公共开发银行的产业政策和风险分担:欧洲投资银行和EFSI应对新冠疫情的经验教训

IF 0.2 4区 经济学 Q4 ECONOMICS
S. Griffith‐Jones, Natalya Naqvi
{"title":"公共开发银行的产业政策和风险分担:欧洲投资银行和EFSI应对新冠疫情的经验教训","authors":"S. Griffith‐Jones, Natalya Naqvi","doi":"10.33776/rem.v0i59.5258","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The European Investment Bank (EIB) and European Investment Fund (EIF) have been key partners in implementing the Juncker Plan (EFSI) (2015–2020), which aims to increase lending to economically or socially valuable projects too risky to receive private finance through leveraging scarce budgetary resources, and going forward will play an important role in the EU’s post-COVID industrial policy response. In order to evaluate these initiatives, we: 1) distinguish between “real economy” risks arising from natural uncertainty relating to investments in certain types of projects or sectors and “financial” risks that are related to financial products or intermediaries themselves, and create the danger of subsidising the profits of private investors while socialising their risk of losses; and 2) outline the trade-off between increased leverage and policy steer and control over projects due to the number of intermediaries involved, and the need to make projects attractive for private investors. We argue that EFSI has made significant achievements, including enabling the EIB and EIF to provide long-term finance in the post-crisis period and to take more “real economy” risk, leading to valuable investments that would otherwise have not taken place. However, member states’ budgetary constraints have created incentives for EFSI to focus excessively on increasing leverage, at the expense of policy steer. Furthermore, the use of complex financial products and opaque pricing methods with terms too generous for private investors has in some cases generated excessive “financial risk” at the expense of “real economy risk”. In order to increase investment in the real economy and play a role in structural transformation, the EIB’s post-COVID response must have a greater focus on the final beneficiaries of projects rather than on the private financial intermediaries themselves. In those cases where it is necessary to use intermediaries, performance related conditionalities should be strictly enforced to have greater control over projects. 1 We would like to thank Helen Kavvadia, Matthias Thiemann, Daniel Mertens, Camila Villard Duran and Peter Volberding for comments on earlier drafts. We gratefully acknowledge financial and intellectual insights from FEPS, especially from Laszlo Andor and David Rinaldi Page 1 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford Page 2 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 Table of contents Introduction 3 I. A framework for evaluating risk sharing in public development banks 4 II. The EIB, EFSI and InvestEU 6 III. Instruments used in EFSI 10 IV. Relationship with financial intermediaries and private investors 17 V. Conclusion: Achievements, risks and lessons for the EIB’s post-COVID response 22 References 24 List of interviews 26 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford Page 3 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 Introduction In the wake of the financial crisis of 2007/09, and the Eurozone debt crisis of 2009/10, there has been renewed support for public regional and national development banks, as the limitations and problems of a purely private financial sector have become more evident to different strands of economic thinking (Griffith-Jones and Ocampo, 2018). In this context, the European Investment Bank Group (EIB), with its long track record of successfully playing a key and large role in funding intra-European infrastructure, including renewable energy, SMEs and innovation, has taken on renewed importance. The EIB and European Investment Fund (EIF) have been key partners in implementing the post-crisis Juncker Plan (EFSI) (2015–2020), a EUR 33.5bn guarantee from the EU and EIB budgets, which aims to increase lending to economically or socially valuable projects too risky to receive private finance through leveraging scarce budgetary resources. Following the 2020 COVID crisis, the EIB plans to take an important role in the joint EU Response package, including through its implementation of an expanded InvestEU guarantee of EUR 75bn which reportedly aims to mobilise a preliminary estimate of EUR 1000bn in investment, and creation of a new industrial policy oriented strategic European investment window2. In order to evaluate the EIB’s activities under EFSI and draw lessons for its response to COVID, we distinguish between “real economy” risks arising from natural uncertainty relating to investments in certain types of projects or sectors and “financial” risks that are related to financial products or intermediaries themselves, and create the danger of subsidising the profits of private investors while socialising their risk of losses. We then outline the trade-off between increased leverage and policy steer and control over projects due to the number of intermediaries involved, and the need to make projects attractive for private investors. We argue that EFSI has made significant achievements, including enabling the EIB and EIF to provide long-term finance in the post-crisis period, and to take more “real economy” risk, leading to valuable real economy investments that would otherwise have not taken place. However, member states’ budgetary constraints have created incentives for EFSI to focus excessively on increasing leverage at the expense of policy steer. Furthermore, the use of complex financial products and opaque pricing methods with terms too generous for private investors has in some cases generated excessive “financial risk” at the expense of “real economy risk”. In order to increase investment in the real economy and play an effective role in European industrial policy, it is important that the EIB’s post-COVID response has a greater focus on the final beneficiaries of projects rather than on the private financial intermediaries themselves. In those cases where it is necessary to use intermediaries, 2 https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/qanda_20_947 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford performance-related conditionalities should be enforced to have greater control over projects. The paper proceeds as follows. In part I we outline an analytical framework for evaluating these initiatives. In part II we give some background on the EIB’s historical evolution before discussing its post-2008 activities. In part III we detail EFSI’s leverage mechanism and the instruments and financial products it uses, in order to illustrate the tradeoffs between financial and real economy risk, and leverage and policy steer. Finally, in part IV we discuss the distribution of risks of losses and profits between public and private actors and put forward a framework by which to assess the consequences of risk sharing arrangements. We conclude by discussing the implications for the EIB’s post-COVID response. I. A framework for evaluating risk sharing in public development banks In evaluating the types of instruments these initiatives use to finance investment, two related issues emerge. The first concerns the types of risks various instruments entail for the public sector. The second concerns the trade-off between increasing loan volume through leverage and policy steer3. Analytical framework for risk taking There is a key distinction on the nature of risk that is essential to clarify, both from an analytical point of view and a policy perspective. This should be important to evaluate initiatives like EFSI and InvestEU. There is first the “real economy” type of risks; these are basically related to the natural uncertainty related to projects or sectors. These are typical: 1) in infrastructure projects, as discussed for example in Griffith-Jones, 1993 (eg risks of construction difficulties and delays, especially in engineering ambitious projects, like the Channel Tunnel). We illustrate this in Box 1 below, with an offshore wind example, funded by EFSI; 2) Such “real economy” risks are also very prevalent in the funding of innovative companies, such as start-ups, often based on potentially excellent ideas, but lacking assets for guarantees and/or track record; 3) Financing of SMEs is generally considered more risky in most countries, except in countries – like Germany – with very decentralised banking systems, which allow for a greater knowledge of companies, thus reducing asymmetries of information (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981), and a long tradition of broadly successful lending to SMEs. SME financing becomes more risky if financial crises happen, when the benefits of diversification are reduced; 4) Very importantly, “real economy” risks can also relate to sectorial or crosssectorial innovation that may lead to major increases in productivity and/or significant 3 Because EFSI is recent, and because many of the projects have long maturities, the full impact of which will only be known in longer term, it is hard to determine concretely at this stage what the full economic and budgetary implications are. Nonetheless, in this paper we attempt to delineate a framework for assessing likely results. Page 4 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford Page 5 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020","PeriodicalId":44512,"journal":{"name":"Revista De Economia Mundial","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.2000,"publicationDate":"2021-09-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"6","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Industrial Policy and Risk Sharing in Public Development Banks: Lessons for the Post- COVID Response from the EIB and EFSI\",\"authors\":\"S. Griffith‐Jones, Natalya Naqvi\",\"doi\":\"10.33776/rem.v0i59.5258\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"The European Investment Bank (EIB) and European Investment Fund (EIF) have been key partners in implementing the Juncker Plan (EFSI) (2015–2020), which aims to increase lending to economically or socially valuable projects too risky to receive private finance through leveraging scarce budgetary resources, and going forward will play an important role in the EU’s post-COVID industrial policy response. In order to evaluate these initiatives, we: 1) distinguish between “real economy” risks arising from natural uncertainty relating to investments in certain types of projects or sectors and “financial” risks that are related to financial products or intermediaries themselves, and create the danger of subsidising the profits of private investors while socialising their risk of losses; and 2) outline the trade-off between increased leverage and policy steer and control over projects due to the number of intermediaries involved, and the need to make projects attractive for private investors. We argue that EFSI has made significant achievements, including enabling the EIB and EIF to provide long-term finance in the post-crisis period and to take more “real economy” risk, leading to valuable investments that would otherwise have not taken place. However, member states’ budgetary constraints have created incentives for EFSI to focus excessively on increasing leverage, at the expense of policy steer. Furthermore, the use of complex financial products and opaque pricing methods with terms too generous for private investors has in some cases generated excessive “financial risk” at the expense of “real economy risk”. In order to increase investment in the real economy and play a role in structural transformation, the EIB’s post-COVID response must have a greater focus on the final beneficiaries of projects rather than on the private financial intermediaries themselves. In those cases where it is necessary to use intermediaries, performance related conditionalities should be strictly enforced to have greater control over projects. 1 We would like to thank Helen Kavvadia, Matthias Thiemann, Daniel Mertens, Camila Villard Duran and Peter Volberding for comments on earlier drafts. We gratefully acknowledge financial and intellectual insights from FEPS, especially from Laszlo Andor and David Rinaldi Page 1 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford Page 2 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 Table of contents Introduction 3 I. A framework for evaluating risk sharing in public development banks 4 II. The EIB, EFSI and InvestEU 6 III. Instruments used in EFSI 10 IV. Relationship with financial intermediaries and private investors 17 V. Conclusion: Achievements, risks and lessons for the EIB’s post-COVID response 22 References 24 List of interviews 26 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford Page 3 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 Introduction In the wake of the financial crisis of 2007/09, and the Eurozone debt crisis of 2009/10, there has been renewed support for public regional and national development banks, as the limitations and problems of a purely private financial sector have become more evident to different strands of economic thinking (Griffith-Jones and Ocampo, 2018). In this context, the European Investment Bank Group (EIB), with its long track record of successfully playing a key and large role in funding intra-European infrastructure, including renewable energy, SMEs and innovation, has taken on renewed importance. The EIB and European Investment Fund (EIF) have been key partners in implementing the post-crisis Juncker Plan (EFSI) (2015–2020), a EUR 33.5bn guarantee from the EU and EIB budgets, which aims to increase lending to economically or socially valuable projects too risky to receive private finance through leveraging scarce budgetary resources. Following the 2020 COVID crisis, the EIB plans to take an important role in the joint EU Response package, including through its implementation of an expanded InvestEU guarantee of EUR 75bn which reportedly aims to mobilise a preliminary estimate of EUR 1000bn in investment, and creation of a new industrial policy oriented strategic European investment window2. In order to evaluate the EIB’s activities under EFSI and draw lessons for its response to COVID, we distinguish between “real economy” risks arising from natural uncertainty relating to investments in certain types of projects or sectors and “financial” risks that are related to financial products or intermediaries themselves, and create the danger of subsidising the profits of private investors while socialising their risk of losses. We then outline the trade-off between increased leverage and policy steer and control over projects due to the number of intermediaries involved, and the need to make projects attractive for private investors. We argue that EFSI has made significant achievements, including enabling the EIB and EIF to provide long-term finance in the post-crisis period, and to take more “real economy” risk, leading to valuable real economy investments that would otherwise have not taken place. However, member states’ budgetary constraints have created incentives for EFSI to focus excessively on increasing leverage at the expense of policy steer. Furthermore, the use of complex financial products and opaque pricing methods with terms too generous for private investors has in some cases generated excessive “financial risk” at the expense of “real economy risk”. In order to increase investment in the real economy and play an effective role in European industrial policy, it is important that the EIB’s post-COVID response has a greater focus on the final beneficiaries of projects rather than on the private financial intermediaries themselves. In those cases where it is necessary to use intermediaries, 2 https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/qanda_20_947 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford performance-related conditionalities should be enforced to have greater control over projects. The paper proceeds as follows. In part I we outline an analytical framework for evaluating these initiatives. In part II we give some background on the EIB’s historical evolution before discussing its post-2008 activities. In part III we detail EFSI’s leverage mechanism and the instruments and financial products it uses, in order to illustrate the tradeoffs between financial and real economy risk, and leverage and policy steer. Finally, in part IV we discuss the distribution of risks of losses and profits between public and private actors and put forward a framework by which to assess the consequences of risk sharing arrangements. We conclude by discussing the implications for the EIB’s post-COVID response. I. A framework for evaluating risk sharing in public development banks In evaluating the types of instruments these initiatives use to finance investment, two related issues emerge. The first concerns the types of risks various instruments entail for the public sector. The second concerns the trade-off between increasing loan volume through leverage and policy steer3. Analytical framework for risk taking There is a key distinction on the nature of risk that is essential to clarify, both from an analytical point of view and a policy perspective. This should be important to evaluate initiatives like EFSI and InvestEU. There is first the “real economy” type of risks; these are basically related to the natural uncertainty related to projects or sectors. These are typical: 1) in infrastructure projects, as discussed for example in Griffith-Jones, 1993 (eg risks of construction difficulties and delays, especially in engineering ambitious projects, like the Channel Tunnel). We illustrate this in Box 1 below, with an offshore wind example, funded by EFSI; 2) Such “real economy” risks are also very prevalent in the funding of innovative companies, such as start-ups, often based on potentially excellent ideas, but lacking assets for guarantees and/or track record; 3) Financing of SMEs is generally considered more risky in most countries, except in countries – like Germany – with very decentralised banking systems, which allow for a greater knowledge of companies, thus reducing asymmetries of information (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981), and a long tradition of broadly successful lending to SMEs. SME financing becomes more risky if financial crises happen, when the benefits of diversification are reduced; 4) Very importantly, “real economy” risks can also relate to sectorial or crosssectorial innovation that may lead to major increases in productivity and/or significant 3 Because EFSI is recent, and because many of the projects have long maturities, the full impact of which will only be known in longer term, it is hard to determine concretely at this stage what the full economic and budgetary implications are. Nonetheless, in this paper we attempt to delineate a framework for assessing likely results. Page 4 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford Page 5 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020\",\"PeriodicalId\":44512,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Revista De Economia Mundial\",\"volume\":\" \",\"pages\":\"\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.2000,\"publicationDate\":\"2021-09-23\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"6\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Revista De Economia Mundial\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"96\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.33776/rem.v0i59.5258\",\"RegionNum\":4,\"RegionCategory\":\"经济学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q4\",\"JCRName\":\"ECONOMICS\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Revista De Economia Mundial","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.33776/rem.v0i59.5258","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q4","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6

摘要

为了评估欧洲投资银行在EFSI下的活动,并为其应对新冠肺炎吸取教训,我们区分了与某些类型的项目或部门投资相关的自然不确定性产生的“实体经济”风险和与金融产品或中介机构本身相关的“金融”风险,并造成补贴私人投资者利润的危险,同时使他们的损失风险社会化。然后,我们概述了由于涉及的中介机构数量以及使项目对私人投资者具有吸引力的必要性,在增加杠杆率和政策引导和控制项目之间的权衡。我们认为,EFSI已经取得了重大成就,包括使欧洲投资银行和欧洲投资基金能够在危机后时期提供长期融资,并承担更多的“实体经济”风险,从而带来了宝贵的实体经济投资,否则这些投资是不会发生的。然而,成员国的预算限制促使EFSI过度关注增加杠杆,而牺牲了政策引导。此外,使用复杂的金融产品和不透明的定价方法,条款对私人投资者过于慷慨,在某些情况下产生了过度的“金融风险”,而牺牲了“实体经济风险”。为了增加对实体经济的投资并在欧洲产业政策中发挥有效作用,欧洲投资银行在新冠疫情后的应对措施必须更加关注项目的最终受益者,而不是私人金融中介机构本身。在需要使用中介机构的情况下,2https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/qanda_20_947牛津大学的全球经济治理方案应强制执行与绩效相关的条件,以加强对项目的控制。文件内容如下。在第一部分中,我们概述了评估这些举措的分析框架。在第二部分中,在讨论欧洲投资银行2008年后的活动之前,我们介绍了其历史演变的一些背景。在第三部分中,我们详细介绍了EFSI的杠杆机制及其使用的工具和金融产品,以说明金融和实体经济风险以及杠杆和政策引导之间的权衡。最后,在第四部分中,我们讨论了公共和私人行为者之间的损失和利润风险分配,并提出了一个评估风险分担安排后果的框架。最后,我们讨论了欧洲投资银行应对新冠疫情后的影响。I.评估公共开发银行风险分担的框架在评估这些举措用于投资的工具类型时,出现了两个相关问题。第一个问题涉及各种工具给公共部门带来的风险类型。第二个问题涉及通过杠杆增加贷款量和政策导向之间的权衡3。风险承担的分析框架从分析的角度和政策的角度来看,风险的性质有一个关键的区别,这一点至关重要。这对于评估EFSI和InvestEU等举措应该很重要。首先是“实体经济”类型的风险;这些基本上与项目或部门相关的自然不确定性有关。这些是典型的:1)在基础设施项目中,例如Griffith-Jones,1993年所讨论的(例如,施工困难和延误的风险,尤其是在雄心勃勃的工程项目中,如英吉利海峡隧道)。我们在下面的方框1中说明了这一点,并以EFSI资助的海上风电为例;2) 这种“实体经济”风险在创新公司(如初创企业)的融资中也非常普遍,这些公司往往基于潜在的优秀想法,但缺乏担保资产和/或业绩记录;3) 在大多数国家,中小企业融资通常被认为风险更大,但在像德国这样银行系统非常分散的国家除外,这些国家可以更多地了解公司,从而减少信息不对称(Stiglitz和Weiss,1981),并有向中小企业提供广泛成功贷款的悠久传统。如果发生金融危机,当多样化的好处减少时,中小企业融资的风险会更大;4) 非常重要的是,“实体经济”风险也可能与部门或跨部门的创新有关,这些创新可能会导致生产力的大幅提高和/或显著的3。因为EFSI是最近才出现的,而且许多项目的到期时间很长,其全部影响只有在长期内才能知道,现阶段很难具体确定所涉全部经济和预算问题。尽管如此,在本文中,我们试图描绘一个评估可能结果的框架。 第4页,共26页公共开发银行的产业政策和风险分担:欧洲投资银行和EFSI的新冠疫情后应对经验教训–Stephany Griffith Jones和Natalya Naqvi©2020年7月/GEG WP 143牛津大学全球经济治理计划第5页,共共26页EFSI–Stephany Griffith Jones和Natalya Naqvi©2020年7月
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Industrial Policy and Risk Sharing in Public Development Banks: Lessons for the Post- COVID Response from the EIB and EFSI
The European Investment Bank (EIB) and European Investment Fund (EIF) have been key partners in implementing the Juncker Plan (EFSI) (2015–2020), which aims to increase lending to economically or socially valuable projects too risky to receive private finance through leveraging scarce budgetary resources, and going forward will play an important role in the EU’s post-COVID industrial policy response. In order to evaluate these initiatives, we: 1) distinguish between “real economy” risks arising from natural uncertainty relating to investments in certain types of projects or sectors and “financial” risks that are related to financial products or intermediaries themselves, and create the danger of subsidising the profits of private investors while socialising their risk of losses; and 2) outline the trade-off between increased leverage and policy steer and control over projects due to the number of intermediaries involved, and the need to make projects attractive for private investors. We argue that EFSI has made significant achievements, including enabling the EIB and EIF to provide long-term finance in the post-crisis period and to take more “real economy” risk, leading to valuable investments that would otherwise have not taken place. However, member states’ budgetary constraints have created incentives for EFSI to focus excessively on increasing leverage, at the expense of policy steer. Furthermore, the use of complex financial products and opaque pricing methods with terms too generous for private investors has in some cases generated excessive “financial risk” at the expense of “real economy risk”. In order to increase investment in the real economy and play a role in structural transformation, the EIB’s post-COVID response must have a greater focus on the final beneficiaries of projects rather than on the private financial intermediaries themselves. In those cases where it is necessary to use intermediaries, performance related conditionalities should be strictly enforced to have greater control over projects. 1 We would like to thank Helen Kavvadia, Matthias Thiemann, Daniel Mertens, Camila Villard Duran and Peter Volberding for comments on earlier drafts. We gratefully acknowledge financial and intellectual insights from FEPS, especially from Laszlo Andor and David Rinaldi Page 1 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford Page 2 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 Table of contents Introduction 3 I. A framework for evaluating risk sharing in public development banks 4 II. The EIB, EFSI and InvestEU 6 III. Instruments used in EFSI 10 IV. Relationship with financial intermediaries and private investors 17 V. Conclusion: Achievements, risks and lessons for the EIB’s post-COVID response 22 References 24 List of interviews 26 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford Page 3 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 Introduction In the wake of the financial crisis of 2007/09, and the Eurozone debt crisis of 2009/10, there has been renewed support for public regional and national development banks, as the limitations and problems of a purely private financial sector have become more evident to different strands of economic thinking (Griffith-Jones and Ocampo, 2018). In this context, the European Investment Bank Group (EIB), with its long track record of successfully playing a key and large role in funding intra-European infrastructure, including renewable energy, SMEs and innovation, has taken on renewed importance. The EIB and European Investment Fund (EIF) have been key partners in implementing the post-crisis Juncker Plan (EFSI) (2015–2020), a EUR 33.5bn guarantee from the EU and EIB budgets, which aims to increase lending to economically or socially valuable projects too risky to receive private finance through leveraging scarce budgetary resources. Following the 2020 COVID crisis, the EIB plans to take an important role in the joint EU Response package, including through its implementation of an expanded InvestEU guarantee of EUR 75bn which reportedly aims to mobilise a preliminary estimate of EUR 1000bn in investment, and creation of a new industrial policy oriented strategic European investment window2. In order to evaluate the EIB’s activities under EFSI and draw lessons for its response to COVID, we distinguish between “real economy” risks arising from natural uncertainty relating to investments in certain types of projects or sectors and “financial” risks that are related to financial products or intermediaries themselves, and create the danger of subsidising the profits of private investors while socialising their risk of losses. We then outline the trade-off between increased leverage and policy steer and control over projects due to the number of intermediaries involved, and the need to make projects attractive for private investors. We argue that EFSI has made significant achievements, including enabling the EIB and EIF to provide long-term finance in the post-crisis period, and to take more “real economy” risk, leading to valuable real economy investments that would otherwise have not taken place. However, member states’ budgetary constraints have created incentives for EFSI to focus excessively on increasing leverage at the expense of policy steer. Furthermore, the use of complex financial products and opaque pricing methods with terms too generous for private investors has in some cases generated excessive “financial risk” at the expense of “real economy risk”. In order to increase investment in the real economy and play an effective role in European industrial policy, it is important that the EIB’s post-COVID response has a greater focus on the final beneficiaries of projects rather than on the private financial intermediaries themselves. In those cases where it is necessary to use intermediaries, 2 https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/qanda_20_947 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford performance-related conditionalities should be enforced to have greater control over projects. The paper proceeds as follows. In part I we outline an analytical framework for evaluating these initiatives. In part II we give some background on the EIB’s historical evolution before discussing its post-2008 activities. In part III we detail EFSI’s leverage mechanism and the instruments and financial products it uses, in order to illustrate the tradeoffs between financial and real economy risk, and leverage and policy steer. Finally, in part IV we discuss the distribution of risks of losses and profits between public and private actors and put forward a framework by which to assess the consequences of risk sharing arrangements. We conclude by discussing the implications for the EIB’s post-COVID response. I. A framework for evaluating risk sharing in public development banks In evaluating the types of instruments these initiatives use to finance investment, two related issues emerge. The first concerns the types of risks various instruments entail for the public sector. The second concerns the trade-off between increasing loan volume through leverage and policy steer3. Analytical framework for risk taking There is a key distinction on the nature of risk that is essential to clarify, both from an analytical point of view and a policy perspective. This should be important to evaluate initiatives like EFSI and InvestEU. There is first the “real economy” type of risks; these are basically related to the natural uncertainty related to projects or sectors. These are typical: 1) in infrastructure projects, as discussed for example in Griffith-Jones, 1993 (eg risks of construction difficulties and delays, especially in engineering ambitious projects, like the Channel Tunnel). We illustrate this in Box 1 below, with an offshore wind example, funded by EFSI; 2) Such “real economy” risks are also very prevalent in the funding of innovative companies, such as start-ups, often based on potentially excellent ideas, but lacking assets for guarantees and/or track record; 3) Financing of SMEs is generally considered more risky in most countries, except in countries – like Germany – with very decentralised banking systems, which allow for a greater knowledge of companies, thus reducing asymmetries of information (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981), and a long tradition of broadly successful lending to SMEs. SME financing becomes more risky if financial crises happen, when the benefits of diversification are reduced; 4) Very importantly, “real economy” risks can also relate to sectorial or crosssectorial innovation that may lead to major increases in productivity and/or significant 3 Because EFSI is recent, and because many of the projects have long maturities, the full impact of which will only be known in longer term, it is hard to determine concretely at this stage what the full economic and budgetary implications are. Nonetheless, in this paper we attempt to delineate a framework for assessing likely results. Page 4 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020 / GEG WP 143 The Global Economic Governance Programme University of Oxford Page 5 of 26 Industrial policy and risk sharing in public development banks: Lessons for the post-COVID response from the EIB and EFSI – Stephany Griffith-Jones and Natalya Naqvi © July 2020
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
0.90
自引率
20.00%
发文量
30
审稿时长
20 weeks
期刊介绍: a Revista de Economía Mundial (REM) ISSN: 1576-0162 es una publicación cuatrimestral editada por la Sociedad de Economía Mundial. Se trata de una Revista científica internacional que se encuentra reseñada en prestigiosos índices internacionales.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信