of a global communication infrastructure transformed capitalism by enabling an exponential shift in the projection of information across long distances and the scale of financial markets. It enabled communities of investors to congregate in newly imagined spaces and facilitated oversight across oceans and continents, whether British families invested in Baltimore real estate or American bankers who reshaped the Caribbean sugar industry (Glotzer, <span>2020</span>; Hudson, <span>2017</span>). New professions such as accountancy developed and the status hierarchy within existing professions, such as law, reshuffled as the most lucrative incomes were gathered by law firms whose senior partners specialized in putting together complex merger agreements and banking syndicate contracts while their entry-level associates fought to quash cases involving minimum wages, injury compensation, and social welfare more broadly in the name of protecting property rights (Auerbach, <span>1976</span>; Preda, <span>2009</span>; Wilkins, <span>1989</span>).</p><p>Economic growth within the United States also changed the hierarchy of relationships between different parts of the country. A larger number of financial centers developed but their orientation toward New York City grew over time. Increasing industrial prosperity threw off larger and larger profits, enabling the wealthiest investors and entrepreneurs to step aside from active management while generating salaries for an ever-wider range of professionals who asserted and protected claims on property. Bank directors in large cities no longer evaluated borrowers themselves but turned to credit experts; bank officials also made common cause with small-town commercial associations to win stronger creditor protections in the 1898 federal bankruptcy act. After the law's passage, credit professionals shared techniques to ensure debts were collected and that those who had not respected property rights were punished for failing “to protect the sanctity of the credit relation” (Hansen, <span>1998</span>; Lamoreaux, <span>1994</span>; Skeel, <span>2001</span>; Smith, <span>2010</span>, quotation p. 218).</p><p>The widening and deepening of financial professional communities was matched in other professional sectors, such as medicine, creating opportunities for financial professionals to make alliances and expand the proprietarian coalition. All professionals faced the fact that much or all of their “capital” was their intangible intellect. The proliferation of professional associations made it possible to convert this intellectual property (so to speak) into state-sanctioned credentialing systems (licensing authorities, medical boards, etc.) with barriers to entry that preserved their advantages. In medicine and other fields these practices typically replicated existing hierarchies of gender and race (Schafer, <span>2014</span>; Wiebe, <span>1962</span>). Many elite financiers used philanthropy to preserve white, Protestant men's places in the colleges producing the new professional meritocracy, as Susie Pak has shown using the example of Thomas Lamont of J.P. Morgan & Co.; indeed, young college men could be found intervening as strikebreakers to uphold proprietarian ideology (Norwood, <span>2002</span>; Pak, <span>2013</span>). Professionals increasingly saw themselves as part of a worldwide meritocracy and used international expositions and literature exchanges as opportunities to circulate ideas for both reform and self-protection (Rosenberg, <span>2012</span>). Financial professionals were key advocates for proprietarian ideology because its abstract premises dovetailed with their pragmatic priorities of protecting assets from taxation and promoting government policies to ensure asset liquidity—and thus transaction fees (Allen, <span>2015</span>; Hansen, <span>2009</span>).</p><p>From time to time Piketty catches sight of the importance of systems of professional knowledge for creating and justifying global systems of inequality. Examining the portfolio composition of the top 1% of French estates during the <i>belle époque</i>, for example, Piketty notes the preponderance of foreign investment, including in French colonies, and alludes to the use of the <i>mission civilisatrice</i> trope to justify the economic order undergirding these profitable extractive relationships. A discussion of the information infrastructure used to defend these arrangements, however, is largely absent. (270–287) Russia and other nations, for example, secretly subsidized Paris newspapers to pontificate on their internal stability and cheer on a friendly foreign policy to ensure a robust market for their bonds (Berenson, <span>1992</span>, p. 235). In the United States, meanwhile, alongside national publications like the <i>Commercial and Financial Chronicle</i> which celebrated proprietary ideology, newspaper publishers not only boosted local “growth machines” but also used their publications to explain and defend proprietarian ideology in their community's hinterlands, as when William Randolph Hearst in San Francisco and Harrison Otis in Los Angeles made the case for military intervention to protect their Peruvian and Mexican investments (Brechin, <span>1999</span>; Kim, <span>2019</span>).</p><p>Business journalists and publicists were an important faction of financial ideologues, generally avoiding other reporters' embrace of methodological objectivity and slipping back and forth between publishing statistics, editing financial magazines, writing advice columns, and lecturing. The weekly <i>Commercial and Financial Chronicle</i>, launched in 1865, was both the statistical supplier of choice and a steadfast advocate for “security of property.” Journalists transformed the internal rationales and assumptions of professional communities into arguments that could be explained and justified as normative in the broader culture (Ryant, <span>1989</span>; Steeples, <span>2002</span>). This ideological work became particularly important in the face of growing skepticism about proprietarian ideology's promises given the high inequality of the interwar years (Knight, <span>2016</span>; O’Sullivan, <span>2016</span>; Piketty, <span>2020</span>, esp. 291–294). Julia Ott shows, for example, how New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) leaders sought after World War I to establish the idea that widespread securities ownership was within reach and would create a “investors' democracy” whose virtues superseded and could displace government regulation of business and corporate finance (Ott, <span>2011</span>, pp. 130–136). In a more direct example, Isaac Martin's account of the 1924–1925 “tax clubs” movement describes the paid activist J. A. Arnold's creation of a coalition of small-town elites in Texas to support a significant federal tax cut whose greatest beneficiaries were wealthy Easterners. Combining “populist tactics and militant anti-egalitarian demands,” movement activists, often local bank officials, anticipated the tax cut would make their own securities more attractive than government-subsidized bonds but made their arguments on proprietarian grounds, insisting the tax cut would ensure money was “released for investment in productive enterprises.” The campaign successfully pressured Congress and rates were slashed in 1926, representing a triumph for the richest Americans (Martin, <span>2013</span>, 44–67, quote p. 58).</p><p>Despite this victory, barely a decade later the Great Depression and the rapid implementation of the New Deal created a profound shock for proprietarian ideologues, shaking them from their belief in the inevitable triumph of their goals. As Ott explains, NYSE leaders assembled a new Senate alliance between their traditional Republican backers and segregationist Southern Democrats to protect the preferential tax treatment of capital gains in the name of “a vision of freedom that centered… [on] the liquidity” of financial assets, deploying their argument widely through both print pamphlets and the new medium of radio (Ott, <span>2019</span>, p. 105). Piketty's emphasis on the New Deal rather than the proprietarian ideologues means he misses an opportunity to explain how this alliance became the launchpad for neo-proprietarian ideology. Organizers like William F. Buckley and Leonard Read built conservative media and explicitly political professional organizations that took up the cause of rolling back taxation and rescinding regulations that might inhibit profit maximization. The proprietarian coalition was able to reinvigorate and expand by making a meritocratic appeal to new professions established to meet the demands of the burgeoning government and the postwar consumer society, from management consultants and government contractors to “entrepreneurs” drawn to companies like Amway and service-industry workers at Wal-Mart who melded evangelical and “promarket” values. The invention and valorization of an American tradition of “free enterprise” was critical to this project, arguably culminating in the success of the former business spokesmen Ronald Reagan and Donald Trump in their respective presidential runs and their aggressive rollbacks of taxes on the wealthy (888–889) (Glickman, <span>2019</span>; McKenna, <span>2006</span>; Mondom, <span>2018</span>; Moreton, <span>2009</span>; Phillips-Fein, <span>2009</span>). Nonetheless financial professionals remain central to this project; indeed the <i>Wall Street Journal</i>'s editorial section today arguably fills the same role as the <i>Commercial and Financial Chronicle</i> in the past as the most prominent media advocate for proprietarian ideology.</p><p>“There is never anything ‘natural’ about social inequality,” Piketty declares after summarizing elite-dominated regimes from Japan to Iran to China. “It is always profoundly ideological and political.” (411) Just because the fall and now rise again of inequality is not a “natural” process, however, does not exclude the possibility that the professionals whose labor is at the heart of its perpetuation do not see their participation as natural. Karen Ho's ethnography of present-day financial workers, <i>Liquidated</i>, examines the worldviews of young professionals who have transitioned from elite universities into entry-level jobs on Wall Street. Poised on the lower rungs of the meritocracy, Ho notes that young workers quickly internalize the logic of “downsizing” and “rightsizing” workers laboring in retail and manufacturing in part because of their own experience of a rapidly churning job market (though with a much more comfortable safety net) (Ho, <span>2009</span>). Bringing a historically-minded approach to how such values permeate through professional cultures not as false consciousness but as a sincere response to precarious conditions may be an important step for those seeking to organize against and overturn the prevailing crisis of wealth inequality.</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":46376,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"History Compass\",\"volume\":\"20 4\",\"pages\":\"\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.5000,\"publicationDate\":\"2022-03-11\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://compass.onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/hic3.12717\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"History Compass\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/hic3.12717\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q1\",\"JCRName\":\"HISTORY\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"History Compass","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/hic3.12717","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"HISTORY","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
摘要
这篇对经济学家托马斯•皮凯蒂(Thomas Piketty)的《资本与意识形态》(Capital and Ideology)的评论文章认为,金融专业人士作为意识形态家的角色是皮凯蒂分析中必要但缺失的组成部分。本文以美国资本主义的历史为线索,综合了大量研究中的例子,追溯了金融专业人士的角色,从共和初期新奥尔良和纽约的会计室,到19世纪末镀金时代股票经纪人和投资银行家的专业化,再到现代华尔街白领。纵观美国历史,金融专业人士和他们的盟友媒体机构一直是“专有权”意识形态的普遍倡导者,这种意识形态将财产权的神圣性置于改善不平等之上。托马斯·皮凯蒂(Thomas Piketty)的《资本论与意识形态》(Capital and Ideology)讲述了经济不平等状况如何推动或限制人类进步的漫长历史。撇开经济增长能提升所有人的观点,皮凯蒂敦促人们从政治和意识形态结构中寻找对社会发展的有力解释。这本书的17章试图在民族国家层面建立一个统一的社会进化理论,发展了一个时序和术语,从贵族、神职人员和农民的“三元”体系(皮凯蒂适合于从中世纪和早期现代社会,从西欧到日本)开始,通过18世纪建立的资产阶级资本主义政权和第一次世界大战后兴起的社会民主主义社会,他认为,最终的结果是如今寡头民粹主义的激增,这种民粹主义谴责不平等,却几乎没有采取任何措施来扭转这种不平等。在皮凯蒂看来,尤其悲惨的是,在近代史上,这种转变伴随着一种“独特的”精英主义意识形态,这种意识形态“将穷人的贫穷归咎于穷人”。(皮凯蒂,2020年,第710页)鉴于皮凯蒂的社会政治目标,《资本论与意识形态》的政治愿景往往缺乏意识形态家。我认为,我们或许可以通过考察金融业专业人士在过去两个世纪中建立和捍卫“不平等制度”(皮凯蒂称之为“不平等制度”)的关键角色,来填补这一空白。从共和国早期开始追踪美国金融专业人士的意识形态工作,我认为我们可能会发现革命时代资本主义知识新体系的发展与当今精英政治的社会角色之间富有成效的连续性。虽然皮凯蒂的早期著作《21世纪资本论》是建立在不受管制的资本主义“自动产生任意和不可持续的不平等”的论点之上的(皮凯蒂,2014年,第1页),续集的恶人不是资本主义本身,而是“所有制”意识形态,这是一种理解世界和塑造特定政治制度的方式,以证明这些不平等的正当性,其第一个前提是“财产权的神圣化”。正如在新书的简短词汇表(1044)中所解释的那样。本书的第一部分追溯了世界上许多地方的政治争论的悠久传统,这些争论致力于驳斥精英在社会契约下对整个政体负有独特责任的观点。《资本论与意识形态》的第三部分描述了“大转型”,即面对第一次世界大战和大萧条,大多数北大西洋民主国家放弃了19世纪的自由主义变体,随后从20世纪70年代开始,在新自由主义的支持下,不平等稳步回归。如今,皮凯蒂担心的是,一种更恶毒的“市场本土主义”(market native - vism)可能会发展成一种利用仇外心理来削弱再分配政策的吸引力,同时巩固有利于现有财富的税收制度。在最后几章中,皮凯蒂试图论证,只有“对私人资本的特殊税收”才能为社会民主主义的复兴提供资金,并确保进步(886-891)。换句话说,皮凯蒂感兴趣的是资本——无论是通过所有权获得对经济产出的控制权,还是以这些产出的(通常是货币化的)回报(而不是资本主义)为代表——产生这些回报和所有权结构的榨取、谈判、强制和合作体系(Levy, 2017)。皮凯蒂特别关注法国历史,以研究收入不平等与产权保护之间的相互关系。在第四章中,他提出了一个违反直觉的论点,即法国大革命尽管推翻了君主制和拥有土地的贵族,但通过将所有权(尤其是土地所有权)从民事权力中分离出来,使财产关系比以往任何时候都更加牢固,从而增强了“现代财产权”的合法性。 (105)取消“特权和收费”和“建立对不同职业和财产权的平等机会”被认为足以确保一个平等社会的理想目标(118)。然而,这个国家最大的财富来源的变化,以及通过税法重新分配国家繁荣的政治压力的缺失,意味着到19世纪晚期,收入不平等已经上升到革命前的水平。尽管如此,第三共和国的政治家们坚持认为法国是“一个‘小农’的国家”(139)是很重要的,但皮凯蒂对收入和财产的详细定量研究表明,从1780年到1910年,法国最贫穷的90%人口的财富分配几乎没有变化,他们的累积总额很少超过收入的50%或财产的20%(130-131)。在将焦点从资本主义转移到财产的过程中,皮凯蒂试图追溯意识形态争论的更长的历史,即资本主义创造的社会条件可以通过由此产生的财产分配来证明是合理的。皮凯蒂将意识形态描述为自上而下“强加意义的企图”。为了研究意识形态,他专注于正式的政治演讲,在政党纲领和政府辩论中发现;他还求助于“理论家和政治行动者,看看不平等是如何被证明是合理的。”(14)在第11章(书中最长的一章)中,他最关注的是那些在20世纪中期在西方民主国家取得胜利的“不完全平等”政权的先锋政党,从德国社会民主党到美国民主党,再到斯堪的纳维亚的工人政党(486-508)。皮凯蒂显然更同情这些政治团体,并且似乎对民主党的转变着迷,例如,民主党从一个由南方奴隶主主导的政党,转变为通过新政取代工业所有制社会不平等制度的工具,最终转变为一个“婆罗门左派”政党,被认定为“为受过高等教育的人服务,而不是为弱势群体服务”。”(834)。然而,这种关注焦点的选择意味着,人们在很大程度上忽略了对资产阶级意识形态在日常生活中造成的不平等状况的关注,以及对这些状况如何将一个广泛的支持者联盟凝聚在一起的关注。皮凯蒂的使命是推翻普选社会中的不平等现象,缺乏这种分析似乎是其中的一个重要缺陷。在书的最后,他概述了一种新的“参与式社会主义”(1016-1022),通过政府行动以及劳动力关系、司法系统和全球机构的变革来推翻普遍存在的不平等制度。分析所谓的“业主”联盟是如何组成的,似乎是一项重要的任务,以确定什么样的政治条件可能推翻业主意识形态。如果不了解优先保护少数精英的财富和特权的政治运动是如何组织更大的追随者的,皮凯蒂的政治使命似乎很可能会失败。换句话说,为业主联盟建立政治力量和动力取决于意识形态。我认为,如果我们把注意力集中在调解全球和地方交易的金融专业人士和职员身上,我们就能找到这些理论家,他们对皮凯蒂的论点非常重要。所谓“金融专业人士”,我指的是各种各样的演员,如破产律师事务所的律师,开发新文学流派以吸引潜在投资者的股票经纪人,促进国际房地产开发计划并开创当地住房市场的房地产经纪人,以及创造证券化金融新形式的抵押贷款银行家(Coffee, 2006;Glotzer, 2020;Hornstein, 2005;海曼,2011;骑士,2016;奥特,2011;斯基尔,2001)。金融专业人士的生计依赖于财产方面的创新:他们不断开发新的工具来代表对财产的债权,以及谈判、核实和主张这些债权的新方法。自身利益驱使他们成为业主联盟的先锋。金融专业人士对无形服务和抽象可转让票据交易费用收入的依赖,反而强化了他们对自营意识形态的忠诚。资产阶级意识形态对金融专业人士的吸引力可以追溯到大西洋世界资产阶级资本主义的信息问题。奴隶种植园的缺席所有权、长途贸易关系和跨区域土地开发计划都要求投资者对其合作伙伴和下属给予高度信任。 在这些条件下,信息不对称充当了一种财产形式;出售或交易“秘密”的能力是建立信任关系的一个重要因素,这种关系可能导致未来有利可图的合作。保持准确、可靠的账目所必需的专业知识,以及将账簿作为一种监督形式的使用,在商业合作者之间创造了一种不稳定的依赖关系,这些合作者可能相隔数千英里,只在几周或几个月的时间内进行沟通(迪茨,2000;罗森塔尔,2018)。建立在地方等级之上的全球声誉网络将全球港口和落后的前哨联系在一起,其规模从多家分行银行到单独的投机者。从信息的流通中,merit等级依次出现,坚持个人并最终在信用机构的记录中量化(Baskin, 1988;Beckert, 2014;Olegario, 2006)。对美国专有权精英政治的描述,可以从考虑早期的美国共和国如何像法国大革命后的政治解决方案一样,在消除“特权和收费”和平等职业机会的同时,寻求保护财产权开始。在实践中,这取决于保护为资本主义项目提供资金的投资者,同时鼓励承担风险的新企业家。投资者受益于伍迪·霍尔顿(Woody Holton)所描述的“保护债权人”宪法,该宪法通过鼓励联邦法院推翻债务人救济立法,确保他们能够收回贷款(霍尔顿,2018)。新政治制度的启动使精英政治沿着种族界限具体化;换句话说,Piketty认为,精英政治出现在工业时代,“是为了在个人能力的基础上证明社会差异的合理性”(710),有关种族能力和经济能力的观点交织在一起,形成了一种社会等级观,其中可能包含从个体商人到外国债务实践的广泛偏见(Flandreau, 2016;Garrett-Scott, 2019;奥马利,2012;白,2015)。在资产阶级资本主义的边缘地带,个人和金融风险的意识形态与以金融为中心的经济文化的植入交织在一起。南方腹地的机会主义投机者受益于从波士顿到英国的投资者为土地投机提供资金的意愿,并受益于共和国早期的社会等级制度,这缓解了他们作为经济参与者的渗透,使他们能够欺骗当地的克里克家庭和其他印第安人,这些印第安人从联邦政府那里获得的救济很少(Saunt, 2019)。信贷的可获得性以及通过社交网络来协商问题和克服商业上的挫折深深植根于白人新教徒的意识形态中,然而即使在白人男性中,优点也可以用具体的术语来描述:正如凯瑟琳·奥利瓦里乌斯(Kathryn Olivarius)所解释的那样,“免疫资本”积累在新奥尔良的商人身上,他们从黄热病中幸存下来,并成为“商品资本主义成功或失败的解释工具”。同样,北方的职员也会将自己的身体和消化系统健康状况与同龄人进行比较,以此来衡量他们成功的机会,像基督教青年协会这样的机构在提高道德的同时,也为身体上的自我完善提供了机会(Lupkin, 2010;Olegario, 2006;Olivarius, 2019,引用第442页;Zakim, 2018)。即使像电报和股票报价机这样的新技术改变了资本主义的地理范围和潜在利润的规模,而人们期望在追求这些机会时运用的专业知识类型变得越来越专业化,种族体现的精英统治仍将是职业成功的重要组成部分。最终,具体化的精英政治将通过把大学生“大学生”(最好是运动员)宣传为理想的“企业专业人员”而转变为教育精英政治(Bjelopera, 2005;克拉克,2010;戴维斯,2000)。越来越多的专家和各种各样的专家认为自己是代理,可以帮助解决委托人的监督问题。专业协会提供了一种方法,可以克服专家人数激增的问题,同时又可作为业主联盟的启动平台。这些协会的成员试图通过生产广泛传播的代表来建立自己的信誉,或者正如马克·弗兰德鲁所说的“信任技术”,创造论坛来展示和承认彼此是可敬的、可靠的人。 由于知识如何在不同专家之间分配的问题仍然悬而未决,这些联系往往以专业知识的结合为标志,从今天的角度来看,这似乎是不协调的:例如,伦敦人类学学会也是创建外国债券持有人公司的一个枢纽,这是一个由“债务秃鹫”建立的组织,旨在赢得英国政府的支持,支持他们以有利可图的条款重组不良外国债务的支付。这两个协会之间的密切关系源于这样一种观点,即理解外国文化所需的知识与理解外国金融所需的知识是一致的(Flandreau, 2016)。将金融部门置于《资本论与意识形态》分析的中心,将使全球等级制度的出现更加清晰。资本主义的扩张依赖于代理人,他们掌握着越来越专业化的知识体系,比如地质学家就有利可图的煤炭和石油矿藏的位置提供建议(Lucier, 2008)。电报和全球通信基础设施的创建,使信息在远距离和金融市场规模上的投射呈指数级变化,从而改变了资本主义。它使投资者社区能够聚集在新想象的空间中,并促进了跨越海洋和大陆的监督,无论是投资巴尔的摩房地产的英国家庭,还是重塑加勒比制糖业的美国银行家(Glotzer, 2020;哈德逊,2017)。会计等新职业发展起来,现有职业(如法律)中的地位等级也在重新调整,因为最有利可图的收入被律师事务所收集,这些律师事务所的高级合伙人专门负责制定复杂的合并协议和银行辛迪加合同,而他们的初级合伙人则以保护财产权的名义,在更广泛的范围内争取撤销涉及最低工资、伤害赔偿和社会福利的案件(Auerbach, 1976;Preda, 2009;威尔金斯,1989)。美国国内的经济增长也改变了这个国家不同地区之间的关系等级。越来越多的金融中心发展起来,但随着时间的推移,它们越来越倾向于纽约市。日益繁荣的工业带来了越来越大的利润,使最富有的投资者和企业家能够放弃积极的管理,同时为越来越多的主张和保护财产索赔的专业人士带来了工资。大城市的银行主管不再亲自评估借款人,而是求助于信贷专家;银行官员还与小城镇商业协会共同努力,在1898年的联邦破产法中争取更强有力的债权人保护。法律通过后,信贷专业人员分享了确保债务被收回的技术,那些不尊重财产权的人因未能“保护信用关系的神圣性”而受到惩罚(Hansen, 1998;Lamoreaux 1994;斯基尔,2001;史密斯,2010,引文第218页)。金融专业群体的扩大和深化与其他专业领域(如医学)相匹配,为金融专业人士结盟和扩大自营联盟创造了机会。所有专业人士都面临这样一个事实:他们的大部分或全部“资本”是他们无形的智力。专业协会的激增使得有可能将这种知识产权(可以这么说)转化为国家认可的认证体系(许可机构、医疗委员会等),这些体系设置了进入壁垒,保留了它们的优势。在医学和其他领域,这些做法通常复制了现有的性别和种族等级制度(Schafer, 2014;Wiebe, 1962)。许多精英金融家利用慈善事业来维持白人新教徒男性在大学里的地位,这些大学产生了新的专业精英,正如苏茜·帕克(Susie Pak)用摩根大通(J.P. Morgan)的托马斯·拉蒙特(Thomas Lamont)的例子所表明的那样;有限公司;事实上,可以发现年轻的大学男生作为罢工破坏者进行干预,以维护业主意识形态(Norwood, 2002;Pak, 2013)。专业人士越来越多地将自己视为世界精英统治的一部分,并利用国际博览会和文学交流作为传播改革和自我保护思想的机会(Rosenberg, 2012)。金融专业人士是自营意识形态的主要倡导者,因为其抽象前提与他们保护资产免受税收和促进政府政策以确保资产流动性(从而确保交易费用)的务实优先事项相吻合(Allen, 2015;汉森,2009)。皮凯蒂不时地注意到专业知识体系对于创造和证明全球不平等体系的重要性。 例如,皮凯蒂考察了在“好日子”期间法国最富有的1%的资产组合构成,注意到外国投资的优势,包括在法国殖民地的投资,并暗示使用“文明使命”的比喻来证明支撑这些有利可图的榨取关系的经济秩序是合理的。然而,对用于维护这些安排的信息基础设施的讨论基本上是缺席的。(270-287)例如,俄罗斯和其他国家秘密资助巴黎的报纸,以夸耀他们的内部稳定,并为友好的外交政策欢呼,以确保他们的债券有一个强劲的市场(Berenson, 1992, p. 235)。与此同时,在美国,除了《商业与金融纪事报》(Commercial and Financial Chronicle)等颂扬私有意识形态的全国性出版物外,报纸出版商不仅推动了当地的“增长机器”,还利用他们的出版物在社区腹地解释和捍卫私有意识形态。当旧金山的威廉·伦道夫·赫斯特和洛杉矶的哈里森·奥蒂斯提出军事干预的理由,以保护他们在秘鲁和墨西哥的投资时(布雷钦,1999;金正日,2019)。商业记者和公关人员是金融理论家的一个重要派别,他们通常不像其他记者那样追求方法论上的客观性,在发布统计数据、编辑金融杂志、撰写建议专栏和演讲之间来回穿梭。1865年创刊的《商业与金融纪事报》(Commercial and Financial Chronicle)周报既是首选的统计数据提供者,也是“财产安全”的坚定倡导者。记者将专业团体的内部原理和假设转化为可以在更广泛的文化中解释和证明为规范的论点(Ryant, 1989;尖塔,2002)。鉴于两次世界大战之间的高度不平等,面对越来越多的对专有意识形态承诺的怀疑,这种意识形态工作变得尤为重要(Knight, 2016;奥沙利文,2016;皮凯蒂,2020,特别是291-294)。例如,茱莉亚·奥特(Julia Ott)展示了纽约证券交易所(NYSE)领导人在第一次世界大战后如何寻求建立一种理念,即广泛的证券所有权是触手可及的,并将创造一种“投资者民主”,其优点取代并可能取代政府对商业和公司金融的监管(Ott, 2011, pp. 130-136)。一个更直接的例子是,艾萨克·马丁(Isaac Martin)对1924-1925年“税收俱乐部”运动的描述是,受薪的激进分子j·a·阿诺德(J. a . Arnold)在德克萨斯州创建了一个由小镇精英组成的联盟,以支持一项重大的联邦减税计划,该联盟的最大受益者是富有的东部人。结合“民粹主义策略和激进的反平等主义要求”,运动积极分子,通常是地方银行官员,预计减税将使他们自己的证券比政府补贴债券更有吸引力,但他们的论点是基于业主的理由,坚持减税将确保资金“被释放出来投资于生产性企业”。该运动成功地向国会施压,1926年税率大幅削减,代表了最富有的美国人的胜利(Martin, 2013, 44-67,引语第58页)。尽管取得了这场胜利,但仅仅十年后,大萧条和新政的迅速实施对业主主义理论家造成了深刻的冲击,动摇了他们对目标必然胜利的信念。正如Ott所解释的那样,纽交所领导人在他们的传统共和党支持者和种族隔离主义的南方民主党人之间组建了一个新的参议院联盟,以保护资本利得的优惠税收待遇,以金融资产“以流动性为中心的自由愿景”的名义,通过印刷小册子和广播新媒体广泛部署他们的论点(Ott, 2019,第105页)。皮凯蒂强调的是罗斯福新政,而不是资产阶级意识形态,这意味着他错过了解释这一联盟如何成为新资产阶级意识形态的跳板的机会。像威廉·f·巴克利(William F. Buckley)和伦纳德·里德(Leonard Read)这样的组织者建立了保守派媒体和明确的政治专业组织,以减少税收和废除可能抑制利润最大化的法规为事业。为了满足迅速发展的政府和战后消费社会的需求,从管理顾问和政府承包商到被安利(Amway)等公司吸引的“企业家”,再到沃尔玛(Wal-Mart)的服务业工人,这些人融合了福音派和“亲市场”价值观,通过对新职业的精英主义呼吁,这些企业得以重新焕发活力并扩大规模。
Financial professionals and the formation of proprietarian ideology
This review essay on economist Thomas Piketty's Capital and Ideology argues that the role of financial professionals as ideologues is a necessary yet missing component of Piketty's analysis. Using the history of capitalism in the United States as a connective thread, the essay synthesizes examples from a broad array of studies to trace the role of financial professionals from the counting houses of early republic New Orleans and New York through the professionalization of stockbrokers and investment bankers in the late-19th century Gilded Age to modern-day Wall Street white-collar workers. Throughout U.S. history financial professionals and their allied media institutions have been ubiquitous and essential advocates for a “proprietarian” ideology which prioritizes the sanctity of property rights over ameliorating inequality.
Thomas Piketty's Capital and Ideology offers a sprawling history of how conditions of economic inequality advance or constrain human progress. Casting aside arguments that economic growth lifts all boats, Piketty urges looking instead to political and ideological structures for a robust explanation of social development. The book's 17 chapters seek to establish a unified theory of social evolution at the nation-state level, developing a chronology and a terminology that proceeds from “ternary” systems of nobles, clerics, and peasants (a model Piketty fits to medieval and early modern societies from Western Europe to Japan) through the bourgeois capitalist regimes established in the eighteenth century and the social-democratic societies that arose in the wake of World War I, finally ending in a present-day surge in oligarchic populism that decries inequality while doing little, he argues, to reverse it. Particularly tragic, in Piketty's eyes, is that in recent history this shift has been accompanied by a “distinctive” meritocratic ideology which “blame[s] the poor for their poverty.” (Piketty, 2020, p. 710) Given Piketty's sociopolitical goals, Capital and Ideology's political vision suffers from often being free of ideologues. I argue that we might fill this gap by examining financial sector professionals as critical actors in establishing and defending “inequality regimes” (as Piketty terms them) throughout the past two centuries. Tracing the ideological work of financial professionals' in the United States from the early republic forward, I suggest we might discover fruitful continuities linking the development of new systems of capitalist knowledge in the Age of Revolutions with the social role of the present-day meritocracy.1
While Piketty's earlier book Capital in the Twenty-First Century was built on the argument that unregulated capitalism “automatically generates arbitrary and unsustainable inequalities,” (Piketty, 2014, p. 1) the villain of the sequel is not capitalism per se but “proprietarian” ideology, a way of making sense of the world and shaping a given political regime to justify these inequalities whose first premise is “the sacralization of property rights,” as explained in the new book's brief glossary (1044). The first section of the book traces a long tradition of political arguments in many parts of the world devoted to refuting the idea that elites held unique responsibilities to the polity as a whole under the social contract. The third section of Capital and Ideology describes the “Great Transformation” which saw most of the North Atlantic democracies abandon the nineteenth-century liberal variation in the face of World War I and the Great Depression, followed by the steady return of inequality under neoliberal auspices from the 1970s onward. In the present day, Piketty is anxious about a possible move to a more malevolent “market nativism” which exploits xenophobia to dampen the appeal of redistributionist policy while entrenching tax systems which privilege existing wealth. In the final chapters, Piketty seeks to argue that only “exceptional taxes on private capital” can fund the reinvigoration of social democracy and ensure progress (886–891).
Piketty, in other words, is interested in capital—whether vested in control over economic outputs through ownership rights or represented in the (usually monetized) returns on those outputs, rather than capitalism—the systems of extraction, negotiation, coercion, and cooperation that produce those returns and ownership structures (Levy, 2017). Piketty devotes particular attention to French history to examine the intertwining of income inequality and the defense of property rights. In the fourth chapter, he offers a counterintuitive argument that the French Revolution, notwithstanding the toppling of the monarchy and the landowning nobility, entrenched property relationships more firmly than they had ever been before by severing ownership (particularly of land) from civil authority, enhancing the legitimacy of “modern property rights.” (105) The removal of “privileges and charges” and “establish[ing] equal access to different occupations and to property rights” were considered sufficient to ensure the desired goal of an egalitarian society (118). Changes in the sources of wealth of the country's largest fortunes, and the absence of political pressure to redistribute the country's prosperity through the tax code, however, meant that by the late nineteenth century income inequality had already risen to levels like those of the pre-revolutionary era. Nonetheless it was important for Third Republic politicians to insist that France was “a country of ‘smallholders’” (139) yet Piketty's detailed quantitative studies of income and property show the distribution of wealth barely budged for the poorest 90% of the country from 1780 until 1910, and that their cumulative total rarely reached above 50% of income or 20% of property (130–131).
In shifting focus from capitalism to property, Piketty seeks to trace the longer history of the ideological argument that the social conditions capitalism creates can be justified by the resulting distribution of property. Piketty describes ideology as “attempts… to impose meaning” from above. To study ideology, he focuses on formal political speech, found in party platforms and governmental debates; he also turns to “theorists and political actors to see how inequalities were justified.” (14) His attention is drawn most, as in the 11th chapter (the book's longest), to those political parties which were in the vanguard of creating the “incomplete equality” regimes that triumphed in Western democracies in the mid-twentieth century, from the German Social Democratic Party to the Democratic Party in the United States to the workers' parties of Scandinavia (486–508). Piketty is clearly more sympathetic to these political groups, and seems fascinated, for example, by the transformations that have taken the Democrats from a party dominated by southern slaveholders to the vehicle for supplanting the inequality regime of industrial ownership societies through the New Deal to, eventually, a party of the “brahmin left” identified with “serving the interests of the highly educated rather than the disadvantaged.” (834).
This choice of focus, however, means that attentiveness to the conditions of inequality proprietarian ideology creates in everyday life, and how these conditions hold together a broad coalition of supporters, is largely missing. The lack of this analysis seems to be an important gap in Piketty's mission to overturn inequality in mass-suffrage societies. At the end of the book, he offers an outline of a new “participatory socialism” (1016–1022) operating through government action alongside transformations in workforce relationships, judicial systems, and global institutions to overturn the prevailing inequality regime. An analysis of how what might be called “proprietarian” coalitions” are assembled would seem to be an important task to determine what set of political conditions might overturn proprietarian ideology. Without understanding how political movements which prioritize the preservation of the wealth and privilege of a tiny elite organize larger followings, it seems likely Piketty's political mission will fail.
Building political power and momentum for proprietarian coalitions depends, in other words, on ideologues. I would argue that we can find these ideologues who are so important for Piketty's argument if we focus on the financial professionals and clerks who mediated global and local exchange. By “financial professionals” I mean actors as varied as the attorneys of the bankruptcy bar, the stockbrokers who developed new genres of literature to reach potential investors, the real estate agents who facilitated international property development schemes and pioneered local housing markets, and the mortgage bankers who created new forms of securitized finance (Coffee, 2006; Glotzer, 2020; Hornstein, 2005; Hyman, 2011; Knight, 2016; Ott, 2011; Skeel, 2001). Financial professionals' livelihood depended on innovation with respect to property: they were ever developing new instruments to represent claims on property and new ways of negotiating, verifying, and asserting these claims. Self-interest led them to be the vanguard of the proprietarian coalition. Financial professionals' reliance on income from intangible services and fees for dealing in abstract negotiable instruments paradoxically reinforced their devotion to proprietarian ideology.
The appeal of proprietarian ideology to financial professionals can be traced back to the information problems of bourgeois capitalism in the Atlantic world. Absentee ownership of slave plantations, long-distance trade relationships, and interregional land development schemes all required investors to place significant trust in their partners and subordinates. Under these conditions, information asymmetries acted as a form of property; the ability to sell or trade “secrets” was an important element of building trust relationships that might lead to future profitable cooperation. The expertise necessary to keep accurate, reliable accounts, and the use of account books as a form of oversight, created a precarious dependence between business collaborators who might be separated by thousands of miles and communicated only over the course of weeks or months (Ditz, 2000; Rosenthal, 2018). Global reputation networks built on hierarchies of place knit together global ports and backwater outposts, ranging in scale from multi-branch banking houses to solitary speculators. From the circulation of information hierarchies of merit in turn emerged, adhering to individuals and eventually quantified in the records of credit agencies (Baskin, 1988; Beckert, 2014; Olegario, 2006).
An account of proprietarian meritocracy in the United States might begin with considering how the early American republic, like the post-French revolution political settlement, sought to preserve property rights while removing “privileges and charges” and equalizing occupational opportunities. In practice, this depended on protecting investors who financed capitalist projects while encouraging a new cadre of risk-bearing entrepreneurs. Investors benefited from what Woody Holton has described as the “procreditor” Constitution, which ensured they would be able to recoup their loans by emboldening federal courts to strike down debtors' relief legislation (Holton, 2018). The launching of the new political system crystallized meritocracy along racial lines; in other words, rather than Piketty's argument that meritocracy arose in the industrial era “to justify social differences on the basis of individual abilities,” (710) the intertwining of ideas about racial capacity and economic capacity shaped a hierarchical vision of society which could encompass a wide range of prejudices from the individual merchant to the debt practices of foreign nations (Flandreau, 2016; Garrett-Scott, 2019; O’Malley, 2012; White, 2015).
In the borderlands of bourgeois capitalism, ideologies of personal and financial risk were intertwined with the implantation of an economic culture arranged around finance. Opportunistic speculators in the Deep South benefited from the willingness of investors from Boston to Britain to fund land speculation and benefited from social hierarchies in the early republic that eased their infiltration as economic actors, enabling them to swindle native Creek families and other Indians who obtained little redress from the federal government (Saunt, 2019). The availability of credit and access to social networks to negotiate problems and overcome business stumbles were deeply rooted in ideologies which favored white, Protestant men, yet even among white men merit could be framed in embodied terms: as Kathryn Olivarius explains, “immunocapital” accrued to New Orleans businessmen who had survived yellow fever and served as “an explanatory tool for success or failure in commodity capitalism.” Northern clerks similarly measured their physical and digestive health against their peers to index their chances for success, with institutions like the Young Men's Christian Association providing opportunities for physical self-improvement alongside moral improvement (Lupkin, 2010; Olegario, 2006; Olivarius, 2019, quote p. 442; Zakim, 2018). The racially embodied meritocracy would continue to be an important component of career success even as new technologies like the telegram and the stock ticker modified the geographic scope of capitalism, and the scale of the potential profits, while the types of expertise men were expected to deploy in pursuit of such opportunities became more and more specialized. Eventually, embodied meritocracy would be transformed into educational meritocracy through the propagation of the undergraduate “college man,” preferably an athlete, as the ideal “corporate professional” (Bjelopera, 2005; Clark, 2010; Davis, 2000).
An increasing number and variety of experts held themselves out as agents who could help resolve principals' monitoring problems. Professional associations provided one way of overcoming the problem of a proliferating number of experts while simultaneously serving as a launchpad for proprietarian coalitions. Members of these associations sought to establish their credibility through the production of broadly-circulating representations, or “technologies of trust” as Marc Flandreau has phrased it, creating forums for demonstrating and recognizing each other as honorable, reliable men. Because questions of how knowledge would be divided amongst different experts were still up for grabs, these associations were often marked by conjunctions of expertise which seem incongruous from present-day perspective: the Anthropological Society of London, for example, also served as a nexus point for the creation of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, an organization established by “debt vultures” to win British government backing for their campaigns to restructure payments on distressed foreign debt on profitable terms. The affinity between the two associations was derived from the idea that the kind of knowledge necessary for understanding foreign cultures was congruent with the kind of knowledge necessary for understanding foreign finance (Flandreau, 2016).
Placing the financial sector at the center of the analysis of Capital and Ideology would make clearer the emergence of global hierarchies of merit. The expansion of capitalism depended on agents who commanded increasingly specialized bodies of knowledge, such as geologists advising on the location of lucrative coal and oil deposits (Lucier, 2008). The telegraph and the creation of a global communication infrastructure transformed capitalism by enabling an exponential shift in the projection of information across long distances and the scale of financial markets. It enabled communities of investors to congregate in newly imagined spaces and facilitated oversight across oceans and continents, whether British families invested in Baltimore real estate or American bankers who reshaped the Caribbean sugar industry (Glotzer, 2020; Hudson, 2017). New professions such as accountancy developed and the status hierarchy within existing professions, such as law, reshuffled as the most lucrative incomes were gathered by law firms whose senior partners specialized in putting together complex merger agreements and banking syndicate contracts while their entry-level associates fought to quash cases involving minimum wages, injury compensation, and social welfare more broadly in the name of protecting property rights (Auerbach, 1976; Preda, 2009; Wilkins, 1989).
Economic growth within the United States also changed the hierarchy of relationships between different parts of the country. A larger number of financial centers developed but their orientation toward New York City grew over time. Increasing industrial prosperity threw off larger and larger profits, enabling the wealthiest investors and entrepreneurs to step aside from active management while generating salaries for an ever-wider range of professionals who asserted and protected claims on property. Bank directors in large cities no longer evaluated borrowers themselves but turned to credit experts; bank officials also made common cause with small-town commercial associations to win stronger creditor protections in the 1898 federal bankruptcy act. After the law's passage, credit professionals shared techniques to ensure debts were collected and that those who had not respected property rights were punished for failing “to protect the sanctity of the credit relation” (Hansen, 1998; Lamoreaux, 1994; Skeel, 2001; Smith, 2010, quotation p. 218).
The widening and deepening of financial professional communities was matched in other professional sectors, such as medicine, creating opportunities for financial professionals to make alliances and expand the proprietarian coalition. All professionals faced the fact that much or all of their “capital” was their intangible intellect. The proliferation of professional associations made it possible to convert this intellectual property (so to speak) into state-sanctioned credentialing systems (licensing authorities, medical boards, etc.) with barriers to entry that preserved their advantages. In medicine and other fields these practices typically replicated existing hierarchies of gender and race (Schafer, 2014; Wiebe, 1962). Many elite financiers used philanthropy to preserve white, Protestant men's places in the colleges producing the new professional meritocracy, as Susie Pak has shown using the example of Thomas Lamont of J.P. Morgan & Co.; indeed, young college men could be found intervening as strikebreakers to uphold proprietarian ideology (Norwood, 2002; Pak, 2013). Professionals increasingly saw themselves as part of a worldwide meritocracy and used international expositions and literature exchanges as opportunities to circulate ideas for both reform and self-protection (Rosenberg, 2012). Financial professionals were key advocates for proprietarian ideology because its abstract premises dovetailed with their pragmatic priorities of protecting assets from taxation and promoting government policies to ensure asset liquidity—and thus transaction fees (Allen, 2015; Hansen, 2009).
From time to time Piketty catches sight of the importance of systems of professional knowledge for creating and justifying global systems of inequality. Examining the portfolio composition of the top 1% of French estates during the belle époque, for example, Piketty notes the preponderance of foreign investment, including in French colonies, and alludes to the use of the mission civilisatrice trope to justify the economic order undergirding these profitable extractive relationships. A discussion of the information infrastructure used to defend these arrangements, however, is largely absent. (270–287) Russia and other nations, for example, secretly subsidized Paris newspapers to pontificate on their internal stability and cheer on a friendly foreign policy to ensure a robust market for their bonds (Berenson, 1992, p. 235). In the United States, meanwhile, alongside national publications like the Commercial and Financial Chronicle which celebrated proprietary ideology, newspaper publishers not only boosted local “growth machines” but also used their publications to explain and defend proprietarian ideology in their community's hinterlands, as when William Randolph Hearst in San Francisco and Harrison Otis in Los Angeles made the case for military intervention to protect their Peruvian and Mexican investments (Brechin, 1999; Kim, 2019).
Business journalists and publicists were an important faction of financial ideologues, generally avoiding other reporters' embrace of methodological objectivity and slipping back and forth between publishing statistics, editing financial magazines, writing advice columns, and lecturing. The weekly Commercial and Financial Chronicle, launched in 1865, was both the statistical supplier of choice and a steadfast advocate for “security of property.” Journalists transformed the internal rationales and assumptions of professional communities into arguments that could be explained and justified as normative in the broader culture (Ryant, 1989; Steeples, 2002). This ideological work became particularly important in the face of growing skepticism about proprietarian ideology's promises given the high inequality of the interwar years (Knight, 2016; O’Sullivan, 2016; Piketty, 2020, esp. 291–294). Julia Ott shows, for example, how New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) leaders sought after World War I to establish the idea that widespread securities ownership was within reach and would create a “investors' democracy” whose virtues superseded and could displace government regulation of business and corporate finance (Ott, 2011, pp. 130–136). In a more direct example, Isaac Martin's account of the 1924–1925 “tax clubs” movement describes the paid activist J. A. Arnold's creation of a coalition of small-town elites in Texas to support a significant federal tax cut whose greatest beneficiaries were wealthy Easterners. Combining “populist tactics and militant anti-egalitarian demands,” movement activists, often local bank officials, anticipated the tax cut would make their own securities more attractive than government-subsidized bonds but made their arguments on proprietarian grounds, insisting the tax cut would ensure money was “released for investment in productive enterprises.” The campaign successfully pressured Congress and rates were slashed in 1926, representing a triumph for the richest Americans (Martin, 2013, 44–67, quote p. 58).
Despite this victory, barely a decade later the Great Depression and the rapid implementation of the New Deal created a profound shock for proprietarian ideologues, shaking them from their belief in the inevitable triumph of their goals. As Ott explains, NYSE leaders assembled a new Senate alliance between their traditional Republican backers and segregationist Southern Democrats to protect the preferential tax treatment of capital gains in the name of “a vision of freedom that centered… [on] the liquidity” of financial assets, deploying their argument widely through both print pamphlets and the new medium of radio (Ott, 2019, p. 105). Piketty's emphasis on the New Deal rather than the proprietarian ideologues means he misses an opportunity to explain how this alliance became the launchpad for neo-proprietarian ideology. Organizers like William F. Buckley and Leonard Read built conservative media and explicitly political professional organizations that took up the cause of rolling back taxation and rescinding regulations that might inhibit profit maximization. The proprietarian coalition was able to reinvigorate and expand by making a meritocratic appeal to new professions established to meet the demands of the burgeoning government and the postwar consumer society, from management consultants and government contractors to “entrepreneurs” drawn to companies like Amway and service-industry workers at Wal-Mart who melded evangelical and “promarket” values. The invention and valorization of an American tradition of “free enterprise” was critical to this project, arguably culminating in the success of the former business spokesmen Ronald Reagan and Donald Trump in their respective presidential runs and their aggressive rollbacks of taxes on the wealthy (888–889) (Glickman, 2019; McKenna, 2006; Mondom, 2018; Moreton, 2009; Phillips-Fein, 2009). Nonetheless financial professionals remain central to this project; indeed the Wall Street Journal's editorial section today arguably fills the same role as the Commercial and Financial Chronicle in the past as the most prominent media advocate for proprietarian ideology.
“There is never anything ‘natural’ about social inequality,” Piketty declares after summarizing elite-dominated regimes from Japan to Iran to China. “It is always profoundly ideological and political.” (411) Just because the fall and now rise again of inequality is not a “natural” process, however, does not exclude the possibility that the professionals whose labor is at the heart of its perpetuation do not see their participation as natural. Karen Ho's ethnography of present-day financial workers, Liquidated, examines the worldviews of young professionals who have transitioned from elite universities into entry-level jobs on Wall Street. Poised on the lower rungs of the meritocracy, Ho notes that young workers quickly internalize the logic of “downsizing” and “rightsizing” workers laboring in retail and manufacturing in part because of their own experience of a rapidly churning job market (though with a much more comfortable safety net) (Ho, 2009). Bringing a historically-minded approach to how such values permeate through professional cultures not as false consciousness but as a sincere response to precarious conditions may be an important step for those seeking to organize against and overturn the prevailing crisis of wealth inequality.