多样化的经济方式能让我们走多远?

IF 3 2区 社会学 Q1 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES
Georgina M. Gómez
{"title":"多样化的经济方式能让我们走多远?","authors":"Georgina M. Gómez","doi":"10.1111/dech.12762","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p><b>Julie and Katherine Gibson-Graham and Kelly Dombroski (eds), <i>The Handbook of Diverse Economies</i>. Cheltenham and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 2020. 546 pp. £ 199.80 hardback</b>.</p><p>There is a long-standing tradition of thought on human-centred and communitarian economies. It connects to a search for utopias (no lands) and udetopias (neverlands) which has accelerated with the advent of capitalism and the obsession with capital accumulation that gave the latter system its name. Intellectuals like Charles Fourier, Silvio Gesell, François Marie, Karl Marx, Robert Owen and Pierre-Joseph Proudhon were pioneers in developing social, economic and political alternatives to capitalism. They engaged with the original 16th century collectivist and utopian socialism of Sir Thomas More, which, as French sociologist Pierre Bourdieu (<span>1998</span>: 125) observed, was ‘often discredited, dismissed and ridiculed in the name of economic realism’. Drawing on this tradition, the scholarly couple Katherine Gibson and Julie Graham added the diverse economies (DE) approach three decades ago.1 Since then, it has developed into a fully-fledged research programme among scholars and a vision of social transformation among activists. The latest arrival in their scientific production <i>The Handbook of Diverse Economies</i>, is edited by J.K. Gibson-Graham and Kelly Dombroski, and the subject of this critical review.</p><p>Through capturing and valorizing the variety of economic, social and political spaces that currently proliferate in the interstices of the capitalist system, the diverse economies approach has gained considerable traction. These spaces, DE authors and followers would emphasize, are not an exercise of the imagination occurring in the no lands and neverlands of utopianism, but tangible and true sources of global hope. They are existing spaces which evade capitalism or shape resistance to it, and mobilize collectives. Underlining that building alternatives to capitalism is feasible as it is ongoing, <i>The Handbook of Diverse Economies</i> adds cases, findings and reflections, and invites analysis of the way scholars understand and write about economic alternatives.</p><p>However, as in previous works (see Gibson-Graham, <span>1996, 2008</span>), engagement with academics outside feminist, post-structural and post-development circles remains pending in this last book. While this new volume refines the contrast with neoliberal politics and the ‘crushing uniformity of mainstream circuits of value’ (Fuller et al., <span>2016</span>: xxiv), it does not meet the need to engage with other ways of theorizing alternatives to overcome the relatively marginal position of diverse economies within the dominant capitalist system. Some of the older critiques of the DE approach are explicitly addressed, but the general lack of receptiveness to criticism limits the influence of the research programme beyond the circles of supporters and partisan advocates of a post-capitalist future.</p><p>This essay begins by introducing the notion of alterity and the trajectory of utopianism, and how the diverse economies approach is situated within this tradition. It subsequently presents a critique of previous research, which is followed by a review of the new book (hereafter referred to as the handbook) and its contribution to this body of scholarly work. The essay delves into the details of what has and what has not been covered by this new addition, and its relevance to the field of development studies.</p><p>A key achievement of the diverse economies framework is that it has rekindled the debate on the notions of alternatives and alterity (Fickey, <span>2011</span>; Lee et al., <span>2004</span>). It is not a new debate, considering that the intellectual production of alternatives to capitalism has inspired humankind since the origins of capitalism itself. In line with this, contending conceptions invariably reject surplus extraction based on private property and its resulting waged employment, but they differ in their interpretation and focus of the meaning of alternative.</p><p>Gritzas and Kavoulakos (<span>2016</span>) have clustered scholarly work on alternatives to capitalism in two broad groups. The ‘utopians’ favoured the organization of a cooperative or community economy; Proudhon was among them, and to some extent, Polanyi and Gesell later followed. The sceptic camp, of which Marx and Engels are representatives, were particularly dismissive of utopian projects and their lack of ‘scientific’ reflection; they were convinced that such utopian initiatives were bound to fail (Engels, <span>1968</span>). Marx and Engels reasoned that individuals cannot change society from below because they do not have the resources to afford a life outside a waged relationship. As workers do not own or control the means of production, they are not able to access the resources needed to afford food, accommodation and meet other basic needs for survival. According to Marx and Engels, forming small networks or communities does not improve utopians’ chances of success in the long run either, because a life outside capitalism requires resources that must come from somewhere. Furthermore, if such a withdrawal from capitalism becomes the life choice of significant numbers of workers, the state would intervene to prevent a mass opt-out from the capitalist economy (North, <span>2016</span>). Subsequent orthodox Marxist scholars similarly discarded the potential of such initiatives as naïve and instead promoted full-scale radical social change that would terminate the hegemony of capitalism when the system had reached its productivity boundary. Recently, scholars have contested the sterile nature of alternative projects and suggest that in current times, the claim that utopian initiatives from below have no potential needs to be researched empirically (Gómez, <span>2018</span>; North, <span>1999, 2016</span>; Pacione, <span>1997</span>).</p><p>The scepticism of the Marxist strand eventually dominated the intellectual debate that challenged capitalism during the 20th century, consigning smaller utopian initiatives to the intellectual margins (Fuller et al., <span>2016</span>). The confrontation between socialism and capitalism resulted in the regulation of capitalist economies which in some countries led to the emergence of welfare states that redistributed economic benefits, further pushing utopian economic and political experiments to the margins (Gritzas and Kavoulakos, <span>2016</span>). With the decline of radical political economy and the rise of neoliberalism in the late 1980s, the scope for alternative thinking was lost in no lands and neverlands. Ironically, this intensified the search among academics who were not deterred by the apparent implications of small-scale practices (Holloway, <span>2010</span>). There was a dire need among scholars to find alternative economic and political practices that would bring hope against the background of hegemonic neoliberal capitalism. The search finally made progress towards the mid-1990s, when the retreat of the welfare state was being contested, new social movements such as the Zapatistas in Mexico emerged and anti-globalization protests gained momentum.</p><p>In 1996, the feminist economic geographers Katherine Gibson and Julie Graham published <i>The End of Capitalism (As We Knew it): A Feminist Critique of Political Economy</i> (Gibson-Graham, <span>1996</span>). A decade later, they collected their ideas in <i>A Postcapitalist Politics</i> (Gibson-Graham, <span>2006</span>). <i>The End of Capitalism</i> was a provocative, fresh and ground-breaking attempt to capture the efforts of various communities around the world that were building different spaces of economic and political interaction. The qualification of ‘different spaces’ applies to a varied set of non-capitalist projects as well as alternatives that directly oppose capitalism. The key analytical instrument of the DE approach is a comprehensive canvas based on grounded and weak theory. The framework presents a broad inventory of empirical practices related to enterprises, labour, transactions, property and finance to construct three loose categories or domains of economic activity: non-capitalist, capitalist and alternative to capitalist (see Table 1). In subsequent publications identifying with the approach, more examples have been added. In this way, the DE approach collected studies on a multitude of different practices around the world that facilitate the material survival of communities and the reproduction of their cultural life. The publications led to a group of scholar-activists forming the Community Economies Research Network (CERN), which engages in research, reflection and practical activities around the world.2 At the time of writing,3 <i>The End of Capitalism</i> (Gibson-Graham, <span>1996</span>) has been cited 5,350 times and Google Scholar lists 10,500 hits for the keyword ‘diverse economies’, which shows how the concept has gained in popularity in some academic and activist circles.</p><p>Intellectually, the DE approach positions itself between the utopians and the Marxists. Gibson-Graham (<span>1996, 2006</span>) define capitalism in relation to five pillars as shown in Table 1: waged labour, exploitative enterprises, private property, market exchange and interest-based finances. They contend that there are too many experiments that do not follow these five characteristics and they criticize the structuralist Marxist approaches for being ‘capitalocentric’, meaning that they ignore the immense variety of practices in the non-capitalist categories. They further argue that Marxist approaches assess capitalism with an essentialist, monolithic discourse that clouds ‘other’ economic practices that are not based either on wage labour or on exploitation. Marxist work, they claim, describes capitalism with ‘totalising concepts and machine-like metaphors’ (Jonas, <span>2016</span>: 6) to express its domination over non-capitalist spaces. As these practices go unnoticed and are treated as unworthy of consideration, the Marxist narrative would endorse the belief that non-capitalist projects are too small, marginal and irrelevant to achieve any systemic transformation. According to Gibson-Graham (<span>1996</span>), keeping non-capitalist projects hidden or invisible makes them appear irrelevant and powerless, thereby silencing existing diversity and further preventing the imagining of non-capitalist futures. The capacity to see diversity is thus impaired and part of the DE project is precisely to construct another dictionary to discuss and analyse alterity.</p><p>The point of departure of the approach, that non-capitalist economic systems have remained invisible, calls for further discussion. Radical political economy scholars have examined these different economies within capitalism but based on the assumptions that they are subordinate subsystems of the capitalist economy, which sustains them to secure its own survival, and that they lack autonomy as alternative economic projects (Jonas, <span>2016</span>). For example, radical development geographer Milton Santos (<span>1977</span>) posited the theory of spatial dialectics with two interconnected economic circuits. Santos reasoned that the urban economy is composed of the ‘upper circuit’ populated by capital-intensive modern industries while the ‘lower circuit’ groups the labour-intensive smaller enterprises exposed to price bargaining. In Santos’s account, the two circuits struggle for control over the urban territory, with the upper circuit normally dominating the lower one and relegating it to the margins. Similar, or at least compatible, theories of two-sector economic structures in which one is superior to the other were salient in radical political economy and structural economic theory (e.g. Fuchs, <span>1974</span>; Hirschman, <span>1958</span>; Lewis, <span>1954</span>). Other authors (e.g. Elson, <span>2007, 2017</span>) argue that capitalism depends for its reproduction on the unpaid work of the domestic economy to sustain the political and economic spheres, which in turn generate the resources that sustain the capitalist economy. These parallel readings of the relation between capitalist and non-capitalist economies situate the latter in a relationship of subordination. Gibson-Graham criticize this a priori value judgement; at the risk of overgeneralization, they argue that Marxist accounts fail to see the potential of such alternatives and, rather than regarding them as equals, they are treated as subordinates.</p><p>In contrast, the diverse economies approach emphasizes horizontality and spatial differentiation with co-existence, although not without tensions. Gibson-Graham critiqued the assumed superior–inferior relationship and proposed an escape out of capitalocentrism by means of a systematic analysis of diversity and alterity. That is, they aim at ‘creating a discourse of economic difference as a contribution to a politics of economic innovation’ (Gibson-Graham, <span>2005a</span>: 6). Their approach emphasizes diversity and combinations across the five pillars of capitalism (see Table 1) and the prospect that current heterogeneity is only the beginning of future systemic transformation. They substitute a conception of a single overarching global capitalist economy with a diverse economy (Jonas, <span>2016</span>). They seek to reveal that the economy is heterogeneous and that it includes other mechanisms of exchange, organization of production, types of property and rewards for labour and finance (Healy, <span>2009, 2011</span>). As a research programme, the DE approach focuses on identifying and recording the great variety of economic activities around the globe. It is oriented towards describing a post-capitalist economy in which ‘other’ projects are registered and revalued.</p><p>While Gibson and Graham took explicit distance from Marxism, they also distanced themselves from utopianism. The diverse economies approach aims at identifying the myriad of economic practices already implemented as complements or as alternatives to the capitalist economy. The idea is to show them as autonomous spaces, and not as inferior or subordinated projects that may occur in neverlands. As a result, the academic project is also a legitimizing force for innovative activists who have already conceived and implemented alternative economic practices and who see their efforts reflected in scholarly theorization. They equally encourage acting, and especially invite academics to try action research. The focus of the DE approach is on the possibilities of the struggle and not on the probability of success (Gibson-Graham, <span>2008</span>: 615).</p><p>The idea of diversity suggests an innate positive connotation or a certain aura of progressiveness that needs to be examined. As argued by Samers (<span>2005</span>), some non-capitalist economic practices are equally or more exploitative than capitalist practices, such as modern slavery and various forms of unpaid work. According to a recent database, over 30 per cent of the world economy is produced informally, although the proportion has been shrinking substantially in the last two decades, up to the pandemic (Medina and Schneider, <span>2019</span>). This figure of 30 per cent hides an enormous diversity in itself; the informal economy is an amalgam of economic relations and practices under a single name that includes informal workers paid in cash, semi-informal workers that are not completely remunerated through the formal banking channels, and others that work without any pay (Gómez et al., <span>2020</span>; Williams, <span>2011</span>; Williams and Windebank, <span>1998</span>). In some corners of informality, agents have organized marketplaces, associations, self-help initiatives, and other ways of structuring their economic life that fit nicely in the ‘other-than-capitalist’ box of the diverse economies framework.</p><p>However, in other corners of the informal economy, there is nothing progressive about it and the notion of diversity veils myriad forms of exploitation and misery. The diverse economies framework does not acknowledge the contrasting diversity of other-than-capitalist enterprises. In keeping with the heterogeneity of the informal economy, there is a minority of well-paid digital workers that have little in common with the great number of unprotected apps-based workers (Meagher, <span>2019</span>) and low-income ‘working poor’ (Fisker, <span>2022</span>; Williams and Round, <span>2008</span>). Similarly, the ‘community’ behind the community economy is often rife with power asymmetries and inequalities (Bayat, <span>1997</span>). Cooperatives and self-managed worker businesses rarely provide a decent living to the unemployed that create them (Suryanata et al., <span>2021</span>). Collective action requires trust which generally is absent in the informal economy or economies, so it remains unorganized and populated by crowds of destitute workers struggling to survive. By critiquing capitalist practices, all other practices appear deserving of promotion, whereas alterity is not necessarily superior. Samers (<span>2005</span>: 883) questions this myopic understanding of the informal economy and asserts that ‘we need a more analytical treatment of informal or diverse economies by distinguishing between their more mundane but dyspeptic varieties (that is, large swathes of informal employment) and those with a seemingly more “progressive” production, extraction, and redistribution of the surplus’. In other words, we need to move beyond the assumption that all that is different to capitalism is desirable.</p><p>There is a related question, namely ‘what is the theoretical advantage of making an inventory of capitalist and non-capitalist practices if this includes exploitative projects?’. A more careful distinction between desirable diversity and undesirable diversity is a pending assignment of the DE framework that has not yet been resolved and does not appear under scrutiny in the handbook either. Various scholars therefore advocate moving away from an inherently positive appreciation of ‘diversity’ as a central expression of disapproval of the status quo (Schreven et al., <span>2008</span>). Others prefer the concept of ‘alterity’ as a non-binary discursive option that expresses degrees of separation and depends on specific contexts and spaces (e.g. Jonas, <span>2013</span>; Lee, <span>2000</span>). They define alterity as ‘a way of knowing, representing and narrating the other in terms that exist outside’ the established categories (Jonas, <span>2016</span>: 9). In other words, alterity is the construction of a sense of other both analytically and empirically (Fuller et al., <span>2016</span>). Still, alterity in any measure and degree suggests an immanent positive content that overrates the progressiveness of many initiatives. Other scholars developed the notion of ‘autonomous geographies’ to refer to the political networks of activists who aim at dislodging capitalism and building post-capitalist collective spaces (e.g. Pickerill and Chatterton, <span>2006</span>). They thus identify political and economic autonomy as the central criterion that couples the desirable to the alternative. Such a conceptualization presents the advantage that a socially minded movement needs to be present in the production of alterity, as opposed to any form of non-capitalist diversity that may or may not be sought after by a particular social group.</p><p>A second well-researched critique of the diverse economies research programme is the issue of scale, which has been noted by several authors. Lee et al. (<span>2010</span>) notably questioned the effectiveness of projects that are small scale, intimate, niche, local and grassroots. The critique examines the realistic transformative potential of the entire inventory of localized case studies and research interventions that show that these are many, varied and individually relevant to its participants. The issue of scale is discussed explicitly in the Introduction to the handbook, in which it is asserted that many non-capitalist practices are ubiquitous around the world, so they do not need to be large to have transformative potential (p. 18). Among other-than-capitalist practices that occur everywhere, the editors of the handbook include a variety of economic activities that are undoubtedly global and salient, such as care labour, housework, family lending, migrant remittances, household flows of goods and services, indigenous struggles and local place-based activism. Quoting previous work with St. Martin and Roelvink (2015, cited on p. 16), Gibson-Graham and Dombroski claim that by making these niche, local initiatives visible, diverse economies scholars ‘cultivate a politics of horizontal extent, reach and association rather than a politics of scale’ (p. 20). They further argue that the scale of these actions is global; because ‘women are everywhere and therefore always somewhere, change can be enacted in all those many somewheres’ (Gibson-Graham, <span>2005b</span>, cited on p. 20). Such a ubiquitous presence would facilitate the replication of change-making practices. This vision admits that replicated practices would not look the same everywhere, as if they were the result of a grand strategy of economic transformation.</p><p>While this constitutes a response to the critique on scaling, it does not convincingly cast light on the question of transformative potential. The emphasis of the DE approach is on scaling out rather than scaling up, which implies the multiplication of similar practices through relational networks and associations instead of the growth of a single project or location. If they did scale out, and diverse economies mushroomed globally as the 58 chapters in the handbook appear to suggest, would that be enough to generate a new type of economy at the aggregate level? Furthermore, scaling by replication is not as straightforward as suggested. The discourse that emphasizes multiplication and ubiquity as methods for effecting change at a global and aggregate level has been examined by scholars specialized in the different localized livelihoods (MacKinnon, <span>2008, 2011</span>) that the diverse economies literature seeks to cover. For example, research on not-for-profit enterprise networks reveals that scaling out works only under specific conditions and it is not free of risks and obstacles (Bocken et al., <span>2016</span>; van Lunenburg et al., <span>2020</span>; Reed, <span>2015</span>).</p><p>Among other limitations, the issue of knowledge is mentioned prominently, because the know-how on starting an alternative or socially oriented project does not travel freely. It requires motivated actors and privately owned resources to grow or to transfer knowledge to others in order that replication can occur. The originators of the transformative project are generally inclined to disseminate knowledge but also seek to benefit from it in financial or reputational terms. At the least, they seek to be acknowledged as the source of the social innovation, including the possibility of being paid for the conception of the idea, and at the most, they hope to obtain financial resources to progress further in their initiative. Similarly, even if knowledge becomes publicly available and free floating — to support, for example, a women's organization in Ireland to replicate the positive experience of a rotating savings and credit association in Kenya — the differences in context and subjectivities require considerable efforts in translation and adaptation, with all the costs, hurdles and risks of failure that this implies. The handbook asserts that ‘women are everywhere’ and there is considerable evidence corroborating that women tend to form organizations in a multitude of places and situations (p. 20). However, the women's associations that support female entrepreneurs in Ireland have little in common with the informal lending circles (<i>chamas</i>) in Kenya. While the transformative potential of scaling by multiplication could allow an other-than-capitalist project to reach ‘many somewheres’, the reasoning does not cast light on why it would happen or who would notice that it is worth the effort. Who would provide the resources, time and energy for a social innovation to travel from one context to another, safeguarding the transformative potential of the original?</p><p>Perhaps the transformative impact of scaling non-capitalist initiatives out and up lies elsewhere. Engaging with the diverse economies approach, Smith et al. (<span>2008</span>) suggest that the issue of scale is not always critical for transforming the system. In their study of diverse economic practices in post-socialist Eastern Europe, at the level of the household they found that workers combine formal and informal employment alongside legal and illegal work, unpaid domestic labour and reciprocal forms of exchange. In other words, each household participates in diverse economic practices to supplement its income and make a living in a capitalist economy. Smith et al. (ibid.) conclude that such a diversity of economic practices within households raises questions over the ability of capitalism to ensure social reproduction. Such questioning may lead to social and economic transformation. It is therefore not the scale of the diverse economies that matters but the questions on occupational identity, class processes and social roles that the practice of diversity can raise. In a more general sense, the need to combine various capitalist and non-capitalist economies in one household to make a living reminds its participants that the arrival and domination of capitalism in Eastern Europe and other areas of the world has brought a series of important challenges to groups of the population struggling to make a living.</p><p>Looking at this line of enquiry from a slightly different angle, another question arises. If non-capitalist activities at the level of the household aim at supporting survival and not at transforming the system, then those other-than-capitalist practices barely represent a move away from capitalism. At the level of the household, practices converge and co-exist, and there is an intimate interaction of the diverse economic practices, with the result that households may not always be able to establish which practice nourishes which. Yet, as Elson (<span>2017</span>) suggests, this convergence of non-capitalist practices at the level of the household has systemic implications and may have consequences for those living in the capitalist economy. Suryanata et al. (<span>2021</span>) conducted research among ‘new farmers’ in Hawaii, who left previous professions and entered farming to change their lifestyle and adopt the diverse socio-ecological values promoted by the DE approach. The study found that, driven by their nostalgia for a romanticized rural life, the new farmers ended up working long hours and resorting to unpaid labour to be able to make a living. Their behaviour reconfirmed that it is impossible for any farmer — old or new — to make a decent living from agriculture without working long hours and exploiting unpaid family members and themselves. The outcome was that the former-professionals-transformed-into-farmers undermined the social reproduction of those who had no other option but to live from farming. The diversification of economic practices in households that could afford it was counterproductive for the well-being of other households that could not make such choices. Hence, it is not possible to affirm that the diversification of economic practices away from capitalism necessarily represents a force that transforms the system in a positive direction; the opposite is also possible.</p><p>Moreover, alternative economic spaces are often populated by agents who lead a capitalist existence during working hours and a non-capitalist existence in their spare time, doing volunteer work, for example. With such a blend of social groups acting in various spheres of economic life, the rationalities that guide emancipatory projects are rarely isolated from the need to obtain resources to keep the various practices alive and extract surpluses to safeguard their survival and impact. It is likely that a large proportion of non-capitalist initiatives are hybrids that blend rationalities and absorb the pressure to secure resources — time and funding — from the capitalist system. The larger the scale, the greater the need to share the space and interact with other spheres and institutions. For instance, the diverse economies inventory presented in the handbook includes complementary currency systems that are convertible to formal national currencies, and therefore dependent on the capitalist economy. It also includes cases of self-managed and non-profit enterprises that require funds to pay salaries and achieve their social goals, and farmers’ markets where sales are concentrated among a handful of traders, excluding the less efficient or productive ones. While some of these cases may be successful in terms of their transformational impact and scaling, they blend elements of alterity with a mainstream existence, thus constituting changing hybrids. At what point is a partially alternative practice — a hybrid — no longer an alternative practice? This thus becomes an ontological question. It is not always possible to separate the market from the non-market, paid from unpaid labour, monetized from non-monetized and the formal from the informal (Rodgers and Williams, <span>2012</span>).</p><p>Together, this set of studies and critiques leads back to the question of the relationship between capitalist and non-capitalist practices. While the DE approach emphasizes horizontal diversity or the co-existence of diverse political and economic spaces, radical political economy, such as dependency theory, concludes that one sector is dominant or superior to the other. As argued by Marx and Engels (Engels, <span>1968</span>), the sector that provides resources for the survival of the second clearly has higher chances of dominating the agenda of the diverse economies. Diverse economic practices appear in a variety of relationships to the capitalist economy: transformational, complementary and subordinate. However, it appears that it cannot be defined a priori. There is therefore a third important area of critique that relates to the purpose of creating an inventory of diverse practices. Why is it relevant to the objective of transforming capitalism? In their article ‘Diverse Economies: Performative Practices for Other Worlds’, Gibson and Graham (Gibson-Graham, <span>2008</span>) engage with the sceptics who asked this question and explain that changing our understanding of the world is to change the world, if only partially and locally. However, 15 years later, the question remains unanswered: in what ways does the recognition of heterogeneous practices, however richly documented, contribute to changing the capitalist system? The handbook offers rather ambiguous clues to illuminate the path or paths — from imagining post-capitalist futures to defining their desirability or seeing them progress away from an exploitative economic system. Creating a language of diversity through research interventions is no doubt a positive step, but it is hardly sufficient to produce the transformation of human existence in the material world that the programme promotes. In the meantime, right-wing governments and wars to secure natural resources keep reproducing the walls of conflict and separation.</p><p>For scholars engaged in development studies, there is a fourth line of questioning to explore. How is alterity defined in a decolonizing world? The diverse economies approach facilitates the discovery of other-than-capitalist practices, supporting the connection of other ontologies to global conversations and scholarly work. The conception of other-than-capitalist practices makes sense in places where capitalist practices are the rule and non-capitalist practices need to be uncovered in order to change what scholars are trained to see first. But non-capitalist practices may occupy a different position in relation to pre-colonial, post-colonial and de-colonial economies. In vast areas of the global South, capitalist practices are the last addition in a long path of economic transformation, and not the other way around. As discussed in some of the chapters in the handbook, the diverse economies in developing countries encompass livelihood activities that have been in existence for centuries. It would therefore be hard to assert the extent to which they can be considered ‘alternative’, except in relation to a Western view of the world that sees capitalism as the rule in economic life. It could be argued that in the global South alterity is the norm. Economies in the global South are well populated by informal, indigenous, vernacular and other-than-capitalist practices.</p><p>This is the exact opposite to the message the diverse economies approach aims to communicate. In Chapter 55 of the handbook, entitled ‘Working with Indigenous Methodologies’, Waitoa and Dombroski explain that the inclusion of a Maori methodology in the handbook constitutes ‘a first step towards identifying instructive points of connection and dissonance with diverse economies methods and approaches’ (p. 502). This is a clear acknowledgement by the diverse economies approach of the specificities of economic life in the developing world. It also implies that the DE approach conceives of indigenous, vernacular and localized economic practices — ubiquitous in the global South — as alternatives to capitalism and the institutions dominant in the global North. Labelling these practices as ‘diverse’ or ‘alternative’ in a world that is dominated by other-than-capitalist practices is not only inaccurate but may also come across as condescending. The DE approach aims to facilitate South–North transfer by emphasizing difference and potential, but its representatives are sometimes insensitive to the fact that certain non-capitalist practices are the norm in other parts of the world and that their value does not lie in appearing unique or exotic from a Northern perspective. That still leaves aside the issue of whether pre-colonial non-capitalist practices are less exploitative and exclusionary than capitalist ones. Or whether pre-colonial empires and their economic practices were any less discriminatory towards the ‘other’ peoples they conquered and enslaved.</p><p>Spanning over 550 pages and 58 chapters across seven sections, the book presents a daunting amount of material. It includes contributions of 69 authors from various backgrounds, career stages and corners of the world. This richness makes the handbook an invaluable starting point for those interested in identifying and seeing the variety of economic practices around the world. By adding studies on new topics and finding analytical connections among them, the handbook improves the coherence of the approach. It presents an up to date collection of cases with cross-cutting issues salient in 2020. Several of the practices studied are rooted in collective action and hope, and the politics of hope (Denzin, <span>2000</span>) is discussed in detail in this handbook. The DE programme emphasizes hope by showing how personal and interpersonal efforts may play a role in demonstrating the possibility of alternative futures (Zademach and Hillebrand, <span>2013</span>).</p><p>The first five sections of the handbook are organized around the categories of enterprises, labour, transactions, property and finance. Each section starts with a framing essay that aims to contextualize the topic and make explicit the connections between the chapters comprising that section. For example, the framing essay of section one on enterprise diversity is authored by Jenny Cameron (pp. 26–39) and focuses on class. From the perspective of the diverse economies framework, class is conceived as a process of producing, appropriating and distributing surplus labour in various types of enterprises. The framing essay is followed by nine studies on the various class processes in these spaces, including worker cooperatives, worker-owned factories, anti-crime initiatives and other kinds of community enterprises and eco-social and ethical businesses. The second section looks at labour and in addition to the framing essay, it consists of eight chapters on precarious labour, informal and unpaid labour, care work, collectively performed reciprocal labour, informal mining and the non-human labour of ‘earth others’. The third section on transactions presents a framing essay, followed by eight chapters on gleaning, community supported agriculture, collective food procurement, alternative currencies, time banking, fair trade networks, social procurement and shared urban spaces. After a framing essay, the fourth section examines property in six chapters focusing on commoning, land trusts, urban land markets and free universities. The fifth section deals with finance and includes a framing article followed by five chapters on Islamic finance, rotating savings and credit associations, indigenous finance, community investment funds and hacking finance. In short, the book chapters cover a broad range of different topics and cases, with ethics and hope as the common principle that drives these diverse and alternative economic practices.</p><p>The diverse economies framework focuses on practices to convey its distance from economic determinism (the ontological restriction to certain economic processes) and empirical realism (the epistemological acceptance of a separation between reality and reflection). In line with these assumptions, the last two sections of the handbook explore subjectivity and methodology. These two areas of enquiry are probably the main original contributions of this volume. The framing essay of the sixth section on subjectivity, by Healy et al., aims to clarify the meaning of the term ‘subject’ in a diverse non-capitalist economy and ‘demotes the primacy of the human subject’ (p. 389). It proposes a reading of the economic subject that explicitly recognizes an anti-essentialist framing, one that emphasizes the open-ended way in which human communities face dilemmas about consumption and necessity or investment and surplus. The authors further explain that this describes the decentred economic subject in the ‘undecidable space of a dilemma’ (p. 385) in which human communities negotiate indefinitely the conditions of ‘antagonistic interdependence’ (ibid.). It is followed by six chapters on diverse subjectivities, power, genealogy, sexuality, affections and economic subjectivity.</p><p>The last section on methodology refrains from promoting a particular methodology, in keeping with the fact that this is a research programme that takes pride in its diversity of topics and approaches. Instead, it favours the imagining of post-capitalist futures and the research interventions that can realize them. As Gibson-Graham argue in Chapter 52, the research methodologies of the diverse economies framework are varied but consistently focus on ‘reading for economic difference’ (p. 476). The seventh section therefore includes eight chapters on indigenous methodologies, assemblage analysis, action research, the tracing of relations and the use of artistic resources as method of enquiry.</p><p>In general, the handbook advances the consistency and completeness of the research programme, not as an alternative economics textbook but as a different approach to understanding what the economy is, in its geographical and everyday diversity. It introduces itself as a set of weak theoretical tools to support the study of capitalist, non-capitalist and community/alternative capitalist practices. While <i>seeing</i> disruptive practices constitutes a first step, the handbook repeatedly reminds the reader that the goal of the research programme is to recover and revalorize the possibilities of a non-capitalist future, or, at least, to demonstrate that capitalist practices are only one of various modalities of economic interaction to secure the material survival and reproduction of communities. Showing and seeing the heterogeneity of economic practices would promote conceptions of and projects advancing a non-capitalist future. Gibson-Graham (<span>2008</span>) claimed that ‘changing our understanding of the world is to change the world’, which is a clear indication of their commitment to performative research. Building on this premise, the DE research programme had been prolific and had contributed a large number of books, academic articles and activists’ reports. It was time to condense its contributions in a massive, comprehensive handbook.</p><p>While the volume is an excellent effort to mitigate the dispersion of topics, cases and differentiated framings within the diverse economies approach, it does not go far enough in engaging with some of the points of critique raised above. The handbook aims to provide the means to create a systematic inventory of diverse, human-scale, community-led economic practices without necessarily assessing how desirable these are. Since its inception in 1996, this post-capitalist research project has generated crowds of adepts and sceptics. The group of supporters appreciates its potential to examine economic diversity and recognize the alterity of economic practices rooted in the politics of hope. The group of sceptics keeps on asking the same questions, which continue to go unanswered. The danger of such silence is that a new sect of scholar-activists may arise, repeating the same narrative in the hope that it will become true. A key proposition of the handbook is that we are occupying a post-capitalist future without fully explaining how we are to know that we have arrived there or specifying which part of the future they are describing. The debate is certainly open as to whether we are experiencing a post-neoliberal phase or another cycle of conservative neoliberalism (Fine and Saad-Filho, <span>2014</span>; Gaudichaud et al., <span>2022</span>; Strange, <span>2016</span>).</p><p>When Gibson and Graham published <i>The End of Capitalism (As We Knew it)</i> in 1996, they produced what many economic geographers considered to be one of the ‘most innovative and startling re-interpretations of the economy in the last decades’ (Zademach and Hillebrand, <span>2013</span>: 16). Their contributions accumulated and were further developed by other scholars around the world, evolving into the diverse economies research programme. The programme offers a post-structuralist reading of political, economic and social interaction to disclose the multiple economic practices that are already in existence within the economic landscape. It has supported the elaboration of a new economic dictionary, with more inclusive language. Moreover, it has recaptured the element of hope in existing initiatives that increase well-being in everyday economic life. At the same time, it has been unable to develop clear criteria on the desirability or progressiveness of those other-than-capitalist economic practices, how they could accumulate sufficient transformative potential, or what effects they could have at the various levels of economic life (households, regions, national and global systems). In relation to development studies, the programme may offer an interesting avenue for South–North knowledge transfer, but that would require another round of remaking the language of economic diversity to account for what is standard and what is alternative. The proportion of the economy that can be described as capitalist — represented by formal labour, pure private property, markets with transparent prices and mainstream finance — may be too small in many countries in the global South for other practices to be considered as ‘alternative’. Just taking account of the informal monetized economic activities measured by Medina and Schneider (<span>2019</span>: 11), alternatives to formal capitalist practices made up 63 per cent of GDP in Bolivia and 57 per cent of GDP in Nigeria. Labelling these as ‘alternative’ therefore does not do justice to their pervasiveness. To consider the alterity of these practices as a matter of degree, as suggested by Jonas (<span>2016</span>), may therefore be a more valid analytical instrument.</p><p>There is also the question of the relationship between capitalist and non-capitalist practices, which situates the diverse economies approach between radical political economy perspectives and the utopians. While the Marxist literature has been dismissive of the latter, the literature on communitarian and human-centred practices has been a source of undeniable hope in the possibility of a post-capitalist future on a healthy planet. Yet the position of these non-capitalist economies in relation to the capitalist economy needs considerably more elaboration within the DE research programme. Are they subordinate, parallel, complementary, or transformative projects in relation the capitalist economy based on waged labour and private property? The answer would not be the same for the unpaid domestic economy, the informal inferior circuits of value, or the value-oriented grassroots niches pursuing ecologically informed economic projects.</p><p>While acknowledging the difficulties of identifying alterity, the actors and their historical and geographical situations, Fickey and Hanrahan (<span>2015</span>: 400) recommend that scholars studying alterity engage more with one another. Indeed, there is a need to compare notes and increase the empirical basis of the research project in a systematic way. <i>The Handbook of Diverse Economies</i> takes a small step in that direction by bringing together a massive network of authors, case studies and methodologies in one volume. What could come next is clearer proof of the research programme's capacity to engage critically with itself.</p>","PeriodicalId":48194,"journal":{"name":"Development and Change","volume":"54 2","pages":"442-460"},"PeriodicalIF":3.0000,"publicationDate":"2023-03-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/dech.12762","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"How Far Does the Diverse Economies Approach Take Us?\",\"authors\":\"Georgina M. Gómez\",\"doi\":\"10.1111/dech.12762\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p><b>Julie and Katherine Gibson-Graham and Kelly Dombroski (eds), <i>The Handbook of Diverse Economies</i>. Cheltenham and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 2020. 546 pp. £ 199.80 hardback</b>.</p><p>There is a long-standing tradition of thought on human-centred and communitarian economies. It connects to a search for utopias (no lands) and udetopias (neverlands) which has accelerated with the advent of capitalism and the obsession with capital accumulation that gave the latter system its name. Intellectuals like Charles Fourier, Silvio Gesell, François Marie, Karl Marx, Robert Owen and Pierre-Joseph Proudhon were pioneers in developing social, economic and political alternatives to capitalism. They engaged with the original 16th century collectivist and utopian socialism of Sir Thomas More, which, as French sociologist Pierre Bourdieu (<span>1998</span>: 125) observed, was ‘often discredited, dismissed and ridiculed in the name of economic realism’. Drawing on this tradition, the scholarly couple Katherine Gibson and Julie Graham added the diverse economies (DE) approach three decades ago.1 Since then, it has developed into a fully-fledged research programme among scholars and a vision of social transformation among activists. The latest arrival in their scientific production <i>The Handbook of Diverse Economies</i>, is edited by J.K. Gibson-Graham and Kelly Dombroski, and the subject of this critical review.</p><p>Through capturing and valorizing the variety of economic, social and political spaces that currently proliferate in the interstices of the capitalist system, the diverse economies approach has gained considerable traction. These spaces, DE authors and followers would emphasize, are not an exercise of the imagination occurring in the no lands and neverlands of utopianism, but tangible and true sources of global hope. They are existing spaces which evade capitalism or shape resistance to it, and mobilize collectives. Underlining that building alternatives to capitalism is feasible as it is ongoing, <i>The Handbook of Diverse Economies</i> adds cases, findings and reflections, and invites analysis of the way scholars understand and write about economic alternatives.</p><p>However, as in previous works (see Gibson-Graham, <span>1996, 2008</span>), engagement with academics outside feminist, post-structural and post-development circles remains pending in this last book. While this new volume refines the contrast with neoliberal politics and the ‘crushing uniformity of mainstream circuits of value’ (Fuller et al., <span>2016</span>: xxiv), it does not meet the need to engage with other ways of theorizing alternatives to overcome the relatively marginal position of diverse economies within the dominant capitalist system. Some of the older critiques of the DE approach are explicitly addressed, but the general lack of receptiveness to criticism limits the influence of the research programme beyond the circles of supporters and partisan advocates of a post-capitalist future.</p><p>This essay begins by introducing the notion of alterity and the trajectory of utopianism, and how the diverse economies approach is situated within this tradition. It subsequently presents a critique of previous research, which is followed by a review of the new book (hereafter referred to as the handbook) and its contribution to this body of scholarly work. The essay delves into the details of what has and what has not been covered by this new addition, and its relevance to the field of development studies.</p><p>A key achievement of the diverse economies framework is that it has rekindled the debate on the notions of alternatives and alterity (Fickey, <span>2011</span>; Lee et al., <span>2004</span>). It is not a new debate, considering that the intellectual production of alternatives to capitalism has inspired humankind since the origins of capitalism itself. In line with this, contending conceptions invariably reject surplus extraction based on private property and its resulting waged employment, but they differ in their interpretation and focus of the meaning of alternative.</p><p>Gritzas and Kavoulakos (<span>2016</span>) have clustered scholarly work on alternatives to capitalism in two broad groups. The ‘utopians’ favoured the organization of a cooperative or community economy; Proudhon was among them, and to some extent, Polanyi and Gesell later followed. The sceptic camp, of which Marx and Engels are representatives, were particularly dismissive of utopian projects and their lack of ‘scientific’ reflection; they were convinced that such utopian initiatives were bound to fail (Engels, <span>1968</span>). Marx and Engels reasoned that individuals cannot change society from below because they do not have the resources to afford a life outside a waged relationship. As workers do not own or control the means of production, they are not able to access the resources needed to afford food, accommodation and meet other basic needs for survival. According to Marx and Engels, forming small networks or communities does not improve utopians’ chances of success in the long run either, because a life outside capitalism requires resources that must come from somewhere. Furthermore, if such a withdrawal from capitalism becomes the life choice of significant numbers of workers, the state would intervene to prevent a mass opt-out from the capitalist economy (North, <span>2016</span>). Subsequent orthodox Marxist scholars similarly discarded the potential of such initiatives as naïve and instead promoted full-scale radical social change that would terminate the hegemony of capitalism when the system had reached its productivity boundary. Recently, scholars have contested the sterile nature of alternative projects and suggest that in current times, the claim that utopian initiatives from below have no potential needs to be researched empirically (Gómez, <span>2018</span>; North, <span>1999, 2016</span>; Pacione, <span>1997</span>).</p><p>The scepticism of the Marxist strand eventually dominated the intellectual debate that challenged capitalism during the 20th century, consigning smaller utopian initiatives to the intellectual margins (Fuller et al., <span>2016</span>). The confrontation between socialism and capitalism resulted in the regulation of capitalist economies which in some countries led to the emergence of welfare states that redistributed economic benefits, further pushing utopian economic and political experiments to the margins (Gritzas and Kavoulakos, <span>2016</span>). With the decline of radical political economy and the rise of neoliberalism in the late 1980s, the scope for alternative thinking was lost in no lands and neverlands. Ironically, this intensified the search among academics who were not deterred by the apparent implications of small-scale practices (Holloway, <span>2010</span>). There was a dire need among scholars to find alternative economic and political practices that would bring hope against the background of hegemonic neoliberal capitalism. The search finally made progress towards the mid-1990s, when the retreat of the welfare state was being contested, new social movements such as the Zapatistas in Mexico emerged and anti-globalization protests gained momentum.</p><p>In 1996, the feminist economic geographers Katherine Gibson and Julie Graham published <i>The End of Capitalism (As We Knew it): A Feminist Critique of Political Economy</i> (Gibson-Graham, <span>1996</span>). A decade later, they collected their ideas in <i>A Postcapitalist Politics</i> (Gibson-Graham, <span>2006</span>). <i>The End of Capitalism</i> was a provocative, fresh and ground-breaking attempt to capture the efforts of various communities around the world that were building different spaces of economic and political interaction. The qualification of ‘different spaces’ applies to a varied set of non-capitalist projects as well as alternatives that directly oppose capitalism. The key analytical instrument of the DE approach is a comprehensive canvas based on grounded and weak theory. The framework presents a broad inventory of empirical practices related to enterprises, labour, transactions, property and finance to construct three loose categories or domains of economic activity: non-capitalist, capitalist and alternative to capitalist (see Table 1). In subsequent publications identifying with the approach, more examples have been added. In this way, the DE approach collected studies on a multitude of different practices around the world that facilitate the material survival of communities and the reproduction of their cultural life. The publications led to a group of scholar-activists forming the Community Economies Research Network (CERN), which engages in research, reflection and practical activities around the world.2 At the time of writing,3 <i>The End of Capitalism</i> (Gibson-Graham, <span>1996</span>) has been cited 5,350 times and Google Scholar lists 10,500 hits for the keyword ‘diverse economies’, which shows how the concept has gained in popularity in some academic and activist circles.</p><p>Intellectually, the DE approach positions itself between the utopians and the Marxists. Gibson-Graham (<span>1996, 2006</span>) define capitalism in relation to five pillars as shown in Table 1: waged labour, exploitative enterprises, private property, market exchange and interest-based finances. They contend that there are too many experiments that do not follow these five characteristics and they criticize the structuralist Marxist approaches for being ‘capitalocentric’, meaning that they ignore the immense variety of practices in the non-capitalist categories. They further argue that Marxist approaches assess capitalism with an essentialist, monolithic discourse that clouds ‘other’ economic practices that are not based either on wage labour or on exploitation. Marxist work, they claim, describes capitalism with ‘totalising concepts and machine-like metaphors’ (Jonas, <span>2016</span>: 6) to express its domination over non-capitalist spaces. As these practices go unnoticed and are treated as unworthy of consideration, the Marxist narrative would endorse the belief that non-capitalist projects are too small, marginal and irrelevant to achieve any systemic transformation. According to Gibson-Graham (<span>1996</span>), keeping non-capitalist projects hidden or invisible makes them appear irrelevant and powerless, thereby silencing existing diversity and further preventing the imagining of non-capitalist futures. The capacity to see diversity is thus impaired and part of the DE project is precisely to construct another dictionary to discuss and analyse alterity.</p><p>The point of departure of the approach, that non-capitalist economic systems have remained invisible, calls for further discussion. Radical political economy scholars have examined these different economies within capitalism but based on the assumptions that they are subordinate subsystems of the capitalist economy, which sustains them to secure its own survival, and that they lack autonomy as alternative economic projects (Jonas, <span>2016</span>). For example, radical development geographer Milton Santos (<span>1977</span>) posited the theory of spatial dialectics with two interconnected economic circuits. Santos reasoned that the urban economy is composed of the ‘upper circuit’ populated by capital-intensive modern industries while the ‘lower circuit’ groups the labour-intensive smaller enterprises exposed to price bargaining. In Santos’s account, the two circuits struggle for control over the urban territory, with the upper circuit normally dominating the lower one and relegating it to the margins. Similar, or at least compatible, theories of two-sector economic structures in which one is superior to the other were salient in radical political economy and structural economic theory (e.g. Fuchs, <span>1974</span>; Hirschman, <span>1958</span>; Lewis, <span>1954</span>). Other authors (e.g. Elson, <span>2007, 2017</span>) argue that capitalism depends for its reproduction on the unpaid work of the domestic economy to sustain the political and economic spheres, which in turn generate the resources that sustain the capitalist economy. These parallel readings of the relation between capitalist and non-capitalist economies situate the latter in a relationship of subordination. Gibson-Graham criticize this a priori value judgement; at the risk of overgeneralization, they argue that Marxist accounts fail to see the potential of such alternatives and, rather than regarding them as equals, they are treated as subordinates.</p><p>In contrast, the diverse economies approach emphasizes horizontality and spatial differentiation with co-existence, although not without tensions. Gibson-Graham critiqued the assumed superior–inferior relationship and proposed an escape out of capitalocentrism by means of a systematic analysis of diversity and alterity. That is, they aim at ‘creating a discourse of economic difference as a contribution to a politics of economic innovation’ (Gibson-Graham, <span>2005a</span>: 6). Their approach emphasizes diversity and combinations across the five pillars of capitalism (see Table 1) and the prospect that current heterogeneity is only the beginning of future systemic transformation. They substitute a conception of a single overarching global capitalist economy with a diverse economy (Jonas, <span>2016</span>). They seek to reveal that the economy is heterogeneous and that it includes other mechanisms of exchange, organization of production, types of property and rewards for labour and finance (Healy, <span>2009, 2011</span>). As a research programme, the DE approach focuses on identifying and recording the great variety of economic activities around the globe. It is oriented towards describing a post-capitalist economy in which ‘other’ projects are registered and revalued.</p><p>While Gibson and Graham took explicit distance from Marxism, they also distanced themselves from utopianism. The diverse economies approach aims at identifying the myriad of economic practices already implemented as complements or as alternatives to the capitalist economy. The idea is to show them as autonomous spaces, and not as inferior or subordinated projects that may occur in neverlands. As a result, the academic project is also a legitimizing force for innovative activists who have already conceived and implemented alternative economic practices and who see their efforts reflected in scholarly theorization. They equally encourage acting, and especially invite academics to try action research. The focus of the DE approach is on the possibilities of the struggle and not on the probability of success (Gibson-Graham, <span>2008</span>: 615).</p><p>The idea of diversity suggests an innate positive connotation or a certain aura of progressiveness that needs to be examined. As argued by Samers (<span>2005</span>), some non-capitalist economic practices are equally or more exploitative than capitalist practices, such as modern slavery and various forms of unpaid work. According to a recent database, over 30 per cent of the world economy is produced informally, although the proportion has been shrinking substantially in the last two decades, up to the pandemic (Medina and Schneider, <span>2019</span>). This figure of 30 per cent hides an enormous diversity in itself; the informal economy is an amalgam of economic relations and practices under a single name that includes informal workers paid in cash, semi-informal workers that are not completely remunerated through the formal banking channels, and others that work without any pay (Gómez et al., <span>2020</span>; Williams, <span>2011</span>; Williams and Windebank, <span>1998</span>). In some corners of informality, agents have organized marketplaces, associations, self-help initiatives, and other ways of structuring their economic life that fit nicely in the ‘other-than-capitalist’ box of the diverse economies framework.</p><p>However, in other corners of the informal economy, there is nothing progressive about it and the notion of diversity veils myriad forms of exploitation and misery. The diverse economies framework does not acknowledge the contrasting diversity of other-than-capitalist enterprises. In keeping with the heterogeneity of the informal economy, there is a minority of well-paid digital workers that have little in common with the great number of unprotected apps-based workers (Meagher, <span>2019</span>) and low-income ‘working poor’ (Fisker, <span>2022</span>; Williams and Round, <span>2008</span>). Similarly, the ‘community’ behind the community economy is often rife with power asymmetries and inequalities (Bayat, <span>1997</span>). Cooperatives and self-managed worker businesses rarely provide a decent living to the unemployed that create them (Suryanata et al., <span>2021</span>). Collective action requires trust which generally is absent in the informal economy or economies, so it remains unorganized and populated by crowds of destitute workers struggling to survive. By critiquing capitalist practices, all other practices appear deserving of promotion, whereas alterity is not necessarily superior. Samers (<span>2005</span>: 883) questions this myopic understanding of the informal economy and asserts that ‘we need a more analytical treatment of informal or diverse economies by distinguishing between their more mundane but dyspeptic varieties (that is, large swathes of informal employment) and those with a seemingly more “progressive” production, extraction, and redistribution of the surplus’. In other words, we need to move beyond the assumption that all that is different to capitalism is desirable.</p><p>There is a related question, namely ‘what is the theoretical advantage of making an inventory of capitalist and non-capitalist practices if this includes exploitative projects?’. A more careful distinction between desirable diversity and undesirable diversity is a pending assignment of the DE framework that has not yet been resolved and does not appear under scrutiny in the handbook either. Various scholars therefore advocate moving away from an inherently positive appreciation of ‘diversity’ as a central expression of disapproval of the status quo (Schreven et al., <span>2008</span>). Others prefer the concept of ‘alterity’ as a non-binary discursive option that expresses degrees of separation and depends on specific contexts and spaces (e.g. Jonas, <span>2013</span>; Lee, <span>2000</span>). They define alterity as ‘a way of knowing, representing and narrating the other in terms that exist outside’ the established categories (Jonas, <span>2016</span>: 9). In other words, alterity is the construction of a sense of other both analytically and empirically (Fuller et al., <span>2016</span>). Still, alterity in any measure and degree suggests an immanent positive content that overrates the progressiveness of many initiatives. Other scholars developed the notion of ‘autonomous geographies’ to refer to the political networks of activists who aim at dislodging capitalism and building post-capitalist collective spaces (e.g. Pickerill and Chatterton, <span>2006</span>). They thus identify political and economic autonomy as the central criterion that couples the desirable to the alternative. Such a conceptualization presents the advantage that a socially minded movement needs to be present in the production of alterity, as opposed to any form of non-capitalist diversity that may or may not be sought after by a particular social group.</p><p>A second well-researched critique of the diverse economies research programme is the issue of scale, which has been noted by several authors. Lee et al. (<span>2010</span>) notably questioned the effectiveness of projects that are small scale, intimate, niche, local and grassroots. The critique examines the realistic transformative potential of the entire inventory of localized case studies and research interventions that show that these are many, varied and individually relevant to its participants. The issue of scale is discussed explicitly in the Introduction to the handbook, in which it is asserted that many non-capitalist practices are ubiquitous around the world, so they do not need to be large to have transformative potential (p. 18). Among other-than-capitalist practices that occur everywhere, the editors of the handbook include a variety of economic activities that are undoubtedly global and salient, such as care labour, housework, family lending, migrant remittances, household flows of goods and services, indigenous struggles and local place-based activism. Quoting previous work with St. Martin and Roelvink (2015, cited on p. 16), Gibson-Graham and Dombroski claim that by making these niche, local initiatives visible, diverse economies scholars ‘cultivate a politics of horizontal extent, reach and association rather than a politics of scale’ (p. 20). They further argue that the scale of these actions is global; because ‘women are everywhere and therefore always somewhere, change can be enacted in all those many somewheres’ (Gibson-Graham, <span>2005b</span>, cited on p. 20). Such a ubiquitous presence would facilitate the replication of change-making practices. This vision admits that replicated practices would not look the same everywhere, as if they were the result of a grand strategy of economic transformation.</p><p>While this constitutes a response to the critique on scaling, it does not convincingly cast light on the question of transformative potential. The emphasis of the DE approach is on scaling out rather than scaling up, which implies the multiplication of similar practices through relational networks and associations instead of the growth of a single project or location. If they did scale out, and diverse economies mushroomed globally as the 58 chapters in the handbook appear to suggest, would that be enough to generate a new type of economy at the aggregate level? Furthermore, scaling by replication is not as straightforward as suggested. The discourse that emphasizes multiplication and ubiquity as methods for effecting change at a global and aggregate level has been examined by scholars specialized in the different localized livelihoods (MacKinnon, <span>2008, 2011</span>) that the diverse economies literature seeks to cover. For example, research on not-for-profit enterprise networks reveals that scaling out works only under specific conditions and it is not free of risks and obstacles (Bocken et al., <span>2016</span>; van Lunenburg et al., <span>2020</span>; Reed, <span>2015</span>).</p><p>Among other limitations, the issue of knowledge is mentioned prominently, because the know-how on starting an alternative or socially oriented project does not travel freely. It requires motivated actors and privately owned resources to grow or to transfer knowledge to others in order that replication can occur. The originators of the transformative project are generally inclined to disseminate knowledge but also seek to benefit from it in financial or reputational terms. At the least, they seek to be acknowledged as the source of the social innovation, including the possibility of being paid for the conception of the idea, and at the most, they hope to obtain financial resources to progress further in their initiative. Similarly, even if knowledge becomes publicly available and free floating — to support, for example, a women's organization in Ireland to replicate the positive experience of a rotating savings and credit association in Kenya — the differences in context and subjectivities require considerable efforts in translation and adaptation, with all the costs, hurdles and risks of failure that this implies. The handbook asserts that ‘women are everywhere’ and there is considerable evidence corroborating that women tend to form organizations in a multitude of places and situations (p. 20). However, the women's associations that support female entrepreneurs in Ireland have little in common with the informal lending circles (<i>chamas</i>) in Kenya. While the transformative potential of scaling by multiplication could allow an other-than-capitalist project to reach ‘many somewheres’, the reasoning does not cast light on why it would happen or who would notice that it is worth the effort. Who would provide the resources, time and energy for a social innovation to travel from one context to another, safeguarding the transformative potential of the original?</p><p>Perhaps the transformative impact of scaling non-capitalist initiatives out and up lies elsewhere. Engaging with the diverse economies approach, Smith et al. (<span>2008</span>) suggest that the issue of scale is not always critical for transforming the system. In their study of diverse economic practices in post-socialist Eastern Europe, at the level of the household they found that workers combine formal and informal employment alongside legal and illegal work, unpaid domestic labour and reciprocal forms of exchange. In other words, each household participates in diverse economic practices to supplement its income and make a living in a capitalist economy. Smith et al. (ibid.) conclude that such a diversity of economic practices within households raises questions over the ability of capitalism to ensure social reproduction. Such questioning may lead to social and economic transformation. It is therefore not the scale of the diverse economies that matters but the questions on occupational identity, class processes and social roles that the practice of diversity can raise. In a more general sense, the need to combine various capitalist and non-capitalist economies in one household to make a living reminds its participants that the arrival and domination of capitalism in Eastern Europe and other areas of the world has brought a series of important challenges to groups of the population struggling to make a living.</p><p>Looking at this line of enquiry from a slightly different angle, another question arises. If non-capitalist activities at the level of the household aim at supporting survival and not at transforming the system, then those other-than-capitalist practices barely represent a move away from capitalism. At the level of the household, practices converge and co-exist, and there is an intimate interaction of the diverse economic practices, with the result that households may not always be able to establish which practice nourishes which. Yet, as Elson (<span>2017</span>) suggests, this convergence of non-capitalist practices at the level of the household has systemic implications and may have consequences for those living in the capitalist economy. Suryanata et al. (<span>2021</span>) conducted research among ‘new farmers’ in Hawaii, who left previous professions and entered farming to change their lifestyle and adopt the diverse socio-ecological values promoted by the DE approach. The study found that, driven by their nostalgia for a romanticized rural life, the new farmers ended up working long hours and resorting to unpaid labour to be able to make a living. Their behaviour reconfirmed that it is impossible for any farmer — old or new — to make a decent living from agriculture without working long hours and exploiting unpaid family members and themselves. The outcome was that the former-professionals-transformed-into-farmers undermined the social reproduction of those who had no other option but to live from farming. The diversification of economic practices in households that could afford it was counterproductive for the well-being of other households that could not make such choices. Hence, it is not possible to affirm that the diversification of economic practices away from capitalism necessarily represents a force that transforms the system in a positive direction; the opposite is also possible.</p><p>Moreover, alternative economic spaces are often populated by agents who lead a capitalist existence during working hours and a non-capitalist existence in their spare time, doing volunteer work, for example. With such a blend of social groups acting in various spheres of economic life, the rationalities that guide emancipatory projects are rarely isolated from the need to obtain resources to keep the various practices alive and extract surpluses to safeguard their survival and impact. It is likely that a large proportion of non-capitalist initiatives are hybrids that blend rationalities and absorb the pressure to secure resources — time and funding — from the capitalist system. The larger the scale, the greater the need to share the space and interact with other spheres and institutions. For instance, the diverse economies inventory presented in the handbook includes complementary currency systems that are convertible to formal national currencies, and therefore dependent on the capitalist economy. It also includes cases of self-managed and non-profit enterprises that require funds to pay salaries and achieve their social goals, and farmers’ markets where sales are concentrated among a handful of traders, excluding the less efficient or productive ones. While some of these cases may be successful in terms of their transformational impact and scaling, they blend elements of alterity with a mainstream existence, thus constituting changing hybrids. At what point is a partially alternative practice — a hybrid — no longer an alternative practice? This thus becomes an ontological question. It is not always possible to separate the market from the non-market, paid from unpaid labour, monetized from non-monetized and the formal from the informal (Rodgers and Williams, <span>2012</span>).</p><p>Together, this set of studies and critiques leads back to the question of the relationship between capitalist and non-capitalist practices. While the DE approach emphasizes horizontal diversity or the co-existence of diverse political and economic spaces, radical political economy, such as dependency theory, concludes that one sector is dominant or superior to the other. As argued by Marx and Engels (Engels, <span>1968</span>), the sector that provides resources for the survival of the second clearly has higher chances of dominating the agenda of the diverse economies. Diverse economic practices appear in a variety of relationships to the capitalist economy: transformational, complementary and subordinate. However, it appears that it cannot be defined a priori. There is therefore a third important area of critique that relates to the purpose of creating an inventory of diverse practices. Why is it relevant to the objective of transforming capitalism? In their article ‘Diverse Economies: Performative Practices for Other Worlds’, Gibson and Graham (Gibson-Graham, <span>2008</span>) engage with the sceptics who asked this question and explain that changing our understanding of the world is to change the world, if only partially and locally. However, 15 years later, the question remains unanswered: in what ways does the recognition of heterogeneous practices, however richly documented, contribute to changing the capitalist system? The handbook offers rather ambiguous clues to illuminate the path or paths — from imagining post-capitalist futures to defining their desirability or seeing them progress away from an exploitative economic system. Creating a language of diversity through research interventions is no doubt a positive step, but it is hardly sufficient to produce the transformation of human existence in the material world that the programme promotes. In the meantime, right-wing governments and wars to secure natural resources keep reproducing the walls of conflict and separation.</p><p>For scholars engaged in development studies, there is a fourth line of questioning to explore. How is alterity defined in a decolonizing world? The diverse economies approach facilitates the discovery of other-than-capitalist practices, supporting the connection of other ontologies to global conversations and scholarly work. The conception of other-than-capitalist practices makes sense in places where capitalist practices are the rule and non-capitalist practices need to be uncovered in order to change what scholars are trained to see first. But non-capitalist practices may occupy a different position in relation to pre-colonial, post-colonial and de-colonial economies. In vast areas of the global South, capitalist practices are the last addition in a long path of economic transformation, and not the other way around. As discussed in some of the chapters in the handbook, the diverse economies in developing countries encompass livelihood activities that have been in existence for centuries. It would therefore be hard to assert the extent to which they can be considered ‘alternative’, except in relation to a Western view of the world that sees capitalism as the rule in economic life. It could be argued that in the global South alterity is the norm. Economies in the global South are well populated by informal, indigenous, vernacular and other-than-capitalist practices.</p><p>This is the exact opposite to the message the diverse economies approach aims to communicate. In Chapter 55 of the handbook, entitled ‘Working with Indigenous Methodologies’, Waitoa and Dombroski explain that the inclusion of a Maori methodology in the handbook constitutes ‘a first step towards identifying instructive points of connection and dissonance with diverse economies methods and approaches’ (p. 502). This is a clear acknowledgement by the diverse economies approach of the specificities of economic life in the developing world. It also implies that the DE approach conceives of indigenous, vernacular and localized economic practices — ubiquitous in the global South — as alternatives to capitalism and the institutions dominant in the global North. Labelling these practices as ‘diverse’ or ‘alternative’ in a world that is dominated by other-than-capitalist practices is not only inaccurate but may also come across as condescending. The DE approach aims to facilitate South–North transfer by emphasizing difference and potential, but its representatives are sometimes insensitive to the fact that certain non-capitalist practices are the norm in other parts of the world and that their value does not lie in appearing unique or exotic from a Northern perspective. That still leaves aside the issue of whether pre-colonial non-capitalist practices are less exploitative and exclusionary than capitalist ones. Or whether pre-colonial empires and their economic practices were any less discriminatory towards the ‘other’ peoples they conquered and enslaved.</p><p>Spanning over 550 pages and 58 chapters across seven sections, the book presents a daunting amount of material. It includes contributions of 69 authors from various backgrounds, career stages and corners of the world. This richness makes the handbook an invaluable starting point for those interested in identifying and seeing the variety of economic practices around the world. By adding studies on new topics and finding analytical connections among them, the handbook improves the coherence of the approach. It presents an up to date collection of cases with cross-cutting issues salient in 2020. Several of the practices studied are rooted in collective action and hope, and the politics of hope (Denzin, <span>2000</span>) is discussed in detail in this handbook. The DE programme emphasizes hope by showing how personal and interpersonal efforts may play a role in demonstrating the possibility of alternative futures (Zademach and Hillebrand, <span>2013</span>).</p><p>The first five sections of the handbook are organized around the categories of enterprises, labour, transactions, property and finance. Each section starts with a framing essay that aims to contextualize the topic and make explicit the connections between the chapters comprising that section. For example, the framing essay of section one on enterprise diversity is authored by Jenny Cameron (pp. 26–39) and focuses on class. From the perspective of the diverse economies framework, class is conceived as a process of producing, appropriating and distributing surplus labour in various types of enterprises. The framing essay is followed by nine studies on the various class processes in these spaces, including worker cooperatives, worker-owned factories, anti-crime initiatives and other kinds of community enterprises and eco-social and ethical businesses. The second section looks at labour and in addition to the framing essay, it consists of eight chapters on precarious labour, informal and unpaid labour, care work, collectively performed reciprocal labour, informal mining and the non-human labour of ‘earth others’. The third section on transactions presents a framing essay, followed by eight chapters on gleaning, community supported agriculture, collective food procurement, alternative currencies, time banking, fair trade networks, social procurement and shared urban spaces. After a framing essay, the fourth section examines property in six chapters focusing on commoning, land trusts, urban land markets and free universities. The fifth section deals with finance and includes a framing article followed by five chapters on Islamic finance, rotating savings and credit associations, indigenous finance, community investment funds and hacking finance. In short, the book chapters cover a broad range of different topics and cases, with ethics and hope as the common principle that drives these diverse and alternative economic practices.</p><p>The diverse economies framework focuses on practices to convey its distance from economic determinism (the ontological restriction to certain economic processes) and empirical realism (the epistemological acceptance of a separation between reality and reflection). In line with these assumptions, the last two sections of the handbook explore subjectivity and methodology. These two areas of enquiry are probably the main original contributions of this volume. The framing essay of the sixth section on subjectivity, by Healy et al., aims to clarify the meaning of the term ‘subject’ in a diverse non-capitalist economy and ‘demotes the primacy of the human subject’ (p. 389). It proposes a reading of the economic subject that explicitly recognizes an anti-essentialist framing, one that emphasizes the open-ended way in which human communities face dilemmas about consumption and necessity or investment and surplus. The authors further explain that this describes the decentred economic subject in the ‘undecidable space of a dilemma’ (p. 385) in which human communities negotiate indefinitely the conditions of ‘antagonistic interdependence’ (ibid.). It is followed by six chapters on diverse subjectivities, power, genealogy, sexuality, affections and economic subjectivity.</p><p>The last section on methodology refrains from promoting a particular methodology, in keeping with the fact that this is a research programme that takes pride in its diversity of topics and approaches. Instead, it favours the imagining of post-capitalist futures and the research interventions that can realize them. As Gibson-Graham argue in Chapter 52, the research methodologies of the diverse economies framework are varied but consistently focus on ‘reading for economic difference’ (p. 476). The seventh section therefore includes eight chapters on indigenous methodologies, assemblage analysis, action research, the tracing of relations and the use of artistic resources as method of enquiry.</p><p>In general, the handbook advances the consistency and completeness of the research programme, not as an alternative economics textbook but as a different approach to understanding what the economy is, in its geographical and everyday diversity. It introduces itself as a set of weak theoretical tools to support the study of capitalist, non-capitalist and community/alternative capitalist practices. While <i>seeing</i> disruptive practices constitutes a first step, the handbook repeatedly reminds the reader that the goal of the research programme is to recover and revalorize the possibilities of a non-capitalist future, or, at least, to demonstrate that capitalist practices are only one of various modalities of economic interaction to secure the material survival and reproduction of communities. Showing and seeing the heterogeneity of economic practices would promote conceptions of and projects advancing a non-capitalist future. Gibson-Graham (<span>2008</span>) claimed that ‘changing our understanding of the world is to change the world’, which is a clear indication of their commitment to performative research. Building on this premise, the DE research programme had been prolific and had contributed a large number of books, academic articles and activists’ reports. It was time to condense its contributions in a massive, comprehensive handbook.</p><p>While the volume is an excellent effort to mitigate the dispersion of topics, cases and differentiated framings within the diverse economies approach, it does not go far enough in engaging with some of the points of critique raised above. The handbook aims to provide the means to create a systematic inventory of diverse, human-scale, community-led economic practices without necessarily assessing how desirable these are. Since its inception in 1996, this post-capitalist research project has generated crowds of adepts and sceptics. The group of supporters appreciates its potential to examine economic diversity and recognize the alterity of economic practices rooted in the politics of hope. The group of sceptics keeps on asking the same questions, which continue to go unanswered. The danger of such silence is that a new sect of scholar-activists may arise, repeating the same narrative in the hope that it will become true. A key proposition of the handbook is that we are occupying a post-capitalist future without fully explaining how we are to know that we have arrived there or specifying which part of the future they are describing. The debate is certainly open as to whether we are experiencing a post-neoliberal phase or another cycle of conservative neoliberalism (Fine and Saad-Filho, <span>2014</span>; Gaudichaud et al., <span>2022</span>; Strange, <span>2016</span>).</p><p>When Gibson and Graham published <i>The End of Capitalism (As We Knew it)</i> in 1996, they produced what many economic geographers considered to be one of the ‘most innovative and startling re-interpretations of the economy in the last decades’ (Zademach and Hillebrand, <span>2013</span>: 16). Their contributions accumulated and were further developed by other scholars around the world, evolving into the diverse economies research programme. The programme offers a post-structuralist reading of political, economic and social interaction to disclose the multiple economic practices that are already in existence within the economic landscape. It has supported the elaboration of a new economic dictionary, with more inclusive language. Moreover, it has recaptured the element of hope in existing initiatives that increase well-being in everyday economic life. At the same time, it has been unable to develop clear criteria on the desirability or progressiveness of those other-than-capitalist economic practices, how they could accumulate sufficient transformative potential, or what effects they could have at the various levels of economic life (households, regions, national and global systems). In relation to development studies, the programme may offer an interesting avenue for South–North knowledge transfer, but that would require another round of remaking the language of economic diversity to account for what is standard and what is alternative. The proportion of the economy that can be described as capitalist — represented by formal labour, pure private property, markets with transparent prices and mainstream finance — may be too small in many countries in the global South for other practices to be considered as ‘alternative’. Just taking account of the informal monetized economic activities measured by Medina and Schneider (<span>2019</span>: 11), alternatives to formal capitalist practices made up 63 per cent of GDP in Bolivia and 57 per cent of GDP in Nigeria. Labelling these as ‘alternative’ therefore does not do justice to their pervasiveness. To consider the alterity of these practices as a matter of degree, as suggested by Jonas (<span>2016</span>), may therefore be a more valid analytical instrument.</p><p>There is also the question of the relationship between capitalist and non-capitalist practices, which situates the diverse economies approach between radical political economy perspectives and the utopians. While the Marxist literature has been dismissive of the latter, the literature on communitarian and human-centred practices has been a source of undeniable hope in the possibility of a post-capitalist future on a healthy planet. Yet the position of these non-capitalist economies in relation to the capitalist economy needs considerably more elaboration within the DE research programme. Are they subordinate, parallel, complementary, or transformative projects in relation the capitalist economy based on waged labour and private property? The answer would not be the same for the unpaid domestic economy, the informal inferior circuits of value, or the value-oriented grassroots niches pursuing ecologically informed economic projects.</p><p>While acknowledging the difficulties of identifying alterity, the actors and their historical and geographical situations, Fickey and Hanrahan (<span>2015</span>: 400) recommend that scholars studying alterity engage more with one another. Indeed, there is a need to compare notes and increase the empirical basis of the research project in a systematic way. <i>The Handbook of Diverse Economies</i> takes a small step in that direction by bringing together a massive network of authors, case studies and methodologies in one volume. What could come next is clearer proof of the research programme's capacity to engage critically with itself.</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":48194,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Development and Change\",\"volume\":\"54 2\",\"pages\":\"442-460\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":3.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2023-03-15\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/dech.12762\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Development and Change\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"90\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/dech.12762\",\"RegionNum\":2,\"RegionCategory\":\"社会学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q1\",\"JCRName\":\"DEVELOPMENT STUDIES\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Development and Change","FirstCategoryId":"90","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/dech.12762","RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"DEVELOPMENT STUDIES","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

朱莉、凯瑟琳·吉布森-格雷厄姆和凯利·东布罗斯基(编),《多样化经济手册》。切尔滕纳姆和北安普顿,马萨诸塞州:爱德华·埃尔加,2020年。546页,精装本售价199.80英镑。以人为中心和共同体经济的思想传统由来已久。它与对乌托邦(无土地)和乌托邦(梦幻之地)的追求有关,这种追求随着资本主义的出现和对资本积累的痴迷而加速,后者的名字由此而来。查尔斯·傅立叶、西尔维奥·格塞尔、弗朗索瓦·玛丽、卡尔·马克思、罗伯特·欧文和皮埃尔-约瑟夫·蒲鲁东等知识分子是发展社会、经济和政治替代资本主义的先驱。正如法国社会学家皮埃尔·布迪厄(Pierre Bourdieu, 1998: 125)所观察到的那样,他们与托马斯·莫尔爵士(Sir Thomas More)最初的16世纪集体主义和乌托邦社会主义进行了接触,这种社会主义“经常以经济现实主义的名义受到质疑、驳斥和嘲笑”。在这一传统的基础上,学者夫妇凯瑟琳·吉布森和朱莉·格雷厄姆在30年前提出了多样化经济(DE)方法从那时起,它已经发展成为学者们的一个成熟的研究项目和活动家们的一个社会转型愿景。他们的最新科学著作《多样化经济手册》由j·k·吉布森-格雷厄姆和凯利·东布罗斯基编辑,也是本文的主题。通过捕捉和评估目前在资本主义制度的间隙中扩散的各种经济、社会和政治空间,多样化经济方法获得了相当大的牵引力。这些空间,DE的作者和追随者会强调,不是发生在乌托邦主义的无地和梦幻之地的想象力的练习,而是全球希望的有形和真实的来源。它们是逃避资本主义或形成对资本主义的抵抗并动员集体的现存空间。强调建立资本主义的替代方案是可行的,因为它正在进行中,多样化经济手册增加了案例,发现和反思,并邀请学者对经济替代方案的理解和写作方式进行分析。然而,正如之前的作品(见Gibson-Graham, 1996, 2008),在最后一本书中,与女权主义、后结构和后发展圈子之外的学者的接触仍然悬而未决。虽然这本新书细化了与新自由主义政治和“主流价值回路的压倒性统一性”的对比(Fuller等人,2016:xxiv),但它不满足与其他理论化替代方案的方式接触的需要,以克服占主导地位的资本主义体系内不同经济的相对边缘地位。一些较早的批评DE方法的明确解决,但普遍缺乏接受批评限制了研究计划的影响超出了支持者和党派倡导的圈子后资本主义的未来。本文首先介绍了另类的概念和乌托邦主义的轨迹,以及多元经济方法是如何在这一传统中定位的。它随后提出了对先前研究的批评,随后是对新书(以下简称手册)及其对这一学术工作的贡献的评论。这篇文章深入研究了这个新增加的内容所涵盖和未涵盖的细节,以及它与发展研究领域的相关性。多样化经济框架的一个关键成就是,它重新点燃了关于替代和替代概念的辩论(Fickey, 2011;Lee et al., 2004)。这并不是一场新的辩论,考虑到自资本主义起源以来,资本主义替代品的智力生产一直激励着人类。与此相一致的是,争论的概念总是拒绝基于私有财产及其产生的有偿就业的剩余提取,但他们对替代意义的解释和重点有所不同。Gritzas和Kavoulakos(2016)将关于资本主义替代品的学术工作分为两大类。“乌托邦主义者”赞成合作社或社区经济的组织;蒲鲁东就是其中之一,在某种程度上,波兰尼和格塞尔也紧随其后。以马克思和恩格斯为代表的怀疑主义阵营对乌托邦计划及其缺乏“科学”反思尤其不屑一顾;他们确信这种乌托邦式的倡议注定要失败(恩格斯,1968)。马克思和恩格斯认为,个人无法从下而上改变社会,因为他们没有资源来维持劳动关系之外的生活。由于工人不拥有或控制生产资料,他们无法获得支付食物、住宿和满足其他基本生存需要所需的资源。 然而,这些非资本主义经济体相对于资本主义经济的地位,需要在经济学的研究计划中得到更多的阐述。它们是从属的、平行的、互补的,还是与基于有偿劳动和私有财产的资本主义经济相关的变革项目?对于没有报酬的国内经济、非正式的次等价值回路或追求生态知情经济项目的以价值为导向的基层利基来说,答案是不一样的。Fickey和Hanrahan(2015: 400)在承认识别另类、行动者及其历史和地理状况的困难的同时,建议研究另类的学者更多地相互接触。的确,有必要进行比较,系统地增加研究项目的经验基础。《多样化经济手册》在这个方向上迈出了一小步,它将大量的作者、案例研究和方法汇集在一起。接下来可能会出现更清晰的证据,证明该研究项目有能力批判性地与自身接触。 根据马克思和恩格斯的观点,从长远来看,形成小型网络或社区也不会提高乌托邦主义者成功的机会,因为资本主义之外的生活需要来自某个地方的资源。此外,如果这种退出资本主义成为大量工人的生活选择,国家将进行干预,以防止大规模选择退出资本主义经济(North, 2016)。后来的正统马克思主义学者同样抛弃了naïve等倡议的潜力,转而提倡全面的激进社会变革,当资本主义制度达到其生产力边界时,这种变革将终止资本主义的霸权。最近,学者们对替代项目的贫瘠性质提出了质疑,并建议在当前时代,自下而上的乌托邦倡议没有潜在需求的说法需要进行实证研究(Gómez, 2018;北方,1999,2016;Pacione, 1997)。马克思主义的怀疑论最终主导了20世纪挑战资本主义的知识辩论,将较小的乌托邦倡议委托给知识边缘(Fuller等人,2016)。社会主义和资本主义之间的对抗导致了对资本主义经济的管制,在一些国家导致了福利国家的出现,这些国家重新分配了经济利益,进一步将乌托邦式的经济和政治实验推向了边缘(Gritzas和Kavoulakos, 2016)。随着20世纪80年代末激进政治经济学的衰落和新自由主义的兴起,另类思维的空间在无地和梦幻岛中消失了。具有讽刺意味的是,这加剧了学者们的研究,他们并没有被小规模实践的明显影响所吓倒(Holloway, 2010)。学者们迫切需要找到另一种经济和政治实践,在霸权的新自由主义资本主义背景下带来希望。这种探索最终在20世纪90年代中期取得了进展,当时福利国家的撤退受到了质疑,新的社会运动(如墨西哥的萨帕塔运动)出现了,反全球化抗议活动势头强劲。1996年,女权主义经济地理学家凯瑟琳·吉布森和朱莉·格雷厄姆出版了《资本主义的终结(正如我们所知):政治经济学的女权主义批判》(吉布森-格雷厄姆,1996)。十年后,他们在《后资本主义政治》(Gibson-Graham, 2006)一书中收集了他们的观点。《资本主义的终结》是一个具有挑衅性的、新鲜的和开创性的尝试,它捕捉了世界各地正在建立不同的经济和政治互动空间的各种社区的努力。“不同空间”的资格适用于各种各样的非资本主义项目,以及直接反对资本主义的替代方案。DE方法的关键分析工具是一个基于扎实和薄弱理论的综合画布。该框架提出了与企业、劳动力、交易、财产和金融相关的经验实践的广泛清单,以构建经济活动的三个松散类别或领域:非资本主义、资本主义和替代资本主义(见表1)。在随后的认同该方法的出版物中,增加了更多的例子。通过这种方式,DE方法收集了世界各地许多不同实践的研究,这些实践促进了社区的物质生存和文化生活的再生产。这些出版物促使一群学者和活动家组成了社区经济研究网络(CERN),该网络在世界各地从事研究、反思和实践活动在撰写本文时,《资本主义的终结》(Gibson-Graham, 1996)已经被引用了5350次,Google Scholar列出了10500个关键词“多样化经济”,这表明这个概念是如何在一些学术和激进主义圈子中流行起来的。在思想上,德意志论将自己定位于乌托邦主义者和马克思主义者之间。Gibson-Graham(1996, 2006)将资本主义定义为表1所示的五大支柱:有偿劳动、剥削性企业、私有财产、市场交换和基于利息的金融。他们认为有太多的实验没有遵循这五个特征,他们批评结构主义马克思主义的方法是“以资本主义为中心的”,这意味着他们忽视了非资本主义范畴的大量实践。他们进一步认为,马克思主义方法用一种本质主义的、单一的话语来评估资本主义,这种话语掩盖了既不基于雇佣劳动也不基于剥削的“其他”经济实践。他们声称,马克思主义的作品用“集权化的概念和机器般的隐喻”来描述资本主义(乔纳斯,2016:6),以表达其对非资本主义空间的统治。 由于这些实践不被注意,被视为不值得考虑,马克思主义的叙述将支持这样一种信念,即非资本主义项目太小,边缘和无关紧要,无法实现任何系统性转型。Gibson-Graham(1996)认为,将非资本主义项目隐藏起来或看不见,会使它们显得无关和无能为力,从而压制了现有的多样性,进一步阻止了对非资本主义未来的想象。因此,看到多样性的能力受到了损害,而DE项目的一部分恰恰是构建另一本字典来讨论和分析多样性。这种方法的出发点是,非资本主义经济体系仍然是不可见的,这需要进一步讨论。激进的政治经济学学者已经在资本主义内部研究了这些不同的经济,但基于这样的假设,即它们是资本主义经济的从属子系统,这使它们能够确保自己的生存,并且它们缺乏作为替代经济项目的自主性(乔纳斯,2016)。例如,激进的发展地理学家米尔顿·桑托斯(Milton Santos, 1977)提出了两个相互关联的经济循环的空间辩证法理论。桑托斯的理由是,城市经济由资本密集型现代产业组成的“上层”组成,而“下层”则由劳动密集型的小型企业组成,这些企业暴露在价格谈判中。在桑托斯的描述中,这两个回路为控制城市领土而斗争,上层回路通常统治下层回路,并将其降至边缘。类似的,或者至少是相容的,两部门经济结构理论,其中一个优于另一个,在激进的政治经济学和结构经济学理论中是突出的(例如Fuchs, 1974;赫希曼,1958;刘易斯,1954)。其他作者(如Elson, 2007年,2017年)认为,资本主义的再生产依赖于国内经济的无偿工作来维持政治和经济领域,这反过来又产生了维持资本主义经济的资源。这些对资本主义和非资本主义经济关系的平行解读将后者置于从属关系中。吉布森-格雷厄姆批评了这种先验的价值判断;冒着过度概括的风险,他们认为马克思主义的描述没有看到这些替代方案的潜力,而不是将它们视为平等,而是将它们视为从属。相比之下,多样化经济方法强调水平性和空间差异与共存,尽管并非没有紧张关系。吉布森-格雷厄姆批判了假定的上下级关系,提出了通过对多样性和互动性的系统分析来摆脱资本中心主义的方法。也就是说,他们的目标是“创造一种经济差异的话语,作为对经济创新政治的贡献”(Gibson-Graham, 2005: 6)。他们的方法强调资本主义五大支柱的多样性和组合(见表1),并认为当前的异质性只是未来系统性转型的开始。他们用多样化的经济取代了单一的全球资本主义经济的概念(乔纳斯,2016)。他们试图揭示经济是异质的,它包括其他交换机制、生产组织、财产类型和劳动和金融奖励(希利,2009年,2011年)。作为一项研究项目,DE方法侧重于识别和记录全球范围内各种各样的经济活动。它旨在描述一种“其他”项目被登记和重估的后资本主义经济。虽然吉布森和格雷厄姆明确地与马克思主义保持距离,但他们也与乌托邦主义保持距离。多样化经济方法的目的是确定已经实施的无数经济实践,作为资本主义经济的补充或替代。这个想法是把它们作为自主的空间来展示,而不是像梦幻庄园那样,作为劣等或从属的项目。因此,对于那些已经构思并实施替代性经济实践的创新活动家来说,学术项目也是一种合法化的力量,他们看到自己的努力反映在学术理论中。他们同样鼓励表演,并特别邀请学者尝试行动研究。DE方法的重点是斗争的可能性,而不是成功的概率(Gibson-Graham, 2008: 615)。多样性的概念暗示了一种内在的积极内涵或某种进步的光环,需要加以检验。正如Samers(2005)所指出的,一些非资本主义经济实践与资本主义实践一样具有剥削性,甚至更具剥削性,例如现代奴隶制和各种形式的无偿工作。 根据最近的一个数据库,超过30%的世界经济是非正式生产的,尽管这一比例在过去二十年中大幅下降,直到大流行(Medina和Schneider, 2019年)。30%的数字本身隐藏着巨大的多样性;非正式经济是一个单一名称下的经济关系和实践的混合体,包括现金支付的非正式工人,不通过正式银行渠道获得完全报酬的半非正式工人,以及其他无薪工作的人(Gómez等人,2020;威廉姆斯,2011;Williams and Windebank, 1998)。在非正式的某些角落,代理人组织了市场、协会、自助倡议和其他方式来组织他们的经济生活,这些方式很好地符合多样化经济框架的“非资本主义”框架。然而,在非正规经济的其他角落,它没有任何进步,多样性的概念掩盖了无数形式的剥削和痛苦。多元经济框架不承认非资本主义企业的对比多样性。与非正规经济的异质性相一致,少数高薪数字工人与大量不受保护的基于应用程序的工人(Meagher, 2019)和低收入的“工作穷人”(Fisker, 2022;Williams and Round, 2008)。同样,社区经济背后的“社区”往往充斥着权力不对称和不平等(Bayat, 1997)。合作社和自我管理的工人企业很少能为创造它们的失业者提供体面的生活(Suryanata et al., 2021)。集体行动需要信任,而信任在非正规经济中通常是缺失的,因此它仍然是无组织的,充斥着一群群为生存而挣扎的贫困工人。通过批判资本主义实践,所有其他实践似乎都值得推广,而另类并不一定优越。Samers(2005: 883)质疑这种对非正规经济的短视理解,并断言“我们需要对非正规经济或多样化经济进行更深入的分析处理,区分其更平凡但令人消化不良的品种(即大量的非正规就业)和那些看起来更“进步”的生产、提取和剩余再分配”。换句话说,我们需要超越这样的假设,即所有与资本主义不同的东西都是可取的。还有一个相关的问题,即“如果资本主义和非资本主义实践的清单包括剥削项目,那么它的理论优势是什么?”更仔细地区分理想的多样性和不理想的多样性是DE框架的一个悬而未决的任务,它尚未得到解决,也没有出现在手册中。因此,许多学者主张放弃对“多样性”固有的积极欣赏,将其作为对现状不满的主要表达方式(Schreven等人,2008)。其他人更喜欢“另类”的概念,认为它是一种非二元的话语选择,表达了分离的程度,并取决于特定的语境和空间(例如乔纳斯,2013;李,2000)。他们将另类定义为“一种以存在于既定范畴之外的术语来认识、表现和叙述他人的方式”(Jonas, 2016: 9)。换句话说,另类是分析性和经验性对他人感的建构(Fuller等人,2016)。然而,在任何尺度和程度上的替代都暗示着一种内在的积极内容,这种内容高估了许多倡议的先进性。其他学者发展了“自治地理”的概念,指的是旨在推翻资本主义和建立后资本主义集体空间的活动家的政治网络(例如Pickerill和Chatterton, 2006)。因此,他们将政治和经济自治视为将理想与替代结合起来的中心标准。这样一种概念化呈现出一种优势,即一种具有社会意识的运动需要出现在另类的生产中,而不是任何形式的非资本主义多样性,可能被某个特定的社会群体所追求,也可能不被追求。对多元经济研究计划的第二个经过充分研究的批评是规模问题,这一点已被几位作者注意到。Lee等人(2010)特别质疑小规模、亲密、利基、地方和基层项目的有效性。该评论考察了整个本地化案例研究和研究干预措施清单的现实变革潜力,这些清单表明,这些案例研究和研究干预措施是许多、不同的,并且与参与者单独相关。 正如马克思和恩格斯(Engels, 1968)所指出的那样,为第二产业的生存提供资源的部门显然更有可能主导不同经济体的议程。不同的经济实践以不同的关系出现在资本主义经济中:转化的、互补的和从属的。然而,它似乎不能被先验地定义。因此,还有第三个重要的批评领域,它与创建各种实践清单的目的有关。为什么它与改造资本主义的目标相关?吉布森和格雷厄姆(Gibson-Graham, 2008)在他们的文章《多样化经济:其他世界的行为实践》中,与提出这个问题的怀疑论者进行了接触,并解释说,改变我们对世界的理解就是改变世界,即使只是部分地和局部地改变世界。然而,15年过去了,这个问题仍然没有答案:对异质实践的承认,无论文献多么丰富,在哪些方面有助于改变资本主义制度?这本手册提供了相当模糊的线索来阐明一条或多条道路——从想象后资本主义的未来,到定义它们的可取性,或者看到它们摆脱剥削性的经济体系。通过研究干预创造一种多样化的语言无疑是一个积极的步骤,但它还不足以产生该计划所促进的物质世界中人类生存的转变。与此同时,右翼政府和争夺自然资源的战争不断制造冲突和分离之墙。对于从事发展研究的学者来说,还有第四个问题需要探索。在一个非殖民化的世界里,另类是如何定义的?多元经济方法有助于发现资本主义以外的实践,支持将其他本体论与全球对话和学术工作联系起来。非资本主义实践的概念在一些地方是有意义的,在这些地方,资本主义实践是规则,而非资本主义实践需要被揭示,以改变学者们所接受的训练,首先看到的是什么。但是,非资本主义实践在与前殖民、后殖民和去殖民经济的关系中可能占有不同的地位。在全球南方的广大地区,资本主义实践是经济转型漫长道路上的最后补充,而不是相反。正如手册中某些章节所讨论的那样,发展中国家的各种经济包括已经存在了几个世纪的生计活动。因此,很难断言它们在多大程度上可以被视为“另类”,除非与西方的世界观有关,即将资本主义视为经济生活的规则。可以说,在全球南方国家,选择是常态。发展中国家的经济中充斥着非正式的、本土的、本土的和非资本主义的实践。这与多元经济方法想要传达的信息完全相反。在题为“使用土著方法”的手册第55章中,Waitoa和Dombroski解释说,在手册中纳入毛利人的方法是“确定不同经济方法和方法之间的联系和不协调的指导性点的第一步”(第502页)。这是不同经济方式对发展中世界经济生活特殊性的明确承认。它还意味着,发展经济学的方法设想本土的、本土的和本地化的经济实践——在全球南方无处不在——作为资本主义和在全球北方占主导地位的制度的替代品。在一个由非资本主义实践主导的世界里,将这些实践贴上“多样化”或“另类”的标签不仅不准确,而且可能会给人一种居高俯下的感觉。DE方法旨在通过强调差异和潜力来促进南北转移,但其代表有时对以下事实不敏感:某些非资本主义做法在世界其他地区是常态,它们的价值并不在于从北方的角度来看是独特的或异国情调的。这仍然忽略了前殖民时期的非资本主义做法是否比资本主义做法更少剥削和排斥性的问题。或者前殖民帝国和他们的经济实践对他们征服和奴役的“其他”民族的歧视是否更少?全书共550多页,分7个部分,共58章,内容之多令人生畏。它包括来自不同背景、职业阶段和世界各个角落的69位作者的贡献。这种丰富性使这本手册成为那些对识别和观察世界各地各种经济实践感兴趣的人的宝贵起点。 通过增加对新主题的研究并发现它们之间的分析联系,手册提高了方法的连贯性。它介绍了2020年突出的跨领域问题的最新案例集。所研究的一些实践植根于集体行动和希望,而希望的政治(Denzin, 2000)在本手册中进行了详细讨论。DE课程通过展示个人和人际努力如何在展示替代未来的可能性中发挥作用来强调希望(Zademach和Hillebrand, 2013)。手册的前五个部分是围绕企业、劳工、交易、财产和金融等类别组织的。每个部分都以一篇框架文章开始,旨在将主题置于背景中,并明确构成该部分的章节之间的联系。例如,第一节关于企业多样性的框架文章是由Jenny Cameron撰写的(第26-39页),主要关注班级。从多元经济框架的角度来看,阶级被认为是在各种类型的企业中生产、占有和分配剩余劳动力的过程。框架文章之后是对这些空间中各种阶级过程的九项研究,包括工人合作社,工人拥有的工厂,反犯罪倡议和其他类型的社区企业以及生态社会和道德企业。第二部分着眼于劳动,除了框架文章外,它还包括八个章节,涉及不稳定劳动、非正式和无偿劳动、护理工作、集体进行的互惠劳动、非正式采矿和“地球他人”的非人类劳动。关于交易的第三部分是一篇框架文章,接下来是关于拾取、社区支持农业、集体粮食采购、替代货币、时间银行、公平贸易网络、社会采购和共享城市空间的八章。在一篇框架文章之后,第四部分在六个章节中考察了财产,重点是共同财产、土地信托、城市土地市场和免费大学。第五部分涉及金融,包括一篇框架文章,随后是关于伊斯兰金融、轮流储蓄和信贷协会、土著金融、社区投资基金和黑客金融的五章。简而言之,这本书的章节涵盖了广泛的不同主题和案例,道德和希望是推动这些多样化和可选择的经济实践的共同原则。多元经济框架侧重于实践,以传达其与经济决定论(对某些经济过程的本体论限制)和经验现实主义(在认识论上接受现实与反思之间的分离)的距离。根据这些假设,手册的最后两个部分探讨了主观性和方法论。这两个领域的调查可能是主要的原始贡献,这一卷。希利等人撰写的关于主体性的第六部分的框架文章,旨在澄清“主体”一词在多样化的非资本主义经济中的含义,并“贬低人类主体的首要地位”(第389页)。它提出了一种对经济主题的解读,明确承认了一种反本质主义的框架,这种框架强调了人类社会面临消费和需求或投资和盈余困境的开放式方式。作者进一步解释说,这描述了“进退两难的不可确定空间”(第385页)中去中心的经济主体,在这个空间中,人类社会无限期地协商“对抗性相互依赖”的条件(同上)。接下来的六章分别论述了多元主体性、权力主体性、宗谱主体性、性主体性、情感主体性和经济主体性。关于方法论的最后一节避免推广特定的方法论,因为这是一个以其主题和方法的多样性而自豪的研究计划。相反,它倾向于想象后资本主义的未来,以及能够实现这些未来的研究干预。正如Gibson-Graham在第52章中所指出的那样,不同经济体框架的研究方法各不相同,但始终专注于“解读经济差异”(第476页)。因此,第七部分包括八个章节,内容涉及本土方法论、组合分析、行动研究、关系追踪和艺术资源作为探究方法的使用。总的来说,这本手册提高了研究计划的一致性和完整性,不是作为另一本经济学教科书,而是作为一种不同的方法来理解经济是什么,在其地理和日常多样性方面。它将自己介绍为一套薄弱的理论工具,以支持对资本主义、非资本主义和社区/替代资本主义实践的研究。 虽然看到破坏性实践是第一步,但手册反复提醒读者,研究计划的目标是恢复和重新评估非资本主义未来的可能性,或者,至少,证明资本主义实践只是各种经济互动模式中的一种,以确保社区的物质生存和再生产。展示和看到经济实践的异质性将促进推进非资本主义未来的概念和项目。Gibson-Graham(2008)声称“改变我们对世界的理解就是改变世界”,这清楚地表明了他们对行为研究的承诺。在这个前提下,DE研究项目一直很多产,并贡献了大量的书籍、学术文章和活动家的报告。是时候把它的贡献浓缩成一本庞大而全面的手册了。虽然这本书在缓解不同经济体方法中主题、案例和差异化框架的分散方面做了出色的努力,但它在涉及上述批评的一些观点方面做得还不够。该手册旨在提供一种方法,对各种各样的、以人为尺度的、社区主导的经济实践进行系统的盘点,而不必评估这些实践有多可取。自1996年成立以来,这个后资本主义研究项目已经产生了大量的专家和怀疑论者。这群支持者赞赏它在审查经济多样性和认识植根于希望政治的经济实践的多样性方面的潜力。这群怀疑论者一直在问同样的问题,而这些问题仍然没有答案。这种沉默的危险在于,一个新的学者激进分子派别可能会出现,重复同样的叙述,希望它能成为现实。这本手册的一个关键主张是,我们正处于一个后资本主义的未来,但没有充分解释我们如何知道我们已经到达那里,也没有具体说明他们描述的是未来的哪一部分。关于我们是否正在经历后新自由主义阶段或另一个保守新自由主义周期的辩论当然是开放的(Fine and Saad-Filho, 2014;Gaudichaud et al., 2022;奇怪,2016)。1996年,吉布森和格雷厄姆出版了《资本主义的终结(正如我们所知)》,许多经济地理学家认为这是“过去几十年来最具创新性和令人吃惊的经济重新解释”之一(扎德马赫和希勒布兰德,2013:16)。他们的贡献不断积累,并被世界各地的其他学者进一步发展,演变成多元经济研究计划。该计划提供了政治,经济和社会互动的后结构主义阅读,以揭示经济景观中已经存在的多种经济实践。它支持编写一部新的经济词典,其语言更具包容性。此外,它在增加日常经济生活福祉的现有倡议中重新获得了希望的因素。与此同时,对于那些非资本主义经济实践的可取性或先进性,它们如何能够积累足够的变革潜力,或者它们在经济生活的各个层面(家庭、区域、国家和全球系统)可能产生的影响,它一直无法制定明确的标准。关于发展研究,该方案可能为南北知识转移提供一个有趣的途径,但这将需要另一轮修改经济多样性的语言,以说明什么是标准的,什么是替代的。在全球南方的许多国家,可以被描述为资本主义的经济比例——以正式劳动力、纯粹的私有财产、价格透明的市场和主流金融为代表——可能太小,以至于其他实践被认为是“替代”。仅考虑到Medina和Schneider(2019: 11)衡量的非正式货币化经济活动,正式资本主义实践的替代方案占玻利维亚GDP的63%,占尼日利亚GDP的57%。因此,将这些标记为“替代”并不能公平地对待它们的普遍性。正如乔纳斯(2016)所建议的那样,将这些实践的替代性视为程度问题,因此可能是一种更有效的分析工具。还有资本主义和非资本主义实践之间的关系问题,它将激进的政治经济学观点和乌托邦主义者之间的不同经济方法置于其中。虽然马克思主义文献对后者不屑一顾,但关于社群主义和以人为中心的实践的文献一直是一个不可否认的希望的来源,即在一个健康的星球上实现后资本主义未来的可能性。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
How Far Does the Diverse Economies Approach Take Us?

Julie and Katherine Gibson-Graham and Kelly Dombroski (eds), The Handbook of Diverse Economies. Cheltenham and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 2020. 546 pp. £ 199.80 hardback.

There is a long-standing tradition of thought on human-centred and communitarian economies. It connects to a search for utopias (no lands) and udetopias (neverlands) which has accelerated with the advent of capitalism and the obsession with capital accumulation that gave the latter system its name. Intellectuals like Charles Fourier, Silvio Gesell, François Marie, Karl Marx, Robert Owen and Pierre-Joseph Proudhon were pioneers in developing social, economic and political alternatives to capitalism. They engaged with the original 16th century collectivist and utopian socialism of Sir Thomas More, which, as French sociologist Pierre Bourdieu (1998: 125) observed, was ‘often discredited, dismissed and ridiculed in the name of economic realism’. Drawing on this tradition, the scholarly couple Katherine Gibson and Julie Graham added the diverse economies (DE) approach three decades ago.1 Since then, it has developed into a fully-fledged research programme among scholars and a vision of social transformation among activists. The latest arrival in their scientific production The Handbook of Diverse Economies, is edited by J.K. Gibson-Graham and Kelly Dombroski, and the subject of this critical review.

Through capturing and valorizing the variety of economic, social and political spaces that currently proliferate in the interstices of the capitalist system, the diverse economies approach has gained considerable traction. These spaces, DE authors and followers would emphasize, are not an exercise of the imagination occurring in the no lands and neverlands of utopianism, but tangible and true sources of global hope. They are existing spaces which evade capitalism or shape resistance to it, and mobilize collectives. Underlining that building alternatives to capitalism is feasible as it is ongoing, The Handbook of Diverse Economies adds cases, findings and reflections, and invites analysis of the way scholars understand and write about economic alternatives.

However, as in previous works (see Gibson-Graham, 1996, 2008), engagement with academics outside feminist, post-structural and post-development circles remains pending in this last book. While this new volume refines the contrast with neoliberal politics and the ‘crushing uniformity of mainstream circuits of value’ (Fuller et al., 2016: xxiv), it does not meet the need to engage with other ways of theorizing alternatives to overcome the relatively marginal position of diverse economies within the dominant capitalist system. Some of the older critiques of the DE approach are explicitly addressed, but the general lack of receptiveness to criticism limits the influence of the research programme beyond the circles of supporters and partisan advocates of a post-capitalist future.

This essay begins by introducing the notion of alterity and the trajectory of utopianism, and how the diverse economies approach is situated within this tradition. It subsequently presents a critique of previous research, which is followed by a review of the new book (hereafter referred to as the handbook) and its contribution to this body of scholarly work. The essay delves into the details of what has and what has not been covered by this new addition, and its relevance to the field of development studies.

A key achievement of the diverse economies framework is that it has rekindled the debate on the notions of alternatives and alterity (Fickey, 2011; Lee et al., 2004). It is not a new debate, considering that the intellectual production of alternatives to capitalism has inspired humankind since the origins of capitalism itself. In line with this, contending conceptions invariably reject surplus extraction based on private property and its resulting waged employment, but they differ in their interpretation and focus of the meaning of alternative.

Gritzas and Kavoulakos (2016) have clustered scholarly work on alternatives to capitalism in two broad groups. The ‘utopians’ favoured the organization of a cooperative or community economy; Proudhon was among them, and to some extent, Polanyi and Gesell later followed. The sceptic camp, of which Marx and Engels are representatives, were particularly dismissive of utopian projects and their lack of ‘scientific’ reflection; they were convinced that such utopian initiatives were bound to fail (Engels, 1968). Marx and Engels reasoned that individuals cannot change society from below because they do not have the resources to afford a life outside a waged relationship. As workers do not own or control the means of production, they are not able to access the resources needed to afford food, accommodation and meet other basic needs for survival. According to Marx and Engels, forming small networks or communities does not improve utopians’ chances of success in the long run either, because a life outside capitalism requires resources that must come from somewhere. Furthermore, if such a withdrawal from capitalism becomes the life choice of significant numbers of workers, the state would intervene to prevent a mass opt-out from the capitalist economy (North, 2016). Subsequent orthodox Marxist scholars similarly discarded the potential of such initiatives as naïve and instead promoted full-scale radical social change that would terminate the hegemony of capitalism when the system had reached its productivity boundary. Recently, scholars have contested the sterile nature of alternative projects and suggest that in current times, the claim that utopian initiatives from below have no potential needs to be researched empirically (Gómez, 2018; North, 1999, 2016; Pacione, 1997).

The scepticism of the Marxist strand eventually dominated the intellectual debate that challenged capitalism during the 20th century, consigning smaller utopian initiatives to the intellectual margins (Fuller et al., 2016). The confrontation between socialism and capitalism resulted in the regulation of capitalist economies which in some countries led to the emergence of welfare states that redistributed economic benefits, further pushing utopian economic and political experiments to the margins (Gritzas and Kavoulakos, 2016). With the decline of radical political economy and the rise of neoliberalism in the late 1980s, the scope for alternative thinking was lost in no lands and neverlands. Ironically, this intensified the search among academics who were not deterred by the apparent implications of small-scale practices (Holloway, 2010). There was a dire need among scholars to find alternative economic and political practices that would bring hope against the background of hegemonic neoliberal capitalism. The search finally made progress towards the mid-1990s, when the retreat of the welfare state was being contested, new social movements such as the Zapatistas in Mexico emerged and anti-globalization protests gained momentum.

In 1996, the feminist economic geographers Katherine Gibson and Julie Graham published The End of Capitalism (As We Knew it): A Feminist Critique of Political Economy (Gibson-Graham, 1996). A decade later, they collected their ideas in A Postcapitalist Politics (Gibson-Graham, 2006). The End of Capitalism was a provocative, fresh and ground-breaking attempt to capture the efforts of various communities around the world that were building different spaces of economic and political interaction. The qualification of ‘different spaces’ applies to a varied set of non-capitalist projects as well as alternatives that directly oppose capitalism. The key analytical instrument of the DE approach is a comprehensive canvas based on grounded and weak theory. The framework presents a broad inventory of empirical practices related to enterprises, labour, transactions, property and finance to construct three loose categories or domains of economic activity: non-capitalist, capitalist and alternative to capitalist (see Table 1). In subsequent publications identifying with the approach, more examples have been added. In this way, the DE approach collected studies on a multitude of different practices around the world that facilitate the material survival of communities and the reproduction of their cultural life. The publications led to a group of scholar-activists forming the Community Economies Research Network (CERN), which engages in research, reflection and practical activities around the world.2 At the time of writing,3 The End of Capitalism (Gibson-Graham, 1996) has been cited 5,350 times and Google Scholar lists 10,500 hits for the keyword ‘diverse economies’, which shows how the concept has gained in popularity in some academic and activist circles.

Intellectually, the DE approach positions itself between the utopians and the Marxists. Gibson-Graham (1996, 2006) define capitalism in relation to five pillars as shown in Table 1: waged labour, exploitative enterprises, private property, market exchange and interest-based finances. They contend that there are too many experiments that do not follow these five characteristics and they criticize the structuralist Marxist approaches for being ‘capitalocentric’, meaning that they ignore the immense variety of practices in the non-capitalist categories. They further argue that Marxist approaches assess capitalism with an essentialist, monolithic discourse that clouds ‘other’ economic practices that are not based either on wage labour or on exploitation. Marxist work, they claim, describes capitalism with ‘totalising concepts and machine-like metaphors’ (Jonas, 2016: 6) to express its domination over non-capitalist spaces. As these practices go unnoticed and are treated as unworthy of consideration, the Marxist narrative would endorse the belief that non-capitalist projects are too small, marginal and irrelevant to achieve any systemic transformation. According to Gibson-Graham (1996), keeping non-capitalist projects hidden or invisible makes them appear irrelevant and powerless, thereby silencing existing diversity and further preventing the imagining of non-capitalist futures. The capacity to see diversity is thus impaired and part of the DE project is precisely to construct another dictionary to discuss and analyse alterity.

The point of departure of the approach, that non-capitalist economic systems have remained invisible, calls for further discussion. Radical political economy scholars have examined these different economies within capitalism but based on the assumptions that they are subordinate subsystems of the capitalist economy, which sustains them to secure its own survival, and that they lack autonomy as alternative economic projects (Jonas, 2016). For example, radical development geographer Milton Santos (1977) posited the theory of spatial dialectics with two interconnected economic circuits. Santos reasoned that the urban economy is composed of the ‘upper circuit’ populated by capital-intensive modern industries while the ‘lower circuit’ groups the labour-intensive smaller enterprises exposed to price bargaining. In Santos’s account, the two circuits struggle for control over the urban territory, with the upper circuit normally dominating the lower one and relegating it to the margins. Similar, or at least compatible, theories of two-sector economic structures in which one is superior to the other were salient in radical political economy and structural economic theory (e.g. Fuchs, 1974; Hirschman, 1958; Lewis, 1954). Other authors (e.g. Elson, 2007, 2017) argue that capitalism depends for its reproduction on the unpaid work of the domestic economy to sustain the political and economic spheres, which in turn generate the resources that sustain the capitalist economy. These parallel readings of the relation between capitalist and non-capitalist economies situate the latter in a relationship of subordination. Gibson-Graham criticize this a priori value judgement; at the risk of overgeneralization, they argue that Marxist accounts fail to see the potential of such alternatives and, rather than regarding them as equals, they are treated as subordinates.

In contrast, the diverse economies approach emphasizes horizontality and spatial differentiation with co-existence, although not without tensions. Gibson-Graham critiqued the assumed superior–inferior relationship and proposed an escape out of capitalocentrism by means of a systematic analysis of diversity and alterity. That is, they aim at ‘creating a discourse of economic difference as a contribution to a politics of economic innovation’ (Gibson-Graham, 2005a: 6). Their approach emphasizes diversity and combinations across the five pillars of capitalism (see Table 1) and the prospect that current heterogeneity is only the beginning of future systemic transformation. They substitute a conception of a single overarching global capitalist economy with a diverse economy (Jonas, 2016). They seek to reveal that the economy is heterogeneous and that it includes other mechanisms of exchange, organization of production, types of property and rewards for labour and finance (Healy, 2009, 2011). As a research programme, the DE approach focuses on identifying and recording the great variety of economic activities around the globe. It is oriented towards describing a post-capitalist economy in which ‘other’ projects are registered and revalued.

While Gibson and Graham took explicit distance from Marxism, they also distanced themselves from utopianism. The diverse economies approach aims at identifying the myriad of economic practices already implemented as complements or as alternatives to the capitalist economy. The idea is to show them as autonomous spaces, and not as inferior or subordinated projects that may occur in neverlands. As a result, the academic project is also a legitimizing force for innovative activists who have already conceived and implemented alternative economic practices and who see their efforts reflected in scholarly theorization. They equally encourage acting, and especially invite academics to try action research. The focus of the DE approach is on the possibilities of the struggle and not on the probability of success (Gibson-Graham, 2008: 615).

The idea of diversity suggests an innate positive connotation or a certain aura of progressiveness that needs to be examined. As argued by Samers (2005), some non-capitalist economic practices are equally or more exploitative than capitalist practices, such as modern slavery and various forms of unpaid work. According to a recent database, over 30 per cent of the world economy is produced informally, although the proportion has been shrinking substantially in the last two decades, up to the pandemic (Medina and Schneider, 2019). This figure of 30 per cent hides an enormous diversity in itself; the informal economy is an amalgam of economic relations and practices under a single name that includes informal workers paid in cash, semi-informal workers that are not completely remunerated through the formal banking channels, and others that work without any pay (Gómez et al., 2020; Williams, 2011; Williams and Windebank, 1998). In some corners of informality, agents have organized marketplaces, associations, self-help initiatives, and other ways of structuring their economic life that fit nicely in the ‘other-than-capitalist’ box of the diverse economies framework.

However, in other corners of the informal economy, there is nothing progressive about it and the notion of diversity veils myriad forms of exploitation and misery. The diverse economies framework does not acknowledge the contrasting diversity of other-than-capitalist enterprises. In keeping with the heterogeneity of the informal economy, there is a minority of well-paid digital workers that have little in common with the great number of unprotected apps-based workers (Meagher, 2019) and low-income ‘working poor’ (Fisker, 2022; Williams and Round, 2008). Similarly, the ‘community’ behind the community economy is often rife with power asymmetries and inequalities (Bayat, 1997). Cooperatives and self-managed worker businesses rarely provide a decent living to the unemployed that create them (Suryanata et al., 2021). Collective action requires trust which generally is absent in the informal economy or economies, so it remains unorganized and populated by crowds of destitute workers struggling to survive. By critiquing capitalist practices, all other practices appear deserving of promotion, whereas alterity is not necessarily superior. Samers (2005: 883) questions this myopic understanding of the informal economy and asserts that ‘we need a more analytical treatment of informal or diverse economies by distinguishing between their more mundane but dyspeptic varieties (that is, large swathes of informal employment) and those with a seemingly more “progressive” production, extraction, and redistribution of the surplus’. In other words, we need to move beyond the assumption that all that is different to capitalism is desirable.

There is a related question, namely ‘what is the theoretical advantage of making an inventory of capitalist and non-capitalist practices if this includes exploitative projects?’. A more careful distinction between desirable diversity and undesirable diversity is a pending assignment of the DE framework that has not yet been resolved and does not appear under scrutiny in the handbook either. Various scholars therefore advocate moving away from an inherently positive appreciation of ‘diversity’ as a central expression of disapproval of the status quo (Schreven et al., 2008). Others prefer the concept of ‘alterity’ as a non-binary discursive option that expresses degrees of separation and depends on specific contexts and spaces (e.g. Jonas, 2013; Lee, 2000). They define alterity as ‘a way of knowing, representing and narrating the other in terms that exist outside’ the established categories (Jonas, 2016: 9). In other words, alterity is the construction of a sense of other both analytically and empirically (Fuller et al., 2016). Still, alterity in any measure and degree suggests an immanent positive content that overrates the progressiveness of many initiatives. Other scholars developed the notion of ‘autonomous geographies’ to refer to the political networks of activists who aim at dislodging capitalism and building post-capitalist collective spaces (e.g. Pickerill and Chatterton, 2006). They thus identify political and economic autonomy as the central criterion that couples the desirable to the alternative. Such a conceptualization presents the advantage that a socially minded movement needs to be present in the production of alterity, as opposed to any form of non-capitalist diversity that may or may not be sought after by a particular social group.

A second well-researched critique of the diverse economies research programme is the issue of scale, which has been noted by several authors. Lee et al. (2010) notably questioned the effectiveness of projects that are small scale, intimate, niche, local and grassroots. The critique examines the realistic transformative potential of the entire inventory of localized case studies and research interventions that show that these are many, varied and individually relevant to its participants. The issue of scale is discussed explicitly in the Introduction to the handbook, in which it is asserted that many non-capitalist practices are ubiquitous around the world, so they do not need to be large to have transformative potential (p. 18). Among other-than-capitalist practices that occur everywhere, the editors of the handbook include a variety of economic activities that are undoubtedly global and salient, such as care labour, housework, family lending, migrant remittances, household flows of goods and services, indigenous struggles and local place-based activism. Quoting previous work with St. Martin and Roelvink (2015, cited on p. 16), Gibson-Graham and Dombroski claim that by making these niche, local initiatives visible, diverse economies scholars ‘cultivate a politics of horizontal extent, reach and association rather than a politics of scale’ (p. 20). They further argue that the scale of these actions is global; because ‘women are everywhere and therefore always somewhere, change can be enacted in all those many somewheres’ (Gibson-Graham, 2005b, cited on p. 20). Such a ubiquitous presence would facilitate the replication of change-making practices. This vision admits that replicated practices would not look the same everywhere, as if they were the result of a grand strategy of economic transformation.

While this constitutes a response to the critique on scaling, it does not convincingly cast light on the question of transformative potential. The emphasis of the DE approach is on scaling out rather than scaling up, which implies the multiplication of similar practices through relational networks and associations instead of the growth of a single project or location. If they did scale out, and diverse economies mushroomed globally as the 58 chapters in the handbook appear to suggest, would that be enough to generate a new type of economy at the aggregate level? Furthermore, scaling by replication is not as straightforward as suggested. The discourse that emphasizes multiplication and ubiquity as methods for effecting change at a global and aggregate level has been examined by scholars specialized in the different localized livelihoods (MacKinnon, 2008, 2011) that the diverse economies literature seeks to cover. For example, research on not-for-profit enterprise networks reveals that scaling out works only under specific conditions and it is not free of risks and obstacles (Bocken et al., 2016; van Lunenburg et al., 2020; Reed, 2015).

Among other limitations, the issue of knowledge is mentioned prominently, because the know-how on starting an alternative or socially oriented project does not travel freely. It requires motivated actors and privately owned resources to grow or to transfer knowledge to others in order that replication can occur. The originators of the transformative project are generally inclined to disseminate knowledge but also seek to benefit from it in financial or reputational terms. At the least, they seek to be acknowledged as the source of the social innovation, including the possibility of being paid for the conception of the idea, and at the most, they hope to obtain financial resources to progress further in their initiative. Similarly, even if knowledge becomes publicly available and free floating — to support, for example, a women's organization in Ireland to replicate the positive experience of a rotating savings and credit association in Kenya — the differences in context and subjectivities require considerable efforts in translation and adaptation, with all the costs, hurdles and risks of failure that this implies. The handbook asserts that ‘women are everywhere’ and there is considerable evidence corroborating that women tend to form organizations in a multitude of places and situations (p. 20). However, the women's associations that support female entrepreneurs in Ireland have little in common with the informal lending circles (chamas) in Kenya. While the transformative potential of scaling by multiplication could allow an other-than-capitalist project to reach ‘many somewheres’, the reasoning does not cast light on why it would happen or who would notice that it is worth the effort. Who would provide the resources, time and energy for a social innovation to travel from one context to another, safeguarding the transformative potential of the original?

Perhaps the transformative impact of scaling non-capitalist initiatives out and up lies elsewhere. Engaging with the diverse economies approach, Smith et al. (2008) suggest that the issue of scale is not always critical for transforming the system. In their study of diverse economic practices in post-socialist Eastern Europe, at the level of the household they found that workers combine formal and informal employment alongside legal and illegal work, unpaid domestic labour and reciprocal forms of exchange. In other words, each household participates in diverse economic practices to supplement its income and make a living in a capitalist economy. Smith et al. (ibid.) conclude that such a diversity of economic practices within households raises questions over the ability of capitalism to ensure social reproduction. Such questioning may lead to social and economic transformation. It is therefore not the scale of the diverse economies that matters but the questions on occupational identity, class processes and social roles that the practice of diversity can raise. In a more general sense, the need to combine various capitalist and non-capitalist economies in one household to make a living reminds its participants that the arrival and domination of capitalism in Eastern Europe and other areas of the world has brought a series of important challenges to groups of the population struggling to make a living.

Looking at this line of enquiry from a slightly different angle, another question arises. If non-capitalist activities at the level of the household aim at supporting survival and not at transforming the system, then those other-than-capitalist practices barely represent a move away from capitalism. At the level of the household, practices converge and co-exist, and there is an intimate interaction of the diverse economic practices, with the result that households may not always be able to establish which practice nourishes which. Yet, as Elson (2017) suggests, this convergence of non-capitalist practices at the level of the household has systemic implications and may have consequences for those living in the capitalist economy. Suryanata et al. (2021) conducted research among ‘new farmers’ in Hawaii, who left previous professions and entered farming to change their lifestyle and adopt the diverse socio-ecological values promoted by the DE approach. The study found that, driven by their nostalgia for a romanticized rural life, the new farmers ended up working long hours and resorting to unpaid labour to be able to make a living. Their behaviour reconfirmed that it is impossible for any farmer — old or new — to make a decent living from agriculture without working long hours and exploiting unpaid family members and themselves. The outcome was that the former-professionals-transformed-into-farmers undermined the social reproduction of those who had no other option but to live from farming. The diversification of economic practices in households that could afford it was counterproductive for the well-being of other households that could not make such choices. Hence, it is not possible to affirm that the diversification of economic practices away from capitalism necessarily represents a force that transforms the system in a positive direction; the opposite is also possible.

Moreover, alternative economic spaces are often populated by agents who lead a capitalist existence during working hours and a non-capitalist existence in their spare time, doing volunteer work, for example. With such a blend of social groups acting in various spheres of economic life, the rationalities that guide emancipatory projects are rarely isolated from the need to obtain resources to keep the various practices alive and extract surpluses to safeguard their survival and impact. It is likely that a large proportion of non-capitalist initiatives are hybrids that blend rationalities and absorb the pressure to secure resources — time and funding — from the capitalist system. The larger the scale, the greater the need to share the space and interact with other spheres and institutions. For instance, the diverse economies inventory presented in the handbook includes complementary currency systems that are convertible to formal national currencies, and therefore dependent on the capitalist economy. It also includes cases of self-managed and non-profit enterprises that require funds to pay salaries and achieve their social goals, and farmers’ markets where sales are concentrated among a handful of traders, excluding the less efficient or productive ones. While some of these cases may be successful in terms of their transformational impact and scaling, they blend elements of alterity with a mainstream existence, thus constituting changing hybrids. At what point is a partially alternative practice — a hybrid — no longer an alternative practice? This thus becomes an ontological question. It is not always possible to separate the market from the non-market, paid from unpaid labour, monetized from non-monetized and the formal from the informal (Rodgers and Williams, 2012).

Together, this set of studies and critiques leads back to the question of the relationship between capitalist and non-capitalist practices. While the DE approach emphasizes horizontal diversity or the co-existence of diverse political and economic spaces, radical political economy, such as dependency theory, concludes that one sector is dominant or superior to the other. As argued by Marx and Engels (Engels, 1968), the sector that provides resources for the survival of the second clearly has higher chances of dominating the agenda of the diverse economies. Diverse economic practices appear in a variety of relationships to the capitalist economy: transformational, complementary and subordinate. However, it appears that it cannot be defined a priori. There is therefore a third important area of critique that relates to the purpose of creating an inventory of diverse practices. Why is it relevant to the objective of transforming capitalism? In their article ‘Diverse Economies: Performative Practices for Other Worlds’, Gibson and Graham (Gibson-Graham, 2008) engage with the sceptics who asked this question and explain that changing our understanding of the world is to change the world, if only partially and locally. However, 15 years later, the question remains unanswered: in what ways does the recognition of heterogeneous practices, however richly documented, contribute to changing the capitalist system? The handbook offers rather ambiguous clues to illuminate the path or paths — from imagining post-capitalist futures to defining their desirability or seeing them progress away from an exploitative economic system. Creating a language of diversity through research interventions is no doubt a positive step, but it is hardly sufficient to produce the transformation of human existence in the material world that the programme promotes. In the meantime, right-wing governments and wars to secure natural resources keep reproducing the walls of conflict and separation.

For scholars engaged in development studies, there is a fourth line of questioning to explore. How is alterity defined in a decolonizing world? The diverse economies approach facilitates the discovery of other-than-capitalist practices, supporting the connection of other ontologies to global conversations and scholarly work. The conception of other-than-capitalist practices makes sense in places where capitalist practices are the rule and non-capitalist practices need to be uncovered in order to change what scholars are trained to see first. But non-capitalist practices may occupy a different position in relation to pre-colonial, post-colonial and de-colonial economies. In vast areas of the global South, capitalist practices are the last addition in a long path of economic transformation, and not the other way around. As discussed in some of the chapters in the handbook, the diverse economies in developing countries encompass livelihood activities that have been in existence for centuries. It would therefore be hard to assert the extent to which they can be considered ‘alternative’, except in relation to a Western view of the world that sees capitalism as the rule in economic life. It could be argued that in the global South alterity is the norm. Economies in the global South are well populated by informal, indigenous, vernacular and other-than-capitalist practices.

This is the exact opposite to the message the diverse economies approach aims to communicate. In Chapter 55 of the handbook, entitled ‘Working with Indigenous Methodologies’, Waitoa and Dombroski explain that the inclusion of a Maori methodology in the handbook constitutes ‘a first step towards identifying instructive points of connection and dissonance with diverse economies methods and approaches’ (p. 502). This is a clear acknowledgement by the diverse economies approach of the specificities of economic life in the developing world. It also implies that the DE approach conceives of indigenous, vernacular and localized economic practices — ubiquitous in the global South — as alternatives to capitalism and the institutions dominant in the global North. Labelling these practices as ‘diverse’ or ‘alternative’ in a world that is dominated by other-than-capitalist practices is not only inaccurate but may also come across as condescending. The DE approach aims to facilitate South–North transfer by emphasizing difference and potential, but its representatives are sometimes insensitive to the fact that certain non-capitalist practices are the norm in other parts of the world and that their value does not lie in appearing unique or exotic from a Northern perspective. That still leaves aside the issue of whether pre-colonial non-capitalist practices are less exploitative and exclusionary than capitalist ones. Or whether pre-colonial empires and their economic practices were any less discriminatory towards the ‘other’ peoples they conquered and enslaved.

Spanning over 550 pages and 58 chapters across seven sections, the book presents a daunting amount of material. It includes contributions of 69 authors from various backgrounds, career stages and corners of the world. This richness makes the handbook an invaluable starting point for those interested in identifying and seeing the variety of economic practices around the world. By adding studies on new topics and finding analytical connections among them, the handbook improves the coherence of the approach. It presents an up to date collection of cases with cross-cutting issues salient in 2020. Several of the practices studied are rooted in collective action and hope, and the politics of hope (Denzin, 2000) is discussed in detail in this handbook. The DE programme emphasizes hope by showing how personal and interpersonal efforts may play a role in demonstrating the possibility of alternative futures (Zademach and Hillebrand, 2013).

The first five sections of the handbook are organized around the categories of enterprises, labour, transactions, property and finance. Each section starts with a framing essay that aims to contextualize the topic and make explicit the connections between the chapters comprising that section. For example, the framing essay of section one on enterprise diversity is authored by Jenny Cameron (pp. 26–39) and focuses on class. From the perspective of the diverse economies framework, class is conceived as a process of producing, appropriating and distributing surplus labour in various types of enterprises. The framing essay is followed by nine studies on the various class processes in these spaces, including worker cooperatives, worker-owned factories, anti-crime initiatives and other kinds of community enterprises and eco-social and ethical businesses. The second section looks at labour and in addition to the framing essay, it consists of eight chapters on precarious labour, informal and unpaid labour, care work, collectively performed reciprocal labour, informal mining and the non-human labour of ‘earth others’. The third section on transactions presents a framing essay, followed by eight chapters on gleaning, community supported agriculture, collective food procurement, alternative currencies, time banking, fair trade networks, social procurement and shared urban spaces. After a framing essay, the fourth section examines property in six chapters focusing on commoning, land trusts, urban land markets and free universities. The fifth section deals with finance and includes a framing article followed by five chapters on Islamic finance, rotating savings and credit associations, indigenous finance, community investment funds and hacking finance. In short, the book chapters cover a broad range of different topics and cases, with ethics and hope as the common principle that drives these diverse and alternative economic practices.

The diverse economies framework focuses on practices to convey its distance from economic determinism (the ontological restriction to certain economic processes) and empirical realism (the epistemological acceptance of a separation between reality and reflection). In line with these assumptions, the last two sections of the handbook explore subjectivity and methodology. These two areas of enquiry are probably the main original contributions of this volume. The framing essay of the sixth section on subjectivity, by Healy et al., aims to clarify the meaning of the term ‘subject’ in a diverse non-capitalist economy and ‘demotes the primacy of the human subject’ (p. 389). It proposes a reading of the economic subject that explicitly recognizes an anti-essentialist framing, one that emphasizes the open-ended way in which human communities face dilemmas about consumption and necessity or investment and surplus. The authors further explain that this describes the decentred economic subject in the ‘undecidable space of a dilemma’ (p. 385) in which human communities negotiate indefinitely the conditions of ‘antagonistic interdependence’ (ibid.). It is followed by six chapters on diverse subjectivities, power, genealogy, sexuality, affections and economic subjectivity.

The last section on methodology refrains from promoting a particular methodology, in keeping with the fact that this is a research programme that takes pride in its diversity of topics and approaches. Instead, it favours the imagining of post-capitalist futures and the research interventions that can realize them. As Gibson-Graham argue in Chapter 52, the research methodologies of the diverse economies framework are varied but consistently focus on ‘reading for economic difference’ (p. 476). The seventh section therefore includes eight chapters on indigenous methodologies, assemblage analysis, action research, the tracing of relations and the use of artistic resources as method of enquiry.

In general, the handbook advances the consistency and completeness of the research programme, not as an alternative economics textbook but as a different approach to understanding what the economy is, in its geographical and everyday diversity. It introduces itself as a set of weak theoretical tools to support the study of capitalist, non-capitalist and community/alternative capitalist practices. While seeing disruptive practices constitutes a first step, the handbook repeatedly reminds the reader that the goal of the research programme is to recover and revalorize the possibilities of a non-capitalist future, or, at least, to demonstrate that capitalist practices are only one of various modalities of economic interaction to secure the material survival and reproduction of communities. Showing and seeing the heterogeneity of economic practices would promote conceptions of and projects advancing a non-capitalist future. Gibson-Graham (2008) claimed that ‘changing our understanding of the world is to change the world’, which is a clear indication of their commitment to performative research. Building on this premise, the DE research programme had been prolific and had contributed a large number of books, academic articles and activists’ reports. It was time to condense its contributions in a massive, comprehensive handbook.

While the volume is an excellent effort to mitigate the dispersion of topics, cases and differentiated framings within the diverse economies approach, it does not go far enough in engaging with some of the points of critique raised above. The handbook aims to provide the means to create a systematic inventory of diverse, human-scale, community-led economic practices without necessarily assessing how desirable these are. Since its inception in 1996, this post-capitalist research project has generated crowds of adepts and sceptics. The group of supporters appreciates its potential to examine economic diversity and recognize the alterity of economic practices rooted in the politics of hope. The group of sceptics keeps on asking the same questions, which continue to go unanswered. The danger of such silence is that a new sect of scholar-activists may arise, repeating the same narrative in the hope that it will become true. A key proposition of the handbook is that we are occupying a post-capitalist future without fully explaining how we are to know that we have arrived there or specifying which part of the future they are describing. The debate is certainly open as to whether we are experiencing a post-neoliberal phase or another cycle of conservative neoliberalism (Fine and Saad-Filho, 2014; Gaudichaud et al., 2022; Strange, 2016).

When Gibson and Graham published The End of Capitalism (As We Knew it) in 1996, they produced what many economic geographers considered to be one of the ‘most innovative and startling re-interpretations of the economy in the last decades’ (Zademach and Hillebrand, 2013: 16). Their contributions accumulated and were further developed by other scholars around the world, evolving into the diverse economies research programme. The programme offers a post-structuralist reading of political, economic and social interaction to disclose the multiple economic practices that are already in existence within the economic landscape. It has supported the elaboration of a new economic dictionary, with more inclusive language. Moreover, it has recaptured the element of hope in existing initiatives that increase well-being in everyday economic life. At the same time, it has been unable to develop clear criteria on the desirability or progressiveness of those other-than-capitalist economic practices, how they could accumulate sufficient transformative potential, or what effects they could have at the various levels of economic life (households, regions, national and global systems). In relation to development studies, the programme may offer an interesting avenue for South–North knowledge transfer, but that would require another round of remaking the language of economic diversity to account for what is standard and what is alternative. The proportion of the economy that can be described as capitalist — represented by formal labour, pure private property, markets with transparent prices and mainstream finance — may be too small in many countries in the global South for other practices to be considered as ‘alternative’. Just taking account of the informal monetized economic activities measured by Medina and Schneider (2019: 11), alternatives to formal capitalist practices made up 63 per cent of GDP in Bolivia and 57 per cent of GDP in Nigeria. Labelling these as ‘alternative’ therefore does not do justice to their pervasiveness. To consider the alterity of these practices as a matter of degree, as suggested by Jonas (2016), may therefore be a more valid analytical instrument.

There is also the question of the relationship between capitalist and non-capitalist practices, which situates the diverse economies approach between radical political economy perspectives and the utopians. While the Marxist literature has been dismissive of the latter, the literature on communitarian and human-centred practices has been a source of undeniable hope in the possibility of a post-capitalist future on a healthy planet. Yet the position of these non-capitalist economies in relation to the capitalist economy needs considerably more elaboration within the DE research programme. Are they subordinate, parallel, complementary, or transformative projects in relation the capitalist economy based on waged labour and private property? The answer would not be the same for the unpaid domestic economy, the informal inferior circuits of value, or the value-oriented grassroots niches pursuing ecologically informed economic projects.

While acknowledging the difficulties of identifying alterity, the actors and their historical and geographical situations, Fickey and Hanrahan (2015: 400) recommend that scholars studying alterity engage more with one another. Indeed, there is a need to compare notes and increase the empirical basis of the research project in a systematic way. The Handbook of Diverse Economies takes a small step in that direction by bringing together a massive network of authors, case studies and methodologies in one volume. What could come next is clearer proof of the research programme's capacity to engage critically with itself.

求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
Development and Change
Development and Change DEVELOPMENT STUDIES-
CiteScore
6.80
自引率
3.30%
发文量
46
期刊介绍: Development and Change is essential reading for anyone interested in development studies and social change. It publishes articles from a wide range of authors, both well-established specialists and young scholars, and is an important resource for: - social science faculties and research institutions - international development agencies and NGOs - graduate teachers and researchers - all those with a serious interest in the dynamics of development, from reflective activists to analytical practitioners
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信