{"title":"ESG活动家的教训:塞恩斯伯里的案例和生活工资","authors":"Tom Gosling","doi":"10.1111/jacf.12550","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>Sainsbury's, one of the UK's large supermarket chains, found itself in the crosshairs of ESG activism in 2022. That was when ShareAction, a well-known responsible investment NGO, filed the first Living Wage resolution in the UK.1</p><p>Among the 10 co-filers were blue-chip names in the UK investment world, including Legal and General, HSBC Asset Management, Fidelity International, Nest, and the Brunel Pension Partnership.</p><p>This Living Wage resolution was rejected by roughly five out of every six of the Sainsbury's investors that voted on the resolution at the company's Annual General Meeting on July 7, 2022. To understand how and why this measure failed to gain acceptance, it's useful to start by noting the difference between The Living Wage and the National Living Wage, which is briefly described in the box below.</p><p>ShareAction clearly saw its Living Wage resolution at Sainsbury's as the opening salvo in a battle it intended to conduct with the entire UK supermarket sector. It was also one of the NGO's first efforts to draw attention to the importance of the “S” in ESG. The proposal described the resolution as a “litmus test for investors’ social commitments amid the cost-of-living crisis.”</p><p>In an unusual move, Schroders, the well-known UK asset manager with one of the five largest investment positions in Sainsbury's, published <i>ahead of the vote</i> its rationale for its decision <i>not</i> to support the resolution. Kimberley Lewis, Head of Schroders’ Active Ownership group, wrote an article titled, “Why Sainsbury's AGM is a Pivotal Moment for ESG.”4 After pointing out that Sainsbury's is widely recognized as a well-run company that considers all important stakeholders in key decisions and has invested heavily in its employees, the article then expressed the concern that imposing this further restriction on Sainsbury's at a time when no other UK supermarket was a Living Wage Employer could undermine the company's competitive position, which would end up doing economic harm to many of its employees and customers as well as its investors.</p><p>Lewis closed her article with a warning against the unforeseen risks of applying ESG factors “in a blanket way and without due consideration,” describing it as “‘unthinking ESG’ … which harms the credibility of sustainable investing.” Along with this warning, she also expressed her view of the outcome of the impending resolution as “a test of whether important nuances in these debates can be heard”.</p><p>There is much that could be said about this resolution. We might start by asking how ShareAction could claim that the resolution—which requires the company to adopt a floor on employee pay set by a third party—would leave board discretion wholly unaffected and intact, because the Living Wage Foundation “would merely set the minimum level”. But while we are raising such questions about the NGO, we could also ask why Schroders, itself a Living Wage Employer, thinks that what is sauce for the goose should not be sauce for the gander too. Failure to explain its voting decision in the context of an Engagement Blueprint that encourages Living Wage adoption seems, if not an oversight, then at least a missed opportunity to provide clarity about its own convictions.</p><p>But my purpose here is more analytical than polemical, namely, to examine the claims on both sides of this debate when viewed through the lens of investor and board duties. To help with this analysis, I will start by providing a brief overview of the ESG decision-making principles that London Business School developed with The Investor Forum during 2021 in a project we called “What does stakeholder capitalism mean for investors?”5 Then I will go on to argue that, however, much the framework supports Schroders’ position, the underlying principles are not a free pass for companies and investors to ignore any ESG issue they find troublesome.</p><p>To illustrate this point, I'll also use the framework to evaluate another resolution, this one put forward in 2020 by a P&G shareholder on deforestation. In this case application of the principles leads to broad support for this resolution that, unlike the ShareAction resolution, not only passed but received the support of fully two thirds of its investors.</p><p>The impetus for the collaboration between The Investor Forum and London Business School was investors’ confusion and uncertainty about how to evaluate and respond to the multiple competing demands to act on ESG issues while lacking a clear framework for deciding which actions to pursue or support. The framework begins by recognizing asset managers’ fiduciary duty to act in the interests of their clients. Despite common rhetoric to the contrary, not all ESG initiatives work to increase shareholder value, even over the long term. Some simply cost money.</p><p>None of this should be construed as denying that asset owners and end beneficiaries have non-financial objectives and concerns that may well sometimes lead them to view such costs as worth bearing. But in such cases, asset managers’ fiduciary duty to act in the interests of their clients imposes on them a second obligation: when intending to pursue ESG initiatives and investments that are <i>expected</i> to sacrifice long-run value (presumably without undermining the company's competitive position), corporate boards must first seek and gain the clearest possible mandate from their investors to make such (again, presumably modest) sacrifices. Launching major ESG initiatives involving large capital commitments that are <i>expected</i> to reduce shareholder returns <i>without such a mandate</i> is courting investor disapproval and, eventually, removal.</p><p>Let's now try to apply these tests to the Sainsbury's case.</p><p>Our first principle—that shareholders should act on a stakeholder issue only when the stakeholder (or issue) is material to the company concerned—is a simple matter of prioritization. Sainsbury's employees are clearly an important contributor to, and have a material stake in, the company's long-run success.</p><p>But is the adoption of a Living Wage itself a material stakeholder issue, especially when Sainsbury's reports that the vast majority of its direct and indirect employees are already paid the Living Wage?</p><p>There are many lenses for assessing materiality. There is the traditional lens of <i>financial</i> materiality: stakeholder issues that clearly affect the profitability of the company. But in response to the criticism of this concept as too narrow, there is growing focus on <i>impact</i> materiality—cases in which corporate decisions impose hardship or “costs” on stakeholders, whether or not there is a discernible effect on corporate profits or value. And there is another version called <i>dynamic</i> materiality—involving those issues that, if unaddressed, could become financially material. For example, consumers’ concerns about corporate treatment of workers in supply chains could end up influencing consumer purchasing habits. Into this mix we also introduced the idea of <i>intrinsic</i> materiality, which applies to stakeholder issues relating to traditional social or moral expectations. Finally, stakeholder issues can be company specific or <i>systemic</i>, in the sense of affecting the economy as a whole rather than individual companies.</p><p>Let's start with financial materiality—does the issue of Sainsbury's Living Wage affect the long-run profitability and value of the company? ShareAction claimed that it does. In support of its proposal, Rachel Hargreaves, ShareAction's Campaigns Manager, stated that “research has consistently demonstrated a positive business case for Living Wage rates, even in low-margin sectors such as retail.” And consistent with Hargreaves’ argument, there is in fact a theory of “efficiency wages” that hypothesizes that companies choosing to pay above-market wages may get a payback in the form of higher-quality and more productive employees. Such a policy is widely viewed as a major contributor to the widely heralded success of the U.S. company CostCo.</p><p>But evidence about the more general case is mixed, and invariably contested. The possibility that higher wages <i>can</i> be repaid through higher productivity does not mean they are generally <i>expected</i> to be. And, of course, in all cases there is some level of wages at which the relationship will turn down and become sharply negative.</p><p>One of the most important tasks and responsibilities of Sainsbury's board and executive team is to determine to what extent, if at all, they want to deviate from market norms in how the company rewards their employees. The board and management are highly experienced, and by all accounts well-attuned to employee attitudes and have clear incentives to improve the company's long-term performance. Is it plausible that Sainsbury's shareholders know more than its management about the wage rates likely to maximize returns?</p><p>Moreover, it is not just Sainsbury's board that takes this view. No other UK supermarket is a Living Wage Employer, and this group includes both public and private companies, and those owned by families as well as by private equity firms. How likely is it that <i>all</i> of these companies and management teams are missing an easy win-win from increasing wages to increase long-run profits and value? The onus falls on those making this case to prove it. The shareholders supporting the resolutions have notably failed to provide convincing evidence.9</p><p>This seems to be a case of ESG irrational exuberance and overreach: the desire to claim that any and all ESG activity should be expected to improve long-run performance. But if Sainsbury's management and every other management team in the UK supermarket sector is missing this obvious way to increase long-term value, then rather than filing a Living Wage resolution, investors should simply be firing the boards and installing new managements.</p><p>But financial materiality, as we have already seen, is not the only form of materiality. What about impact materiality and systemic risk? Here the materiality is determined by the extent of the company's impact on stakeholders rather than stakeholders’ impact on long-run corporate profitability and value. There is little doubt that Sainsbury's could dramatically improve the standard of living of a great many of its employees by, say, increasing their wages by a fifth. But in the grand scheme of things, even the number of such employees is relatively small in number. And ShareAction, it's important to recognize, is going after a much bigger target—economy-wide inequality. As their Sainsbury's proposal states, “low pay drives inequality which slows economic growth and stokes instability, presenting material risks to investors.”</p><p>And there is in fact some evidence for the negative impact of inequality on growth. But that evidence is far more compelling in the case of developing, low-income than developed, high-income nations—and, here again, the evidence is mixed and disputed.10 Such is also true of the evidence for inequality being a major contributor to “systemic risk.” And as we shall see, the ability of shareholder action to affect such systemic risks is quite limited.</p><p>But if this appears to be the strongest form of materiality at work in the case of Sainsbury's, there are some major challenges for asset managers when attempting to take actions that purport to represent the moral views of their investor clients. I will later return to these challenges when taking up the question of companies’ need to seek, or at least clarify, client mandates for their ESG initiatives.</p><p>Our second principle, efficacy, states that investors should act only when confident about their ability to bring about the desired change in the real world, and in such a way that the stakeholder benefits exceed the associated costs.</p><p>If the desired benefit is to increase the wages of affected Sainsbury's employees and contractors, then clearly the shareholder resolution would directly achieve this. But what about the wider impact on the systemic issue of inequality, which also seems clearly to motivate the proposal?</p><p>Here the overall consequences are much less certain. If the resolution is successful, that could lead to an industry-wide change in practices. But in what is at least an equally plausible outcome, it could simply make Sainsbury's uncompetitive, leading to loss of market share to companies not adopting the Living Wage policy. Also worth noting is the possibility that, even if investors were successful at passing resolutions at all the <i>listed</i> supermarkets, the steadily growing proportion of the UK market subject to <i>private</i> control, including Aldi, Asda, Lidl, and Morrisons, would use their lower wages to accelerate their growth in market share.</p><p>So, even though Sainsbury, Tesco, and Marks & Spencer could become the firms that determine wages in the economy, the alternative outcome is that they become less competitive and lose market share to private firms. We don't really know how such changes will play out. Therefore, while the Living Wage has symbolic appeal, it's efficacy is surrounded by doubt.</p><p>Furthermore, does the stakeholder benefit outweigh the cost of the action? Again, this is very unclear. The additional costs of fulfilling the Living Wage commitment are very likely to be reflected in some combination of reduced returns to shareholders, reduced employment, and increased prices. Indeed, the study by researchers from Queen Mary University11 cited by ShareAction in support of their case mentions that adopters of the London Living Wage have tended to offset the higher wage costs through a variety of actions, including changes to contracting terms, reduction in headcount or hours, and changes in service specifications and supplies—and, in some cases, acceptance of reduced margin. And since there is no evidence suggesting that overall net stakeholder value will increase, the probable effect of a mandated Living Wage is a “wealth transfer” from one set of stakeholders to another. And most important to keep in mind, it's not just shareholders who would bear the costs, but also the customers who pay the higher prices, and the current or future workers who suffer from the potential reduction in employment at the company.</p><p>Overall, then, the proposal fails the test of efficacy.</p><p>The last of the tests in our report is comparative advantage. Here the shareholder should consider whether they (or the company whose shares they hold) is particularly well-positioned to address, or at least influence, the stakeholder issue. Even once they are satisfied that achieving the ESG outcome is in line with their clients’ interests, asset managers should be using client money to this end only when their actions have at least a reasonable prospect of influencing the desired outcomes.</p><p>So, if the stakeholder issue is viewed narrowly as the pay of the particular affected employees and contractors at Sainsbury's, then, yes, the company has comparative advantage. However, the ShareAction campaign has clearly cast a broader net, purporting as it does to address overall economic inequality.</p><p>Here it is not at all clear that investors or Sainsbury's have comparative advantage. System-wide issues such as the appropriate minimum wage levels run into many level-playing-field problems relating to competitiveness. In such cases, governments are generally best suited to address the issue of inequality directly through minimum wages, progressive taxation, and benefits—and, in the longer term, through policies on education, health, and housing.</p><p>We often hear the argument that governments are failing to act on ESG issues. But the area of minimum wage rates in the UK seems to be one area where this criticism is unfounded. The UK Government has established a rather well structured and mature process that is overseen by the Low Pay Commission2, a process that has support from across the political spectrum, and which takes into account a wide range of stakeholder and economic considerations. Indeed, the current Government has mandated the Low Pay Commission to increase the statutory National Living Wage towards two-thirds of median earnings as quickly as possible consistent with its mandate to consider employment levels and the health of the economy more broadly. So, of all the ESG issues that could be singled out, this is one where the institutions of Government appear to be among the most effective.</p><p>And that, in brief, is why the ShareAction proposal violates the principle of comparative advantage.</p><p>Our analysis up to this point shows that the rationale for shareholders supporting the Living Wage resolution at Sainsbury's rests on a shaky foundation. It is largely inconsistent with our three key principles of materiality, efficacy, and comparative advantage.</p><p>Nevertheless, when dealing with the question of materiality, I did allow for the possibility that investors’ collective sense of morality, of the need to distinguish right from clear wrong, could lead them to support the proposal, thereby outweighing the other considerations. In other words, investors should not support companies that become “bad actors.”</p><p>The problem with this argument, however, is that should such cases arise, asset managers would need to have crystal-clear mandates from their investor clients identifying and articulating such moral objections as their main reason to act. Without such mandates, asset managers would be using “other people's money” to pursue actions with no economic benefits in view and for which neither asset managers nor their investor clients are well-positioned to expect a successful outcome.</p><p>So, this begs the question: Why not just assume that most people would consider payment of the Living Wage a moral imperative? The answer to this question is, it's not at all clear how we establish this. As just noted, we have a political system that has resulted in a quite consistent and well-developed approach to setting a National Living Wage—one that, it's important to note, has not been subjected to the intense cross-party disagreement that has for long been the dominant note in UK politics. Indeed, the UK approach to minimum-wage setting has elicited a striking degree of bi-partisan unity that has persisted for over a decade among Labor, Coalition, and Conservative Governments. Thus, it surely seems reasonable to suppose that many if not most UK citizens view the <i>National</i> Living Wage as an adequate response to the problem of in-work pay rates.</p><p>Given the difficulty of assuming that clients’ views will differ from the prevailing political consensus, my recommendation was that investors voting in favor of the ShareAction proposal have a very clear and explicit mandate from their investor clients directing the asset managers to back the proposal with their (investors’) capital. The same asset managers should also clearly inform their investor clients of the potential for negative effects on shareholder returns, failure of the actions to lead to the desired social outcomes, and potential unintended. Including the possibility noted above of regressive distributional effects. Given all these possible outcomes, and the dearth of evidence about how things will play out, it would be foolhardy for investors to rely on the kind of “win-win” argument presented by ShareAction.</p><p>When I published these arguments in June of 2022, it clearly struck a chord. A number of investors contacted me to thank me for the reasoned analysis. Further suggesting the article was getting some traction, ShareAction published a rebuttal, to which I then felt obliged to respond.12</p><p>At the AGM that was held on Thursday July 7, 2022 to decide the proposal, 83.3% of investors voted against it, with only one in six supporting it. The vote thus failed not only to pass, but to meet the 20% level that the UK Corporate Governance Code and the Investment Association views as conveying a “significant” level of investor opposition to management. Notwithstanding this level of investor opposition to the proposal, ShareAction saw fit to evict Schroders from the Good Work Coalition they had established as an investor collaboration to engage with companies to encourage them to adopt better working practices.13</p><p>There are a number of important lessons for ESG activism that can be drawn from this case. After the AGM took place, I identified four.14</p><p>But having raised these concerns about the ShareAction proposal, I find it important to say that the principles we developed with The Investor Forum do not provide a free pass for investors to ignore ESG issues. To illustrate this, let's briefly consider a different shareholder proposal.</p><p>A number of large public companies have recently faced shareholder proposals relating to deforestation.17 In October 2020, the following resolution was filed at the P&G meeting:18</p><p><i>Shareholders request P&G issue a report assessing if and how it could increase the scale, pace, and rigor of its efforts to eliminate deforestation and the degradation of intact forests in its supply chains</i>.</p><p>The rationale provided by the filer, Green Century Capital Management, was couched in terms of shareholder value considerations: the risk of supply chain disruption due to environmental degradation; competitive effects from falling behind peers on deforestation policies; and reputational and related financial risk. This presumably was intended to secure the support of major index funds.</p><p>But as I'll now demonstrate, the case could be made much stronger. What if the resolution had called for P&G to <i>take action</i> to reduce deforestation in its supply chains? How would this have squared with our principles?</p><p>Let us now briefly run through the application of the principles. And let's start with <i>materiality</i>. Green Century Capital Management made a case for financial materiality of the issue. There is a case for this. However, even if one remains unpersuaded by it, P&G by virtue of its supply chain clearly has a potentially material impact on the issue of deforestation. Given widespread concern about the environment, it is also reasonable to believe that the issue has intrinsic materiality in the eyes of a great many end clients of the asset manager.</p><p>What about <i>efficacy</i>? Large companies have significant ability to influence supplier practices through their supply chain. Moreover, there is very limited ability to reverse deforestation once it has occurred. It is significantly cheaper to avoid deforestation in the first place than to remedy the effects once it has happened. Finally, innovation in new practices that enable production of goods without deforestation can have positive spill-over effects across an industry. Admittedly the competitive concerns outlined above still apply. But in this case, there seems to be a high probability that the net stakeholder benefits outweigh the costs by a very large margin, principally because of the gulf between cost of avoiding damage versus cost of remediation.</p><p>Third and last, what about the question of <i>comparative advantage</i><b>?</b> Deforestation is an area where effective government regulation is difficult to define and put in place, and enforcement is extremely difficult. It requires collaboration between national governments and enforcement by countries where authorities and institutions may be relatively weak. Therefore companies, and by extension investors, seem particularly well placed to act in this area.</p><p>And so, in the case of action on deforestation, the principles of materiality, efficacy at reasonable cost, and comparative advantage are all likely to be met in many cases. Investors still need to be sure that they have a mandate from their clients given that some costs may arise. But the costs are likely to be manageable relative to the benefits, and asset managers may even be able to rely on general pro-social sentiments of end investors as a mandate for action.</p><p>Consistent with this reasoning, the Proctor & Gamble resolution was supported by 67% of shareholders.</p><p>The recognition that shareholders have non-financial as well as financial preferences is welcome, as is the increased willingness of shareholders and their representatives to use their rights to seek to influence companies on ESG issues. ShareAction and Schroders have done us a service by enabling us to have this important debate on an “S” issue within the ESG universe.</p><p>But this needs to be done thoughtfully, with particular attention paid to the likely effectiveness of the action and its potential costs, considered in the context of asset managers’ fiduciary duty to, and mandates from, clients. A rather lazy narrative has grown up around the concept of “doing well by doing good” that is predisposed to view all ESG activities as beneficial for long-term value. But clearly, they are not. ESG interventions often involve trade-offs between shareholder value (even over the long-term) and stakeholder value. Moreover, they often result in trade-offs between different categories of non-shareholder stakeholders.</p><p>Asset managers need to undertake a rigorous analysis to figure out which ESG issues to act on and which to leave alone. The framework of principles we developed with The Investor Forum helps to do just this.</p><p>Thoughtful consideration of the principles suggests that Schroders was right to vote against the Living Wage resolution at Sainsbury's. Costs to shareholders appear almost certain while the net stakeholder value remains highly uncertain and, indeed, quite plausibly zero. There are unpredictable distributional effects since, as we have noted, many low-income stakeholders may be more harmed than helped by the proposal. Shareholders are not nearly as well-positioned to address the issue of minimum in-work wages as the UK Government. And as we have seen, the UK has developed a widely accepted and generally quite effective independent process backed by a political mandate to set minimum wage levels.</p><p>None of this, to be sure, should be taken to mean that Sainsbury's should absolve itself from responsibility for thoughtfully considering the level of fair pay for workers and contractors. The Living Wage provides a useful and relevant framework for this purpose. Investors should continue to engage with Sainsbury's to understand how they are ensuring the well-being of their employees and monitoring conditions in supply chains. But the case is not made for investors to force upon the board a particular course of action on pay.</p><p>Finally, I am by no means suggesting that shareholders and companies be given a free pass on ESG. I've used the example of deforestation to show how the principles can lead to the conclusion that investors should support an ESG-related resolution. But shareholders don't have unlimited capacity to engage companies on ESG issues; they must focus their energies and efforts where they can achieve the most effective outcomes and where there is most bang for their buck. Living Wage accreditation in the UK doesn't meet this test. And so the overwhelming majority of shareholders were right to follow Schroders in voting against the resolution at Sainsbury's AGM in July 2022.</p>","PeriodicalId":0,"journal":{"name":"","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/jacf.12550","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Lessons for ESG activists: The case of Sainsbury's and the living wage\",\"authors\":\"Tom Gosling\",\"doi\":\"10.1111/jacf.12550\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p>Sainsbury's, one of the UK's large supermarket chains, found itself in the crosshairs of ESG activism in 2022. That was when ShareAction, a well-known responsible investment NGO, filed the first Living Wage resolution in the UK.1</p><p>Among the 10 co-filers were blue-chip names in the UK investment world, including Legal and General, HSBC Asset Management, Fidelity International, Nest, and the Brunel Pension Partnership.</p><p>This Living Wage resolution was rejected by roughly five out of every six of the Sainsbury's investors that voted on the resolution at the company's Annual General Meeting on July 7, 2022. To understand how and why this measure failed to gain acceptance, it's useful to start by noting the difference between The Living Wage and the National Living Wage, which is briefly described in the box below.</p><p>ShareAction clearly saw its Living Wage resolution at Sainsbury's as the opening salvo in a battle it intended to conduct with the entire UK supermarket sector. It was also one of the NGO's first efforts to draw attention to the importance of the “S” in ESG. The proposal described the resolution as a “litmus test for investors’ social commitments amid the cost-of-living crisis.”</p><p>In an unusual move, Schroders, the well-known UK asset manager with one of the five largest investment positions in Sainsbury's, published <i>ahead of the vote</i> its rationale for its decision <i>not</i> to support the resolution. Kimberley Lewis, Head of Schroders’ Active Ownership group, wrote an article titled, “Why Sainsbury's AGM is a Pivotal Moment for ESG.”4 After pointing out that Sainsbury's is widely recognized as a well-run company that considers all important stakeholders in key decisions and has invested heavily in its employees, the article then expressed the concern that imposing this further restriction on Sainsbury's at a time when no other UK supermarket was a Living Wage Employer could undermine the company's competitive position, which would end up doing economic harm to many of its employees and customers as well as its investors.</p><p>Lewis closed her article with a warning against the unforeseen risks of applying ESG factors “in a blanket way and without due consideration,” describing it as “‘unthinking ESG’ … which harms the credibility of sustainable investing.” Along with this warning, she also expressed her view of the outcome of the impending resolution as “a test of whether important nuances in these debates can be heard”.</p><p>There is much that could be said about this resolution. We might start by asking how ShareAction could claim that the resolution—which requires the company to adopt a floor on employee pay set by a third party—would leave board discretion wholly unaffected and intact, because the Living Wage Foundation “would merely set the minimum level”. But while we are raising such questions about the NGO, we could also ask why Schroders, itself a Living Wage Employer, thinks that what is sauce for the goose should not be sauce for the gander too. Failure to explain its voting decision in the context of an Engagement Blueprint that encourages Living Wage adoption seems, if not an oversight, then at least a missed opportunity to provide clarity about its own convictions.</p><p>But my purpose here is more analytical than polemical, namely, to examine the claims on both sides of this debate when viewed through the lens of investor and board duties. To help with this analysis, I will start by providing a brief overview of the ESG decision-making principles that London Business School developed with The Investor Forum during 2021 in a project we called “What does stakeholder capitalism mean for investors?”5 Then I will go on to argue that, however, much the framework supports Schroders’ position, the underlying principles are not a free pass for companies and investors to ignore any ESG issue they find troublesome.</p><p>To illustrate this point, I'll also use the framework to evaluate another resolution, this one put forward in 2020 by a P&G shareholder on deforestation. In this case application of the principles leads to broad support for this resolution that, unlike the ShareAction resolution, not only passed but received the support of fully two thirds of its investors.</p><p>The impetus for the collaboration between The Investor Forum and London Business School was investors’ confusion and uncertainty about how to evaluate and respond to the multiple competing demands to act on ESG issues while lacking a clear framework for deciding which actions to pursue or support. The framework begins by recognizing asset managers’ fiduciary duty to act in the interests of their clients. Despite common rhetoric to the contrary, not all ESG initiatives work to increase shareholder value, even over the long term. Some simply cost money.</p><p>None of this should be construed as denying that asset owners and end beneficiaries have non-financial objectives and concerns that may well sometimes lead them to view such costs as worth bearing. But in such cases, asset managers’ fiduciary duty to act in the interests of their clients imposes on them a second obligation: when intending to pursue ESG initiatives and investments that are <i>expected</i> to sacrifice long-run value (presumably without undermining the company's competitive position), corporate boards must first seek and gain the clearest possible mandate from their investors to make such (again, presumably modest) sacrifices. Launching major ESG initiatives involving large capital commitments that are <i>expected</i> to reduce shareholder returns <i>without such a mandate</i> is courting investor disapproval and, eventually, removal.</p><p>Let's now try to apply these tests to the Sainsbury's case.</p><p>Our first principle—that shareholders should act on a stakeholder issue only when the stakeholder (or issue) is material to the company concerned—is a simple matter of prioritization. Sainsbury's employees are clearly an important contributor to, and have a material stake in, the company's long-run success.</p><p>But is the adoption of a Living Wage itself a material stakeholder issue, especially when Sainsbury's reports that the vast majority of its direct and indirect employees are already paid the Living Wage?</p><p>There are many lenses for assessing materiality. There is the traditional lens of <i>financial</i> materiality: stakeholder issues that clearly affect the profitability of the company. But in response to the criticism of this concept as too narrow, there is growing focus on <i>impact</i> materiality—cases in which corporate decisions impose hardship or “costs” on stakeholders, whether or not there is a discernible effect on corporate profits or value. And there is another version called <i>dynamic</i> materiality—involving those issues that, if unaddressed, could become financially material. For example, consumers’ concerns about corporate treatment of workers in supply chains could end up influencing consumer purchasing habits. Into this mix we also introduced the idea of <i>intrinsic</i> materiality, which applies to stakeholder issues relating to traditional social or moral expectations. Finally, stakeholder issues can be company specific or <i>systemic</i>, in the sense of affecting the economy as a whole rather than individual companies.</p><p>Let's start with financial materiality—does the issue of Sainsbury's Living Wage affect the long-run profitability and value of the company? ShareAction claimed that it does. In support of its proposal, Rachel Hargreaves, ShareAction's Campaigns Manager, stated that “research has consistently demonstrated a positive business case for Living Wage rates, even in low-margin sectors such as retail.” And consistent with Hargreaves’ argument, there is in fact a theory of “efficiency wages” that hypothesizes that companies choosing to pay above-market wages may get a payback in the form of higher-quality and more productive employees. Such a policy is widely viewed as a major contributor to the widely heralded success of the U.S. company CostCo.</p><p>But evidence about the more general case is mixed, and invariably contested. The possibility that higher wages <i>can</i> be repaid through higher productivity does not mean they are generally <i>expected</i> to be. And, of course, in all cases there is some level of wages at which the relationship will turn down and become sharply negative.</p><p>One of the most important tasks and responsibilities of Sainsbury's board and executive team is to determine to what extent, if at all, they want to deviate from market norms in how the company rewards their employees. The board and management are highly experienced, and by all accounts well-attuned to employee attitudes and have clear incentives to improve the company's long-term performance. Is it plausible that Sainsbury's shareholders know more than its management about the wage rates likely to maximize returns?</p><p>Moreover, it is not just Sainsbury's board that takes this view. No other UK supermarket is a Living Wage Employer, and this group includes both public and private companies, and those owned by families as well as by private equity firms. How likely is it that <i>all</i> of these companies and management teams are missing an easy win-win from increasing wages to increase long-run profits and value? The onus falls on those making this case to prove it. The shareholders supporting the resolutions have notably failed to provide convincing evidence.9</p><p>This seems to be a case of ESG irrational exuberance and overreach: the desire to claim that any and all ESG activity should be expected to improve long-run performance. But if Sainsbury's management and every other management team in the UK supermarket sector is missing this obvious way to increase long-term value, then rather than filing a Living Wage resolution, investors should simply be firing the boards and installing new managements.</p><p>But financial materiality, as we have already seen, is not the only form of materiality. What about impact materiality and systemic risk? Here the materiality is determined by the extent of the company's impact on stakeholders rather than stakeholders’ impact on long-run corporate profitability and value. There is little doubt that Sainsbury's could dramatically improve the standard of living of a great many of its employees by, say, increasing their wages by a fifth. But in the grand scheme of things, even the number of such employees is relatively small in number. And ShareAction, it's important to recognize, is going after a much bigger target—economy-wide inequality. As their Sainsbury's proposal states, “low pay drives inequality which slows economic growth and stokes instability, presenting material risks to investors.”</p><p>And there is in fact some evidence for the negative impact of inequality on growth. But that evidence is far more compelling in the case of developing, low-income than developed, high-income nations—and, here again, the evidence is mixed and disputed.10 Such is also true of the evidence for inequality being a major contributor to “systemic risk.” And as we shall see, the ability of shareholder action to affect such systemic risks is quite limited.</p><p>But if this appears to be the strongest form of materiality at work in the case of Sainsbury's, there are some major challenges for asset managers when attempting to take actions that purport to represent the moral views of their investor clients. I will later return to these challenges when taking up the question of companies’ need to seek, or at least clarify, client mandates for their ESG initiatives.</p><p>Our second principle, efficacy, states that investors should act only when confident about their ability to bring about the desired change in the real world, and in such a way that the stakeholder benefits exceed the associated costs.</p><p>If the desired benefit is to increase the wages of affected Sainsbury's employees and contractors, then clearly the shareholder resolution would directly achieve this. But what about the wider impact on the systemic issue of inequality, which also seems clearly to motivate the proposal?</p><p>Here the overall consequences are much less certain. If the resolution is successful, that could lead to an industry-wide change in practices. But in what is at least an equally plausible outcome, it could simply make Sainsbury's uncompetitive, leading to loss of market share to companies not adopting the Living Wage policy. Also worth noting is the possibility that, even if investors were successful at passing resolutions at all the <i>listed</i> supermarkets, the steadily growing proportion of the UK market subject to <i>private</i> control, including Aldi, Asda, Lidl, and Morrisons, would use their lower wages to accelerate their growth in market share.</p><p>So, even though Sainsbury, Tesco, and Marks & Spencer could become the firms that determine wages in the economy, the alternative outcome is that they become less competitive and lose market share to private firms. We don't really know how such changes will play out. Therefore, while the Living Wage has symbolic appeal, it's efficacy is surrounded by doubt.</p><p>Furthermore, does the stakeholder benefit outweigh the cost of the action? Again, this is very unclear. The additional costs of fulfilling the Living Wage commitment are very likely to be reflected in some combination of reduced returns to shareholders, reduced employment, and increased prices. Indeed, the study by researchers from Queen Mary University11 cited by ShareAction in support of their case mentions that adopters of the London Living Wage have tended to offset the higher wage costs through a variety of actions, including changes to contracting terms, reduction in headcount or hours, and changes in service specifications and supplies—and, in some cases, acceptance of reduced margin. And since there is no evidence suggesting that overall net stakeholder value will increase, the probable effect of a mandated Living Wage is a “wealth transfer” from one set of stakeholders to another. And most important to keep in mind, it's not just shareholders who would bear the costs, but also the customers who pay the higher prices, and the current or future workers who suffer from the potential reduction in employment at the company.</p><p>Overall, then, the proposal fails the test of efficacy.</p><p>The last of the tests in our report is comparative advantage. Here the shareholder should consider whether they (or the company whose shares they hold) is particularly well-positioned to address, or at least influence, the stakeholder issue. Even once they are satisfied that achieving the ESG outcome is in line with their clients’ interests, asset managers should be using client money to this end only when their actions have at least a reasonable prospect of influencing the desired outcomes.</p><p>So, if the stakeholder issue is viewed narrowly as the pay of the particular affected employees and contractors at Sainsbury's, then, yes, the company has comparative advantage. However, the ShareAction campaign has clearly cast a broader net, purporting as it does to address overall economic inequality.</p><p>Here it is not at all clear that investors or Sainsbury's have comparative advantage. System-wide issues such as the appropriate minimum wage levels run into many level-playing-field problems relating to competitiveness. In such cases, governments are generally best suited to address the issue of inequality directly through minimum wages, progressive taxation, and benefits—and, in the longer term, through policies on education, health, and housing.</p><p>We often hear the argument that governments are failing to act on ESG issues. But the area of minimum wage rates in the UK seems to be one area where this criticism is unfounded. The UK Government has established a rather well structured and mature process that is overseen by the Low Pay Commission2, a process that has support from across the political spectrum, and which takes into account a wide range of stakeholder and economic considerations. Indeed, the current Government has mandated the Low Pay Commission to increase the statutory National Living Wage towards two-thirds of median earnings as quickly as possible consistent with its mandate to consider employment levels and the health of the economy more broadly. So, of all the ESG issues that could be singled out, this is one where the institutions of Government appear to be among the most effective.</p><p>And that, in brief, is why the ShareAction proposal violates the principle of comparative advantage.</p><p>Our analysis up to this point shows that the rationale for shareholders supporting the Living Wage resolution at Sainsbury's rests on a shaky foundation. It is largely inconsistent with our three key principles of materiality, efficacy, and comparative advantage.</p><p>Nevertheless, when dealing with the question of materiality, I did allow for the possibility that investors’ collective sense of morality, of the need to distinguish right from clear wrong, could lead them to support the proposal, thereby outweighing the other considerations. In other words, investors should not support companies that become “bad actors.”</p><p>The problem with this argument, however, is that should such cases arise, asset managers would need to have crystal-clear mandates from their investor clients identifying and articulating such moral objections as their main reason to act. Without such mandates, asset managers would be using “other people's money” to pursue actions with no economic benefits in view and for which neither asset managers nor their investor clients are well-positioned to expect a successful outcome.</p><p>So, this begs the question: Why not just assume that most people would consider payment of the Living Wage a moral imperative? The answer to this question is, it's not at all clear how we establish this. As just noted, we have a political system that has resulted in a quite consistent and well-developed approach to setting a National Living Wage—one that, it's important to note, has not been subjected to the intense cross-party disagreement that has for long been the dominant note in UK politics. Indeed, the UK approach to minimum-wage setting has elicited a striking degree of bi-partisan unity that has persisted for over a decade among Labor, Coalition, and Conservative Governments. Thus, it surely seems reasonable to suppose that many if not most UK citizens view the <i>National</i> Living Wage as an adequate response to the problem of in-work pay rates.</p><p>Given the difficulty of assuming that clients’ views will differ from the prevailing political consensus, my recommendation was that investors voting in favor of the ShareAction proposal have a very clear and explicit mandate from their investor clients directing the asset managers to back the proposal with their (investors’) capital. The same asset managers should also clearly inform their investor clients of the potential for negative effects on shareholder returns, failure of the actions to lead to the desired social outcomes, and potential unintended. Including the possibility noted above of regressive distributional effects. Given all these possible outcomes, and the dearth of evidence about how things will play out, it would be foolhardy for investors to rely on the kind of “win-win” argument presented by ShareAction.</p><p>When I published these arguments in June of 2022, it clearly struck a chord. A number of investors contacted me to thank me for the reasoned analysis. Further suggesting the article was getting some traction, ShareAction published a rebuttal, to which I then felt obliged to respond.12</p><p>At the AGM that was held on Thursday July 7, 2022 to decide the proposal, 83.3% of investors voted against it, with only one in six supporting it. The vote thus failed not only to pass, but to meet the 20% level that the UK Corporate Governance Code and the Investment Association views as conveying a “significant” level of investor opposition to management. Notwithstanding this level of investor opposition to the proposal, ShareAction saw fit to evict Schroders from the Good Work Coalition they had established as an investor collaboration to engage with companies to encourage them to adopt better working practices.13</p><p>There are a number of important lessons for ESG activism that can be drawn from this case. After the AGM took place, I identified four.14</p><p>But having raised these concerns about the ShareAction proposal, I find it important to say that the principles we developed with The Investor Forum do not provide a free pass for investors to ignore ESG issues. To illustrate this, let's briefly consider a different shareholder proposal.</p><p>A number of large public companies have recently faced shareholder proposals relating to deforestation.17 In October 2020, the following resolution was filed at the P&G meeting:18</p><p><i>Shareholders request P&G issue a report assessing if and how it could increase the scale, pace, and rigor of its efforts to eliminate deforestation and the degradation of intact forests in its supply chains</i>.</p><p>The rationale provided by the filer, Green Century Capital Management, was couched in terms of shareholder value considerations: the risk of supply chain disruption due to environmental degradation; competitive effects from falling behind peers on deforestation policies; and reputational and related financial risk. This presumably was intended to secure the support of major index funds.</p><p>But as I'll now demonstrate, the case could be made much stronger. What if the resolution had called for P&G to <i>take action</i> to reduce deforestation in its supply chains? How would this have squared with our principles?</p><p>Let us now briefly run through the application of the principles. And let's start with <i>materiality</i>. Green Century Capital Management made a case for financial materiality of the issue. There is a case for this. However, even if one remains unpersuaded by it, P&G by virtue of its supply chain clearly has a potentially material impact on the issue of deforestation. Given widespread concern about the environment, it is also reasonable to believe that the issue has intrinsic materiality in the eyes of a great many end clients of the asset manager.</p><p>What about <i>efficacy</i>? Large companies have significant ability to influence supplier practices through their supply chain. Moreover, there is very limited ability to reverse deforestation once it has occurred. It is significantly cheaper to avoid deforestation in the first place than to remedy the effects once it has happened. Finally, innovation in new practices that enable production of goods without deforestation can have positive spill-over effects across an industry. Admittedly the competitive concerns outlined above still apply. But in this case, there seems to be a high probability that the net stakeholder benefits outweigh the costs by a very large margin, principally because of the gulf between cost of avoiding damage versus cost of remediation.</p><p>Third and last, what about the question of <i>comparative advantage</i><b>?</b> Deforestation is an area where effective government regulation is difficult to define and put in place, and enforcement is extremely difficult. It requires collaboration between national governments and enforcement by countries where authorities and institutions may be relatively weak. Therefore companies, and by extension investors, seem particularly well placed to act in this area.</p><p>And so, in the case of action on deforestation, the principles of materiality, efficacy at reasonable cost, and comparative advantage are all likely to be met in many cases. Investors still need to be sure that they have a mandate from their clients given that some costs may arise. But the costs are likely to be manageable relative to the benefits, and asset managers may even be able to rely on general pro-social sentiments of end investors as a mandate for action.</p><p>Consistent with this reasoning, the Proctor & Gamble resolution was supported by 67% of shareholders.</p><p>The recognition that shareholders have non-financial as well as financial preferences is welcome, as is the increased willingness of shareholders and their representatives to use their rights to seek to influence companies on ESG issues. ShareAction and Schroders have done us a service by enabling us to have this important debate on an “S” issue within the ESG universe.</p><p>But this needs to be done thoughtfully, with particular attention paid to the likely effectiveness of the action and its potential costs, considered in the context of asset managers’ fiduciary duty to, and mandates from, clients. A rather lazy narrative has grown up around the concept of “doing well by doing good” that is predisposed to view all ESG activities as beneficial for long-term value. But clearly, they are not. ESG interventions often involve trade-offs between shareholder value (even over the long-term) and stakeholder value. Moreover, they often result in trade-offs between different categories of non-shareholder stakeholders.</p><p>Asset managers need to undertake a rigorous analysis to figure out which ESG issues to act on and which to leave alone. The framework of principles we developed with The Investor Forum helps to do just this.</p><p>Thoughtful consideration of the principles suggests that Schroders was right to vote against the Living Wage resolution at Sainsbury's. Costs to shareholders appear almost certain while the net stakeholder value remains highly uncertain and, indeed, quite plausibly zero. There are unpredictable distributional effects since, as we have noted, many low-income stakeholders may be more harmed than helped by the proposal. Shareholders are not nearly as well-positioned to address the issue of minimum in-work wages as the UK Government. And as we have seen, the UK has developed a widely accepted and generally quite effective independent process backed by a political mandate to set minimum wage levels.</p><p>None of this, to be sure, should be taken to mean that Sainsbury's should absolve itself from responsibility for thoughtfully considering the level of fair pay for workers and contractors. The Living Wage provides a useful and relevant framework for this purpose. Investors should continue to engage with Sainsbury's to understand how they are ensuring the well-being of their employees and monitoring conditions in supply chains. But the case is not made for investors to force upon the board a particular course of action on pay.</p><p>Finally, I am by no means suggesting that shareholders and companies be given a free pass on ESG. I've used the example of deforestation to show how the principles can lead to the conclusion that investors should support an ESG-related resolution. But shareholders don't have unlimited capacity to engage companies on ESG issues; they must focus their energies and efforts where they can achieve the most effective outcomes and where there is most bang for their buck. Living Wage accreditation in the UK doesn't meet this test. And so the overwhelming majority of shareholders were right to follow Schroders in voting against the resolution at Sainsbury's AGM in July 2022.</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":0,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"\",\"volume\":null,\"pages\":null},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0,\"publicationDate\":\"2023-06-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/jacf.12550\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jacf.12550\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jacf.12550","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
摘要
英国大型连锁超市之一塞恩斯伯里(Sainsbury's)在2022年发现自己成为了ESG激进主义的目标。就在那时,著名的责任投资非政府组织ShareAction在英国提交了第一份生活工资决议。在10份共同提交的文件中,有英国投资界的蓝筹公司,包括Legal and General、汇丰资产管理、富达国际、Nest和布鲁内尔养老金合伙公司。在2022年7月7日举行的塞恩斯伯里年度股东大会上,大约六分之五的投资者对该决议投了反对票。为了理解这一衡量标准未能获得认可的原因和原因,首先要注意最低生活工资和全国最低生活工资之间的区别,这一点在下面的方框中进行了简要说明。ShareAction显然将其在塞恩斯伯里超市(Sainsbury's)的最低生活工资决议视为其打算与整个英国超市行业展开一场战斗的第一枪。这也是该非政府组织首次努力让人们注意到“S”在ESG中的重要性。该提案将该决议描述为“在生活成本危机中对投资者社会承诺的试金石”。英国知名资产管理公司施罗德(Schroders)采取了一个不同寻常的举动,在投票前公布了其决定不支持该决议的理由。施罗德在塞恩斯伯里拥有五大投资头寸之一。施罗德主动持股组负责人金伯利•刘易斯(Kimberley Lewis)写了一篇题为《为什么Sainsbury的年度股东大会是ESG的关键时刻》的文章。在指出Sainsbury's是一家公认的经营良好的公司,在关键决策中考虑到所有重要的利益相关者,并在员工身上投入了大量资金之后,文章随后表达了这样的担忧:在没有其他英国超市是生活工资雇主的情况下,对Sainsbury's施加进一步的限制可能会破坏该公司的竞争地位,最终会对其许多员工和客户以及投资者造成经济伤害。刘易斯在文章的最后警告称,“笼统地、不加考虑地”应用ESG因素会带来不可预见的风险,她将其描述为“‘轻率的ESG’……这会损害可持续投资的可信度。”除了这一警告,她还表示,她认为即将到来的决议的结果是“能否听到这些辩论中的重要细微差别的考验”。关于这项决议有很多可说的。我们不妨先问一下,ShareAction如何能声称,要求公司采用由第三方设定的员工最低工资标准的决议,会完全不受董事会自由裁量权的影响,因为生活工资基金会“只会设定最低工资标准”。但是,当我们对这家非政府组织提出这样的问题时,我们也可以问一问,为什么施罗德本身就是一家“生活工资雇主”,它认为鹅的酱汁不应该也适用于雄鹅。未能在鼓励采用最低生活工资的“参与蓝图”(Engagement Blueprint)的背景下解释其投票决定,如果不是一种疏忽,那么至少是错失了阐明自己信念的机会。但我在这里的目的更多是分析性的,而不是争论性的,也就是说,从投资者和董事会职责的角度来审视这场辩论双方的主张。为了帮助分析,我将首先简要概述伦敦商学院与投资者论坛在2021年开发的ESG决策原则,我们称之为“利益相关者资本主义对投资者意味着什么?”然后,我将继续论证,尽管该框架在很大程度上支持施罗德的立场,但其基本原则并不是企业和投资者可以忽视任何他们认为棘手的ESG问题的通行证。为了说明这一点,我还将使用该框架来评估另一项决议,该决议是由P&G股东于2020年提出的关于森林砍伐的决议。在这种情况下,原则的应用导致对该决议的广泛支持,与ShareAction决议不同的是,该决议不仅获得了通过,而且得到了其三分之二投资者的支持。投资者论坛与伦敦商学院合作的推动力是,投资者对如何评估和应对在ESG问题上采取行动的多重相互竞争的要求感到困惑和不确定,同时缺乏一个明确的框架来决定采取或支持哪些行动。该框架首先承认资产管理公司为客户利益行事的受托责任。尽管普遍的说法与之相反,但并非所有ESG举措都能增加股东价值,即使从长期来看也是如此。有些只是花钱。所有这些都不应被解释为否认资产所有者和最终受益人有非财务目标和关切,这些目标和关切有时很可能导致他们认为这些成本值得承担。 因此,如果将利益相关者问题狭隘地视为受影响的塞恩斯伯里员工和承包商的薪酬,那么,是的,该公司具有比较优势。然而,ShareAction运动显然撒下了一张更广泛的网,声称要解决整体的经济不平等问题。在这一点上,投资者或塞恩斯伯里是否有比较优势一点也不清楚。诸如适当的最低工资水平等全系统问题涉及许多与竞争力有关的公平竞争问题。在这种情况下,政府通常最适合通过最低工资、累进税和福利来直接解决不平等问题,从长远来看,还可以通过教育、卫生和住房政策来解决。我们经常听到政府未能在ESG问题上采取行动的说法。但在英国的最低工资率方面,这种批评似乎是没有根据的。英国政府已经建立了一个结构相当完善和成熟的程序,由低薪委员会监督,该程序得到了整个政治领域的支持,并考虑到广泛的利益相关者和经济方面的考虑。事实上,现政府已授权低薪委员会根据其更广泛地考虑就业水平和经济健康的任务,尽快将法定全国生活工资提高到收入中位数的三分之二。因此,在所有可以单独列出的ESG问题中,这是政府机构似乎最有效的一个问题。简而言之,这就是ShareAction提案违反比较优势原则的原因。到目前为止,我们的分析表明,股东支持塞恩斯伯里(Sainsbury)最低生活工资决议的理由,建立在一个不稳固的基础上。它在很大程度上不符合我们的三个关键原则:实质性、有效性和比较优势。然而,在处理实质性问题时,我确实考虑到这样一种可能性,即投资者的集体道德感,即需要区分正确与明显错误,可能导致他们支持该提议,从而超过其他考虑因素。换句话说,投资者不应该支持那些成为“坏人”的公司。然而,这种观点的问题在于,如果出现这种情况,资产管理公司将需要获得投资者客户的明确授权,以识别并阐明此类道德反对意见,作为其采取行动的主要理由。如果没有这样的授权,资产管理公司就会用“别人的钱”从事没有经济效益的行动,而且资产管理公司及其投资者客户都无法期望取得成功。所以,这就引出了一个问题:为什么不假设大多数人会认为支付最低生活工资是一种道德要求呢?这个问题的答案是,我们根本不清楚如何建立它。正如刚才提到的,我们的政治制度导致了一个相当一致和完善的方法来设定国民生活工资——一个重要的是要注意的是,它没有受到长期以来在英国政治中占主导地位的激烈的跨党派分歧的影响。事实上,英国在设定最低工资方面的做法已经引起了工党、联合政府和保守党政府之间惊人程度的两党团结,这种团结已经持续了十多年。因此,假设许多(如果不是大多数的话)英国公民将全国最低生活工资(National Living Wage)视为对在职工资水平问题的充分回应,似乎是合理的。考虑到很难假设客户的观点会与主流政治共识不同,我的建议是,投票支持ShareAction提案的投资者得到了他们的投资者客户非常明确的授权,指示资产管理公司用他们(投资者)的资金支持该提案。同样的,资产管理公司也应该清楚地告知他们的投资者客户,对股东回报可能产生负面影响,行动无法产生预期的社会结果,以及潜在的意外。包括上述可能出现的递减分配效应。考虑到所有这些可能的结果,以及缺乏关于事情将如何发展的证据,投资者依赖ShareAction提出的那种“双赢”论点将是鲁莽的。当我在2022年6月发表这些观点时,显然引起了共鸣。许多投资者联系我,感谢我的理性分析。ShareAction发表了一篇反驳文章,进一步表明这篇文章正在引起一些关注,然后我觉得有必要回应。在2022年7月7日星期四举行的股东年会上,83.3%的投资者投了反对票,只有六分之一的投资者投了赞成票。 因此,投票结果不仅没有通过,而且没有达到英国公司治理守则和投资协会认为的20%的水平,即传达了投资者对管理层的“重大”反对。尽管投资者反对该提议的程度如此之高,但ShareAction认为,将施罗德赶出他们建立的良好工作联盟(Good Work Coalition)是合适的。良好工作联盟是一个投资者合作组织,旨在与企业接触,鼓励它们采用更好的工作实践。从这个案例中,我们可以得出许多ESG行动主义的重要教训。在年度股东大会之后,我确定了四个。但是,在提出对ShareAction提案的这些担忧之后,我认为有必要指出的是,我们与投资者论坛共同制定的原则并没有为投资者提供忽视ESG问题的免费通行证。为了说明这一点,让我们简单地考虑一个不同的股东提案。一些大型上市公司最近面临股东关于砍伐森林的建议2020年10月,在P&G会议上提交了以下决议:18股东要求P&G发布一份报告,评估其是否以及如何增加其努力的规模、速度和严格程度,以消除其供应链中森林砍伐和完整森林的退化。申报人绿世纪资本管理公司(Green Century Capital Management)提供的理由是基于股东价值考虑:环境恶化导致供应链中断的风险;在森林砍伐政策上落后于同行的竞争效应;以及声誉和相关的财务风险。这大概是为了获得主要指数基金的支持。但正如我现在要证明的那样,这种情况可以变得更加有力。如果该决议呼吁宝洁采取行动减少其供应链中的森林砍伐,结果会怎样?这怎么符合我们的原则呢?现在让我们简单地回顾一下这些原则的应用。让我们从物质开始。绿色世纪资本管理公司(Green Century Capital Management)对该问题的财务重要性提出了理由。这是有道理的。然而,即使人们不相信它,凭借其供应链,P&G显然对森林砍伐问题具有潜在的实质性影响。鉴于对环境的广泛关注,我们也有理由相信,在这家资产管理公司的许多终端客户看来,这个问题具有内在的重要性。功效呢?大公司有很大的能力通过他们的供应链影响供应商的做法。此外,森林砍伐一旦发生,逆转的能力非常有限。从一开始就避免森林砍伐比在森林砍伐发生后进行补救要便宜得多。最后,在不砍伐森林的情况下进行商品生产的新做法的创新可以对整个行业产生积极的溢出效应。诚然,上述对竞争的担忧仍然存在。但在这种情况下,利益相关者的净收益似乎很有可能大大超过成本,这主要是因为避免损害的成本与补救成本之间存在鸿沟。第三也是最后一点,比较优势的问题是什么?森林砍伐是一个难以界定和实施有效政府监管的领域,执行起来极其困难。它需要各国政府之间的合作,以及当局和机构可能相对薄弱的国家的执法。因此,公司,以及投资者,似乎特别适合在这一领域采取行动。因此,在对森林砍伐采取行动的情况下,实质性原则、合理成本下的有效性原则和比较优势原则在许多情况下都可能得到满足。考虑到可能会产生一些成本,投资者仍需要确保他们得到了客户的授权。但相对于收益而言,成本可能是可控的,资产管理公司甚至可能将终端投资者普遍的亲社会情绪作为行动的依据。与这一推理相一致的是,Proctor &甘布尔的决议得到67%股东的支持。认识到股东既有财务方面的偏好,也有非财务方面的偏好是值得欢迎的,股东及其代表越来越愿意利用自己的权利,在ESG问题上寻求对公司施加影响。ShareAction和施罗德帮了我们一个忙,让我们能够就ESG领域的“S”问题展开这场重要的辩论。但这需要深思熟虑,尤其要注意行动的可能有效性及其潜在成本,并考虑到资产管理公司对客户的受托责任和客户的委托。 围绕“通过做好事来做得更好”的概念,一种相当懒惰的说法已经形成,这种说法倾向于认为所有ESG活动都有利于实现长期价值。但很明显,它们并非如此。ESG干预通常涉及股东价值(即使是长期的)和利益相关者价值之间的权衡。此外,它们往往导致不同类别的非股东利益相关者之间的权衡。资产管理公司需要进行严格的分析,以确定哪些ESG问题需要采取行动,哪些问题不用管。我们与投资者论坛共同制定的原则框架有助于做到这一点。对这些原则的深思熟虑表明,施罗德投票反对塞恩斯伯里的生活工资决议是正确的。股东的成本似乎几乎可以确定,而股东的净价值仍然高度不确定,实际上,很有可能为零。正如我们所指出的那样,由于该提案对许多低收入利益相关者的伤害可能大于帮助,因此存在不可预测的分配效应。在解决最低工作工资问题上,股东们的地位远不如英国政府。正如我们所看到的,英国已经制定了一套被广泛接受、总体上相当有效的独立程序,并得到了设定最低工资水平的政治授权的支持。当然,这一切都不意味着塞恩斯伯里可以免除自己仔细考虑工人和承包商公平薪酬水平的责任。最低生活工资为这一目的提供了一个有用和相关的框架。投资者应继续与塞恩斯伯里接触,了解他们如何确保员工的福祉,并监控供应链的状况。但投资者没有理由强迫董事会在薪酬问题上采取特定的行动。最后,我绝不是建议股东和公司在ESG问题上获得免费通行证。我以森林砍伐为例,说明这些原则如何得出这样的结论:投资者应该支持与esg相关的决议。但股东并没有无限的能力让公司参与ESG问题;他们必须把精力和努力集中在能够取得最有效成果的地方,以及最物有所值的地方。英国的生活工资认证不符合这一标准。因此,绝大多数股东在2022年7月的塞恩斯伯里年度股东大会上跟随施罗德投票反对该决议是正确的。
Lessons for ESG activists: The case of Sainsbury's and the living wage
Sainsbury's, one of the UK's large supermarket chains, found itself in the crosshairs of ESG activism in 2022. That was when ShareAction, a well-known responsible investment NGO, filed the first Living Wage resolution in the UK.1
Among the 10 co-filers were blue-chip names in the UK investment world, including Legal and General, HSBC Asset Management, Fidelity International, Nest, and the Brunel Pension Partnership.
This Living Wage resolution was rejected by roughly five out of every six of the Sainsbury's investors that voted on the resolution at the company's Annual General Meeting on July 7, 2022. To understand how and why this measure failed to gain acceptance, it's useful to start by noting the difference between The Living Wage and the National Living Wage, which is briefly described in the box below.
ShareAction clearly saw its Living Wage resolution at Sainsbury's as the opening salvo in a battle it intended to conduct with the entire UK supermarket sector. It was also one of the NGO's first efforts to draw attention to the importance of the “S” in ESG. The proposal described the resolution as a “litmus test for investors’ social commitments amid the cost-of-living crisis.”
In an unusual move, Schroders, the well-known UK asset manager with one of the five largest investment positions in Sainsbury's, published ahead of the vote its rationale for its decision not to support the resolution. Kimberley Lewis, Head of Schroders’ Active Ownership group, wrote an article titled, “Why Sainsbury's AGM is a Pivotal Moment for ESG.”4 After pointing out that Sainsbury's is widely recognized as a well-run company that considers all important stakeholders in key decisions and has invested heavily in its employees, the article then expressed the concern that imposing this further restriction on Sainsbury's at a time when no other UK supermarket was a Living Wage Employer could undermine the company's competitive position, which would end up doing economic harm to many of its employees and customers as well as its investors.
Lewis closed her article with a warning against the unforeseen risks of applying ESG factors “in a blanket way and without due consideration,” describing it as “‘unthinking ESG’ … which harms the credibility of sustainable investing.” Along with this warning, she also expressed her view of the outcome of the impending resolution as “a test of whether important nuances in these debates can be heard”.
There is much that could be said about this resolution. We might start by asking how ShareAction could claim that the resolution—which requires the company to adopt a floor on employee pay set by a third party—would leave board discretion wholly unaffected and intact, because the Living Wage Foundation “would merely set the minimum level”. But while we are raising such questions about the NGO, we could also ask why Schroders, itself a Living Wage Employer, thinks that what is sauce for the goose should not be sauce for the gander too. Failure to explain its voting decision in the context of an Engagement Blueprint that encourages Living Wage adoption seems, if not an oversight, then at least a missed opportunity to provide clarity about its own convictions.
But my purpose here is more analytical than polemical, namely, to examine the claims on both sides of this debate when viewed through the lens of investor and board duties. To help with this analysis, I will start by providing a brief overview of the ESG decision-making principles that London Business School developed with The Investor Forum during 2021 in a project we called “What does stakeholder capitalism mean for investors?”5 Then I will go on to argue that, however, much the framework supports Schroders’ position, the underlying principles are not a free pass for companies and investors to ignore any ESG issue they find troublesome.
To illustrate this point, I'll also use the framework to evaluate another resolution, this one put forward in 2020 by a P&G shareholder on deforestation. In this case application of the principles leads to broad support for this resolution that, unlike the ShareAction resolution, not only passed but received the support of fully two thirds of its investors.
The impetus for the collaboration between The Investor Forum and London Business School was investors’ confusion and uncertainty about how to evaluate and respond to the multiple competing demands to act on ESG issues while lacking a clear framework for deciding which actions to pursue or support. The framework begins by recognizing asset managers’ fiduciary duty to act in the interests of their clients. Despite common rhetoric to the contrary, not all ESG initiatives work to increase shareholder value, even over the long term. Some simply cost money.
None of this should be construed as denying that asset owners and end beneficiaries have non-financial objectives and concerns that may well sometimes lead them to view such costs as worth bearing. But in such cases, asset managers’ fiduciary duty to act in the interests of their clients imposes on them a second obligation: when intending to pursue ESG initiatives and investments that are expected to sacrifice long-run value (presumably without undermining the company's competitive position), corporate boards must first seek and gain the clearest possible mandate from their investors to make such (again, presumably modest) sacrifices. Launching major ESG initiatives involving large capital commitments that are expected to reduce shareholder returns without such a mandate is courting investor disapproval and, eventually, removal.
Let's now try to apply these tests to the Sainsbury's case.
Our first principle—that shareholders should act on a stakeholder issue only when the stakeholder (or issue) is material to the company concerned—is a simple matter of prioritization. Sainsbury's employees are clearly an important contributor to, and have a material stake in, the company's long-run success.
But is the adoption of a Living Wage itself a material stakeholder issue, especially when Sainsbury's reports that the vast majority of its direct and indirect employees are already paid the Living Wage?
There are many lenses for assessing materiality. There is the traditional lens of financial materiality: stakeholder issues that clearly affect the profitability of the company. But in response to the criticism of this concept as too narrow, there is growing focus on impact materiality—cases in which corporate decisions impose hardship or “costs” on stakeholders, whether or not there is a discernible effect on corporate profits or value. And there is another version called dynamic materiality—involving those issues that, if unaddressed, could become financially material. For example, consumers’ concerns about corporate treatment of workers in supply chains could end up influencing consumer purchasing habits. Into this mix we also introduced the idea of intrinsic materiality, which applies to stakeholder issues relating to traditional social or moral expectations. Finally, stakeholder issues can be company specific or systemic, in the sense of affecting the economy as a whole rather than individual companies.
Let's start with financial materiality—does the issue of Sainsbury's Living Wage affect the long-run profitability and value of the company? ShareAction claimed that it does. In support of its proposal, Rachel Hargreaves, ShareAction's Campaigns Manager, stated that “research has consistently demonstrated a positive business case for Living Wage rates, even in low-margin sectors such as retail.” And consistent with Hargreaves’ argument, there is in fact a theory of “efficiency wages” that hypothesizes that companies choosing to pay above-market wages may get a payback in the form of higher-quality and more productive employees. Such a policy is widely viewed as a major contributor to the widely heralded success of the U.S. company CostCo.
But evidence about the more general case is mixed, and invariably contested. The possibility that higher wages can be repaid through higher productivity does not mean they are generally expected to be. And, of course, in all cases there is some level of wages at which the relationship will turn down and become sharply negative.
One of the most important tasks and responsibilities of Sainsbury's board and executive team is to determine to what extent, if at all, they want to deviate from market norms in how the company rewards their employees. The board and management are highly experienced, and by all accounts well-attuned to employee attitudes and have clear incentives to improve the company's long-term performance. Is it plausible that Sainsbury's shareholders know more than its management about the wage rates likely to maximize returns?
Moreover, it is not just Sainsbury's board that takes this view. No other UK supermarket is a Living Wage Employer, and this group includes both public and private companies, and those owned by families as well as by private equity firms. How likely is it that all of these companies and management teams are missing an easy win-win from increasing wages to increase long-run profits and value? The onus falls on those making this case to prove it. The shareholders supporting the resolutions have notably failed to provide convincing evidence.9
This seems to be a case of ESG irrational exuberance and overreach: the desire to claim that any and all ESG activity should be expected to improve long-run performance. But if Sainsbury's management and every other management team in the UK supermarket sector is missing this obvious way to increase long-term value, then rather than filing a Living Wage resolution, investors should simply be firing the boards and installing new managements.
But financial materiality, as we have already seen, is not the only form of materiality. What about impact materiality and systemic risk? Here the materiality is determined by the extent of the company's impact on stakeholders rather than stakeholders’ impact on long-run corporate profitability and value. There is little doubt that Sainsbury's could dramatically improve the standard of living of a great many of its employees by, say, increasing their wages by a fifth. But in the grand scheme of things, even the number of such employees is relatively small in number. And ShareAction, it's important to recognize, is going after a much bigger target—economy-wide inequality. As their Sainsbury's proposal states, “low pay drives inequality which slows economic growth and stokes instability, presenting material risks to investors.”
And there is in fact some evidence for the negative impact of inequality on growth. But that evidence is far more compelling in the case of developing, low-income than developed, high-income nations—and, here again, the evidence is mixed and disputed.10 Such is also true of the evidence for inequality being a major contributor to “systemic risk.” And as we shall see, the ability of shareholder action to affect such systemic risks is quite limited.
But if this appears to be the strongest form of materiality at work in the case of Sainsbury's, there are some major challenges for asset managers when attempting to take actions that purport to represent the moral views of their investor clients. I will later return to these challenges when taking up the question of companies’ need to seek, or at least clarify, client mandates for their ESG initiatives.
Our second principle, efficacy, states that investors should act only when confident about their ability to bring about the desired change in the real world, and in such a way that the stakeholder benefits exceed the associated costs.
If the desired benefit is to increase the wages of affected Sainsbury's employees and contractors, then clearly the shareholder resolution would directly achieve this. But what about the wider impact on the systemic issue of inequality, which also seems clearly to motivate the proposal?
Here the overall consequences are much less certain. If the resolution is successful, that could lead to an industry-wide change in practices. But in what is at least an equally plausible outcome, it could simply make Sainsbury's uncompetitive, leading to loss of market share to companies not adopting the Living Wage policy. Also worth noting is the possibility that, even if investors were successful at passing resolutions at all the listed supermarkets, the steadily growing proportion of the UK market subject to private control, including Aldi, Asda, Lidl, and Morrisons, would use their lower wages to accelerate their growth in market share.
So, even though Sainsbury, Tesco, and Marks & Spencer could become the firms that determine wages in the economy, the alternative outcome is that they become less competitive and lose market share to private firms. We don't really know how such changes will play out. Therefore, while the Living Wage has symbolic appeal, it's efficacy is surrounded by doubt.
Furthermore, does the stakeholder benefit outweigh the cost of the action? Again, this is very unclear. The additional costs of fulfilling the Living Wage commitment are very likely to be reflected in some combination of reduced returns to shareholders, reduced employment, and increased prices. Indeed, the study by researchers from Queen Mary University11 cited by ShareAction in support of their case mentions that adopters of the London Living Wage have tended to offset the higher wage costs through a variety of actions, including changes to contracting terms, reduction in headcount or hours, and changes in service specifications and supplies—and, in some cases, acceptance of reduced margin. And since there is no evidence suggesting that overall net stakeholder value will increase, the probable effect of a mandated Living Wage is a “wealth transfer” from one set of stakeholders to another. And most important to keep in mind, it's not just shareholders who would bear the costs, but also the customers who pay the higher prices, and the current or future workers who suffer from the potential reduction in employment at the company.
Overall, then, the proposal fails the test of efficacy.
The last of the tests in our report is comparative advantage. Here the shareholder should consider whether they (or the company whose shares they hold) is particularly well-positioned to address, or at least influence, the stakeholder issue. Even once they are satisfied that achieving the ESG outcome is in line with their clients’ interests, asset managers should be using client money to this end only when their actions have at least a reasonable prospect of influencing the desired outcomes.
So, if the stakeholder issue is viewed narrowly as the pay of the particular affected employees and contractors at Sainsbury's, then, yes, the company has comparative advantage. However, the ShareAction campaign has clearly cast a broader net, purporting as it does to address overall economic inequality.
Here it is not at all clear that investors or Sainsbury's have comparative advantage. System-wide issues such as the appropriate minimum wage levels run into many level-playing-field problems relating to competitiveness. In such cases, governments are generally best suited to address the issue of inequality directly through minimum wages, progressive taxation, and benefits—and, in the longer term, through policies on education, health, and housing.
We often hear the argument that governments are failing to act on ESG issues. But the area of minimum wage rates in the UK seems to be one area where this criticism is unfounded. The UK Government has established a rather well structured and mature process that is overseen by the Low Pay Commission2, a process that has support from across the political spectrum, and which takes into account a wide range of stakeholder and economic considerations. Indeed, the current Government has mandated the Low Pay Commission to increase the statutory National Living Wage towards two-thirds of median earnings as quickly as possible consistent with its mandate to consider employment levels and the health of the economy more broadly. So, of all the ESG issues that could be singled out, this is one where the institutions of Government appear to be among the most effective.
And that, in brief, is why the ShareAction proposal violates the principle of comparative advantage.
Our analysis up to this point shows that the rationale for shareholders supporting the Living Wage resolution at Sainsbury's rests on a shaky foundation. It is largely inconsistent with our three key principles of materiality, efficacy, and comparative advantage.
Nevertheless, when dealing with the question of materiality, I did allow for the possibility that investors’ collective sense of morality, of the need to distinguish right from clear wrong, could lead them to support the proposal, thereby outweighing the other considerations. In other words, investors should not support companies that become “bad actors.”
The problem with this argument, however, is that should such cases arise, asset managers would need to have crystal-clear mandates from their investor clients identifying and articulating such moral objections as their main reason to act. Without such mandates, asset managers would be using “other people's money” to pursue actions with no economic benefits in view and for which neither asset managers nor their investor clients are well-positioned to expect a successful outcome.
So, this begs the question: Why not just assume that most people would consider payment of the Living Wage a moral imperative? The answer to this question is, it's not at all clear how we establish this. As just noted, we have a political system that has resulted in a quite consistent and well-developed approach to setting a National Living Wage—one that, it's important to note, has not been subjected to the intense cross-party disagreement that has for long been the dominant note in UK politics. Indeed, the UK approach to minimum-wage setting has elicited a striking degree of bi-partisan unity that has persisted for over a decade among Labor, Coalition, and Conservative Governments. Thus, it surely seems reasonable to suppose that many if not most UK citizens view the National Living Wage as an adequate response to the problem of in-work pay rates.
Given the difficulty of assuming that clients’ views will differ from the prevailing political consensus, my recommendation was that investors voting in favor of the ShareAction proposal have a very clear and explicit mandate from their investor clients directing the asset managers to back the proposal with their (investors’) capital. The same asset managers should also clearly inform their investor clients of the potential for negative effects on shareholder returns, failure of the actions to lead to the desired social outcomes, and potential unintended. Including the possibility noted above of regressive distributional effects. Given all these possible outcomes, and the dearth of evidence about how things will play out, it would be foolhardy for investors to rely on the kind of “win-win” argument presented by ShareAction.
When I published these arguments in June of 2022, it clearly struck a chord. A number of investors contacted me to thank me for the reasoned analysis. Further suggesting the article was getting some traction, ShareAction published a rebuttal, to which I then felt obliged to respond.12
At the AGM that was held on Thursday July 7, 2022 to decide the proposal, 83.3% of investors voted against it, with only one in six supporting it. The vote thus failed not only to pass, but to meet the 20% level that the UK Corporate Governance Code and the Investment Association views as conveying a “significant” level of investor opposition to management. Notwithstanding this level of investor opposition to the proposal, ShareAction saw fit to evict Schroders from the Good Work Coalition they had established as an investor collaboration to engage with companies to encourage them to adopt better working practices.13
There are a number of important lessons for ESG activism that can be drawn from this case. After the AGM took place, I identified four.14
But having raised these concerns about the ShareAction proposal, I find it important to say that the principles we developed with The Investor Forum do not provide a free pass for investors to ignore ESG issues. To illustrate this, let's briefly consider a different shareholder proposal.
A number of large public companies have recently faced shareholder proposals relating to deforestation.17 In October 2020, the following resolution was filed at the P&G meeting:18
Shareholders request P&G issue a report assessing if and how it could increase the scale, pace, and rigor of its efforts to eliminate deforestation and the degradation of intact forests in its supply chains.
The rationale provided by the filer, Green Century Capital Management, was couched in terms of shareholder value considerations: the risk of supply chain disruption due to environmental degradation; competitive effects from falling behind peers on deforestation policies; and reputational and related financial risk. This presumably was intended to secure the support of major index funds.
But as I'll now demonstrate, the case could be made much stronger. What if the resolution had called for P&G to take action to reduce deforestation in its supply chains? How would this have squared with our principles?
Let us now briefly run through the application of the principles. And let's start with materiality. Green Century Capital Management made a case for financial materiality of the issue. There is a case for this. However, even if one remains unpersuaded by it, P&G by virtue of its supply chain clearly has a potentially material impact on the issue of deforestation. Given widespread concern about the environment, it is also reasonable to believe that the issue has intrinsic materiality in the eyes of a great many end clients of the asset manager.
What about efficacy? Large companies have significant ability to influence supplier practices through their supply chain. Moreover, there is very limited ability to reverse deforestation once it has occurred. It is significantly cheaper to avoid deforestation in the first place than to remedy the effects once it has happened. Finally, innovation in new practices that enable production of goods without deforestation can have positive spill-over effects across an industry. Admittedly the competitive concerns outlined above still apply. But in this case, there seems to be a high probability that the net stakeholder benefits outweigh the costs by a very large margin, principally because of the gulf between cost of avoiding damage versus cost of remediation.
Third and last, what about the question of comparative advantage? Deforestation is an area where effective government regulation is difficult to define and put in place, and enforcement is extremely difficult. It requires collaboration between national governments and enforcement by countries where authorities and institutions may be relatively weak. Therefore companies, and by extension investors, seem particularly well placed to act in this area.
And so, in the case of action on deforestation, the principles of materiality, efficacy at reasonable cost, and comparative advantage are all likely to be met in many cases. Investors still need to be sure that they have a mandate from their clients given that some costs may arise. But the costs are likely to be manageable relative to the benefits, and asset managers may even be able to rely on general pro-social sentiments of end investors as a mandate for action.
Consistent with this reasoning, the Proctor & Gamble resolution was supported by 67% of shareholders.
The recognition that shareholders have non-financial as well as financial preferences is welcome, as is the increased willingness of shareholders and their representatives to use their rights to seek to influence companies on ESG issues. ShareAction and Schroders have done us a service by enabling us to have this important debate on an “S” issue within the ESG universe.
But this needs to be done thoughtfully, with particular attention paid to the likely effectiveness of the action and its potential costs, considered in the context of asset managers’ fiduciary duty to, and mandates from, clients. A rather lazy narrative has grown up around the concept of “doing well by doing good” that is predisposed to view all ESG activities as beneficial for long-term value. But clearly, they are not. ESG interventions often involve trade-offs between shareholder value (even over the long-term) and stakeholder value. Moreover, they often result in trade-offs between different categories of non-shareholder stakeholders.
Asset managers need to undertake a rigorous analysis to figure out which ESG issues to act on and which to leave alone. The framework of principles we developed with The Investor Forum helps to do just this.
Thoughtful consideration of the principles suggests that Schroders was right to vote against the Living Wage resolution at Sainsbury's. Costs to shareholders appear almost certain while the net stakeholder value remains highly uncertain and, indeed, quite plausibly zero. There are unpredictable distributional effects since, as we have noted, many low-income stakeholders may be more harmed than helped by the proposal. Shareholders are not nearly as well-positioned to address the issue of minimum in-work wages as the UK Government. And as we have seen, the UK has developed a widely accepted and generally quite effective independent process backed by a political mandate to set minimum wage levels.
None of this, to be sure, should be taken to mean that Sainsbury's should absolve itself from responsibility for thoughtfully considering the level of fair pay for workers and contractors. The Living Wage provides a useful and relevant framework for this purpose. Investors should continue to engage with Sainsbury's to understand how they are ensuring the well-being of their employees and monitoring conditions in supply chains. But the case is not made for investors to force upon the board a particular course of action on pay.
Finally, I am by no means suggesting that shareholders and companies be given a free pass on ESG. I've used the example of deforestation to show how the principles can lead to the conclusion that investors should support an ESG-related resolution. But shareholders don't have unlimited capacity to engage companies on ESG issues; they must focus their energies and efforts where they can achieve the most effective outcomes and where there is most bang for their buck. Living Wage accreditation in the UK doesn't meet this test. And so the overwhelming majority of shareholders were right to follow Schroders in voting against the resolution at Sainsbury's AGM in July 2022.