财政、土地和劳工

IF 2.9 2区 经济学 Q2 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES
Samuel Frederico, Stefan Ouma, Emily Duncan, Carla Gras
{"title":"财政、土地和劳工","authors":"Samuel Frederico,&nbsp;Stefan Ouma,&nbsp;Emily Duncan,&nbsp;Carla Gras","doi":"10.1111/joac.70038","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>The dynamics of contemporary capitalism have empowered the role and influence of finance within the realm of agriculture. In response, agri-finance research has focused on the extension of global finance's investment chains and how parts of the agricultural sector—mainly farmland—are transformed into financial assets, where multiple sources of capital seek to make gains. To do so, scholarship on ‘finance going farming’ has directed attention to the variety of financial actors (i.e., pension, endowment and private equity funds, insurance companies and investment banks); their motives to invest; the variegated mechanisms deployed to reformat farmland and agricultural production for financial purposes; and the increasing power of shareholders to shape productive and distributive decisions. While this literature has advanced our understanding of how finance makes its way into agriculture, within agrarian studies, these processes and dynamics raise important conceptual and methodological challenges about how to centre financialization in dynamics of agrarian change. In this exchange, our contributors consider how contemporary trends in agri-finance demand us to rethink relations of production, property and power and processes of accumulation. Key questions that the forum addresses include how and to what extent is finance connected to the restructuring of capital and its modalities of accumulation in agrarian settings? What ties does financialization have to changes in labour regimes? How does it affect productive capital and its associated relations of power? This Forum is part of the 25th Anniversary Forums<sup>1</sup>, following ‘How is climate change changing agrarian studies?’ (Paprocki et al. <span>2025</span>), ‘Challenging agroecology—Promise and pitfalls for agrarian studies’ (McKay et al. <span>2025</span>) and ‘What is the value of value for agrarian studies’ (Akram-Lodhi et al. <span>2025</span>).</p><p>The growing hegemony of finance has been reshaping the mechanisms through which land and nature are appropriated. In global agriculture, institutional investors—such as pension funds, insurance companies, private equity firms and sovereign wealth funds—have become central actors in reorganizing the circuits of accumulation by shifting the focus from production to asset valorization and the extraction of territorialized rents (Cotula <span>2012</span>; Isakson <span>2014</span>; Clapp and Isakson <span>2018</span>). This text contributes to the debate by examining how land is increasingly treated as a financial asset through the articulation of rentier and speculative logics, suggesting that asset managers play a pivotal role as strategic intermediaries who coordinate investment flows, mediate relationships between financial investors and local actors, and embed financial rationalities into the operational logic of farming enterprises (Clapp and Isakson <span>2018</span>).</p><p>Although often grouped under the label of ‘financial capital’, institutional investors differ considerably in their profiles, time horizons and modes of territorialization (Knuth <span>2015</span>; Ouma <span>2020</span>). Among them, asset management firms have emerged as key protagonists in the financialization of the global economy (Christophers <span>2023</span>). Acting as intermediaries, managing pooled resources from pension funds, insurance companies, endowments and high-net-worth individuals, they allocate capital across asset classes to maximize returns, shaping global investment flows and corporate strategies in the agrifood sector.</p><p>These dynamics operate through complex trans-scalar arrangements that obscure ownership structures and hinder legal accountability. The ‘architecture of invisibility’ shields asset managers from the social and environmental consequences of their investments, impeding the identification of both investors and land assets. At the same time, such arrangements reveal that financialization is neither de-territorialized nor purely abstract, but materializes through specific actors, institutions and territorial configurations. To address these transformations, this intervention analyzes (1) the conversion of land into a financial asset and its implications for property relations; (2) the role of asset managers in the trans-scalar governance of farmland, coordinating capital flows and shaping land markets through financial rationalities; and (3) the architecture of invisibility and trans-scalar arrangements that conceal ownership patterns while facilitating the incorporation of peripheral territories into global circuits of capital accumulation.</p><p>Almost 15 years have passed since Tania Li's seminal paper, ‘Situating Labour in the Land Grab Debate’ (Li <span>2011</span>), was published. With over 1,200 citations on Google Scholar, one might expect us to have arrived at a profound understanding of the impact of the global land grab on labour regimes and capital–agricultural labour relations across diverse geographies.</p><p>From a broader perspective, the answer to that expectation is ‘yes’. Indeed, a growing body of literature has examined how large-scale investments in agriculture reshape the spheres of production, reproduction and agricultural labour markets at large. This often includes contract-farming arrangements, where these spheres are closely intertwined, as household labour is frequently mobilized—often in cheapened or unpaid forms—to subsidize contract-based agricultural production.</p><p>However, once we centre finance in a more substantial way by looking into financialized farmland or agricultural operations—something Li did not do in her seminal paper—‘labour’ still remains a lacunae. Major empirical works on capital placements in agriculture,<sup>4</sup> such as Fairbairn (<span>2020</span>), Dixon (<span>2023</span>), Langford (<span>2023</span>) and my own (Ouma <span>2020</span>), say very little about labour, class relations and labour struggles (for a constructive critique of this, see also Sturman <span>2024</span>). Cochet's (<span>2018</span>) work on the labour-value nexus in large-scale farming is one of the few major contributions on the topic, yet it has received only 27 citations since its publication. Assuming that large-scale agriculture is defined by a separation of capital and labour, unlike the ‘family farm’, the Cochet's paper focuses on different types of large-scale farming in Ecuador, Ethiopia, Ukraine and South Africa, in order to ‘study the way value added is distributed in order to compare the shares going to labour compensation, capital (investors and financial institutions …) and other actors (rental payments for land, taxes or duties paid to the state)’ (ibid.: 18). Although it is not solely focused on cases where agricultural investment funds drive the expansion of large-scale farming, it is still a useful piece due to its ambition to quantify how value is distributed between capital and labour.</p><p>At the same time, empirical and research-related developments have further complicated the labour question, requiring us to acknowledge the multiple ways to think through the finance-land-labour nexus. In this intervention, I will argue that the financialization of farmland and agricultural production can be connected to labour issues in at least six promising ways. During this, I will stick to my own line of research: the placement of equity capital in production. That said, finance's penetration of agriculture also includes the classic vehicle of ‘credit’ (Green <span>1987</span>; Le Heron <span>1991</span>; Green <span>2022</span>) as well as other stages of the agricultural value chain (Clapp and Isakson <span>2018</span>; Burch and Lawrence <span>2013</span>).</p><p>The first approach discussed here follows on from Li's (<span>2011</span>) original work. This approach directs our attention towards the dynamics of inclusion and exclusion arising from the large-scale placement of capital in agriculture. What labour relations and practices are established on assetized farms? What racialized, gendered and classed legacies do these rely on? How do these arrangements differ from those on farms run as plantations or large-family farms with a long-term farming intention, where rentierism and speculation play less of a role? How do such placements shape labour markets over longer periods of time? In my own research, I demonstrated that investors targeting farms in Aotearoa New Zealand did not need to develop new methods of labour exploitation. Instead, they could build upon three decades of market liberalisation and ‘farm professionalization’, which resulted in the development of a flexible labour market system (Stringer <span>2016</span>). This system often relied on South/Southeast Asian or Pacific Islander workers, who were hired through labour market intermediaries, as seen in the dairy industry. Alternatively, farms could utilize external contractors, or ‘teams for hire’, for specific services, as observed in the fruit industry.</p><p>However, what farm managers and investors pressured by the drive for shareholder value do is think more deeply about labour incentivization and monitoring. This results in a practice that I call ‘dashboard farming’ (Ouma <span>2020</span>, 141). For instance, the Map of Agriculture project<sup>5</sup> emerged from the desire of a New Zealand agri-focused asset manager to create a ‘Bloomberg for agriculture’ so that both the scouting for farms and their management become better aligned with the data-centred work of institutional investors and asset managers.</p><p>This insight comes with two caveats. First, given the wide variety of investment geographies, these findings cannot easily be generalized, and we must always consider the finance capital-labour nexus within its specific historical and geographical context. Secondly, critics might argue that finance underpins <i>all</i> investments in agriculture, whether they are classified as ordinary, so-called strategic agribusiness investments (e.g., Del Monte opening a new pineapple farm), or as instances of assetization, where new players target agriculture solely for the purpose of asset creation. From this perspective, the emerging literature on large-scale land grabs addressing labour issues might be considered a step in the right direction. Indeed, there are cases where both logics cannot be easily separated (Cochet <span>2018</span>). However, we need to operate more carefully and adopt a distinction between the logic of investment—which might shape classical agribusiness decisions—and that of capital placements (see <i>endnote 4</i>), where financiers acquire an asset with the explicit intention of speculation and rent-seeking over a relatively short period of time. We need more research that accounts for this distinct logic and thus examines in detail the impact of a focus on financial objectives, metrics and narratives on on-farm labour relations and labour markets, and the mechanisms through which this occurs. At the same time, we need to consider the exclusionary dynamics induced by large-scale capital placements in farmland in particular. What happens to farmers (as well as fisher folk, hunters, beekeepers, nut collectors and pastoralists, for example) who have been dispossessed and displaced by such placements? What happens to the domain of reproductive labour, as is brilliantly illustrated in great empirical detail in Chung's work on Tanzania (Chung <span>2024</span>)? Although we have seen a lot of good work published in this field in recent years, this work has usually not built a more solid bridge between inclusion–exclusion dynamics and the fundamental logics of capital markets.</p><p>A second way of thinking about the relationship between finance, land and labour is to prioritize social reproduction, which, as of more recently, has become a more central concern in the land grab debate and critical agrarian studies at large (Chung <span>2017</span>; Ossome <span>2022</span>; Shattuck et al. <span>2023</span>; Wolford <span>2021</span>; see also the contribution of Alessandra Mezzadri to this first instalment of this forum). However, it needs to be more explicitly tied to the question of how financialization/assetization dynamics reshape the land–social reproduction nexus. Social reproduction becomes relevant in relation to female farm (or factory) workers, raising the question of how corporate financialization logics shape their lived experiences at the intersection of wage and the household sphere. However, it could also be extended to include the female spouses and children of farmers who are recruited as cheap labour in contract farming, as demonstrated in our own research (Iddrisu et al. <span>2002</span>), building upon an established tradition that goes back to the heydays of the modes of production debate (Carney <span>1988</span>). Lastly, finance and social reproduction might be connected via the issue of ‘credit’ rather than equity. This is superbly demonstrated by Green and Bylander (<span>2021</span>) in their work on microfinance, household indebtedness and distress land sales in Laos. Like the realm of production itself, both aspects might be sites of resistance, and the ‘counter-topographies’ (Del Rio <span>2024</span>) emanating from this hold valuable lessons for imagining alternative production and financing methods.</p><p>Some readers of this journal may find the third approach challenging, as it replaces the traditional Marxist category of ‘labour’ with ‘work’. Of course, many Marxists are not opposed to broadening the category of ‘labour’ per se, as evidenced by more recent work on labour as social reproduction or different classes of labour, as shown in this journal (Barbesgaard <span>2025</span>). However, what might raise a few eyebrows is moving away from the exploited classes—the rural working people, broadly speaking—to encompass all the other players involved in turning agriculture into a financial asset, such as fund managers, placement agents, lawyers, valuers, enterprising family farmers and (internationally mobile) farm managers (Langford <span>2023</span>). Examining how these ‘agents of capital’ assemble an agricultural asset through embodied work builds on a praxeological tradition (Boussard <span>2017</span>) that appears to conflict with Marxist concerns (Fine <span>2003</span>; Preda <span>2013</span>). However, adopting the perspective of the ‘micro-founded political economy of the investment chain’ (Braun <span>2016</span>, 6), which links the concrete actions of sense-making subjects to more abstract ‘operations of capital’ (Mezzadra and Neilson <span>2015</span>; Ouma <span>2016</span>), allows us to salvage the best of both worlds. Andrew Ofstehage's (<span>2025</span>) recent book, which focuses on how migrant farmers from the US contribute to the creation of ‘soylandia’ in Brazil, is a great example of this.</p><p>A fourth way to multiply ‘labour’ within the finance-agriculture context is to introduce non-human labour, taking cues from critical animal and multispecies studies. Financiers, or at least the farm managers they employ, often make conscious decisions about which animal breeds or crops to introduce and how to maximize their output. In my own research into assetized farms in Tanzania and Aotearoa New Zealand, I have observed the impact of factors such as different poultry or dairy breeds or the type of clover planted on the rate at which investment capital is recouped. The concept of non-human labour could also be extended to include the work of microorganisms, which further challenges classic Marxist thinking on labour. This could explain why the seminal book on the subject by Besky and Blanchette (<span>2019</span>) has not yet been cited in any contributions to the ‘land grab literature’ (according to Google Scholar). Similarly, Wolford et al.'s (<span>2024</span>) recent stock-taking article cites an impressive 304 papers but does not mention the words ‘animal’ or ‘non-human labour’ once! While there are limits to how much ‘labour’ we can attribute to animals and other non-human organisms (Marxist Education Project <span>2024</span>), it would be beneficial to further explore this connection, particularly in light of rapid technological advances that facilitate the manipulation and control of organisms of various sizes, incorporating them into capitalist systems in increasingly profound ways (Guthman and Fairbairn <span>2024</span>). As we see the further expansion of venture-capital powered platforms and other ‘AG-tech solutions’ (Reisman et al. <span>2025</span>), this also bears the question of how new forms of precision-farming reshape the labouring capacity of animals, microorganisms and nature at large.</p><p>The fifth way to focus on labour in the context of our debate relates to the long-standing interest of those working on the agrarian question. Might capitalist technological progress render certain forms of labour obsolete? Examples of this include the replacement of manual tasks such as milking and cleaning stalls by robots and the replacement of the cognitive work of farm managers and workers by data-collecting tractors and drones. In certain parts of the world, digital technologies and processes of automation are beginning to reshape the domain of agricultural production and its pre- and post-stages to such extents that the classic Mann–Dickinson thesis, which claimed that agriculture cannot be fully subsumed to capitalist logics because of its metabolism and dependence on family labour, needs to be revisited (Mann and Dickinson <span>1978</span>). When adopting a financialization and assetization optic, new empirical avenues emerge. Financiers tend to prefer lean corporate structures. Reducing capital-intensive costs can improve the appearance of assets on the balance sheet. Similarly, cutting back on human labour, which requires wages and benefits such as health insurance and pension payments and may organize collectively, can also enhance an asset's value. Digital technologies can aid these processes. For example, capital cost expenditure can be closely monitored through dashboards, and production processes can be automated (Rotz et al. <span>2019</span>).</p><p>Lastly, we can problematize labour itself as a source of capital that ultimately finds its way into agriculture. This brings us to Mr and Mrs Scheper, two retired German doctors whom I mention in the epilogue of my book. In 2018, they discovered that their retirement provider, the medical chamber of a German state, had invested in a TIAA-CREF fund in Brazil. In the United States, the institution now simply known as TIAA serves teachers, professors and other professionals as a retirement providers. The said fund had been accused of gross social and environmental misconduct (Schwab <span>2018</span>). As I wrote, ‘Having supported indigenous struggles in Brazil for decades and having personal experience in the field, the Schepers were particularly shocked at what had seemingly happened to their retirement savings’ (Ouma <span>2020</span>, 181). The Schepers' experience highlights an uncomfortable question: Where does all the interest-bearing capital flowing into agriculture come from? While the very rich and ultra-wealthy certainly have a stake in this (Bill Gates is currently the largest private farmland owner in the United States!), a significant proportion of this originates from pension funds centred on the working and middle classes. By 2023, an astonishing 960 active funds had specialized in food and agricultural assets (Seufert et al. <span>2025</span>, 15), managing over US$150 billion in future pensions for workers in countries with capital market-based retirement systems. While the Schepers are not workers in the strict sense of the word, they are still representative of what I have termed the ‘global return society’—a global socio-material formation in which the reproduction of the better-off people of the Global North (and increasingly the Global South) is tied to the reproduction of finance capital, both ‘at home’ and ‘abroad’ (Ouma <span>2020</span>, 135; see also Parfitt <span>2018</span>, for an insightful article). The role of pension funds in the financialization/assetization of agriculture and the underlying politics of reproducing imperial lifestyles of a certain class of labour within transnational ‘value relations’ (Araghi <span>2003</span>) has received little attention from scholars.</p><p>I hope scholars of critical agrarian studies find these reflections useful, and the finance-land-labour nexus will move to the centre of debates for the years to come. Placing labour at the finance-land nexus is not a straightforward affair, as there are multiple entry points for framing the ‘labour question’ in this context.</p><p><b>Acknowledgements</b></p><p>I thank Carla Gras, Youjin Chung and Sara Hayyat for their comments on earlier versions of this paper.</p><p>The finance, land and labour nexus continues to form new assemblages and shift over time. To this mix, we must increasingly add digital technologies as a key element of transformation. Digital agriculture is rapidly changing the ways in which farmland is acquired, managed and turned into a financial asset. These tools are used to make land, labour and production more legible and more visible to a range of agrifood actors, leading to new forms of governance. In this contribution, I examine the growing interconnections between the assetization of land and digital technologies (and their associated data). In turn, I relate these evolving trends to the question of labour, asking: How does the use of new digital tools in assetized and non-assetized contexts affect the nature of agricultural labour?</p><p>In considering how to conceptualize the critical role of technology in new forms of accumulation and the changing dynamics of financialization, I examine the coupling of platform capitalism and surveillance capitalism in agriculture. As we continue to theorize about the power of digital technologies to restructure production, ownership and related material relations, there is a need to apply these concepts to the agrarian questions of land and labour. Studies have demonstrated the ways in which these technologies and their associated data are reinforcing corporate power and reshaping agricultural knowledge production, but little work to date has been done to extend the analysis to the assetization of land and changes in labour regimes. I suggest that emerging forms of agrarian platform and surveillance capitalism—with attention to global forces, such as climate change, and regional differences—are key to understanding contemporary processes of agrarian change.</p><p>The contributions to this Forum provide valuable insight for centering finance within agrarian change. They do this by offering grounds to analyse four interrelated processes: (1) the distinct logic of the assetization of farmland and agricultural operations; (2) the variety of property structures to control land and other elements of agricultural production; (3) the mutually reinforcing ties between assetization, digital technologies and the development of new sites for financial investment in the agricultural sector (i.e., the creation of monetized exchanges involving data and expert knowledge, giving place for new types of service-provision); and (4) the impacts on the demand for labour and labour relations driven by shareholder value. To connect the above contributions with a broader analysis of agrarian change, I synthesize these collective insights with Bernstein's key questions of agrarian political economy (see Bernstein <span>2010</span>).</p>","PeriodicalId":47678,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Agrarian Change","volume":"25 4","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":2.9000,"publicationDate":"2025-09-15","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/joac.70038","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Finance, Land and Labour\",\"authors\":\"Samuel Frederico,&nbsp;Stefan Ouma,&nbsp;Emily Duncan,&nbsp;Carla Gras\",\"doi\":\"10.1111/joac.70038\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p>The dynamics of contemporary capitalism have empowered the role and influence of finance within the realm of agriculture. In response, agri-finance research has focused on the extension of global finance's investment chains and how parts of the agricultural sector—mainly farmland—are transformed into financial assets, where multiple sources of capital seek to make gains. To do so, scholarship on ‘finance going farming’ has directed attention to the variety of financial actors (i.e., pension, endowment and private equity funds, insurance companies and investment banks); their motives to invest; the variegated mechanisms deployed to reformat farmland and agricultural production for financial purposes; and the increasing power of shareholders to shape productive and distributive decisions. While this literature has advanced our understanding of how finance makes its way into agriculture, within agrarian studies, these processes and dynamics raise important conceptual and methodological challenges about how to centre financialization in dynamics of agrarian change. In this exchange, our contributors consider how contemporary trends in agri-finance demand us to rethink relations of production, property and power and processes of accumulation. Key questions that the forum addresses include how and to what extent is finance connected to the restructuring of capital and its modalities of accumulation in agrarian settings? What ties does financialization have to changes in labour regimes? How does it affect productive capital and its associated relations of power? This Forum is part of the 25th Anniversary Forums<sup>1</sup>, following ‘How is climate change changing agrarian studies?’ (Paprocki et al. <span>2025</span>), ‘Challenging agroecology—Promise and pitfalls for agrarian studies’ (McKay et al. <span>2025</span>) and ‘What is the value of value for agrarian studies’ (Akram-Lodhi et al. <span>2025</span>).</p><p>The growing hegemony of finance has been reshaping the mechanisms through which land and nature are appropriated. In global agriculture, institutional investors—such as pension funds, insurance companies, private equity firms and sovereign wealth funds—have become central actors in reorganizing the circuits of accumulation by shifting the focus from production to asset valorization and the extraction of territorialized rents (Cotula <span>2012</span>; Isakson <span>2014</span>; Clapp and Isakson <span>2018</span>). This text contributes to the debate by examining how land is increasingly treated as a financial asset through the articulation of rentier and speculative logics, suggesting that asset managers play a pivotal role as strategic intermediaries who coordinate investment flows, mediate relationships between financial investors and local actors, and embed financial rationalities into the operational logic of farming enterprises (Clapp and Isakson <span>2018</span>).</p><p>Although often grouped under the label of ‘financial capital’, institutional investors differ considerably in their profiles, time horizons and modes of territorialization (Knuth <span>2015</span>; Ouma <span>2020</span>). Among them, asset management firms have emerged as key protagonists in the financialization of the global economy (Christophers <span>2023</span>). Acting as intermediaries, managing pooled resources from pension funds, insurance companies, endowments and high-net-worth individuals, they allocate capital across asset classes to maximize returns, shaping global investment flows and corporate strategies in the agrifood sector.</p><p>These dynamics operate through complex trans-scalar arrangements that obscure ownership structures and hinder legal accountability. The ‘architecture of invisibility’ shields asset managers from the social and environmental consequences of their investments, impeding the identification of both investors and land assets. At the same time, such arrangements reveal that financialization is neither de-territorialized nor purely abstract, but materializes through specific actors, institutions and territorial configurations. To address these transformations, this intervention analyzes (1) the conversion of land into a financial asset and its implications for property relations; (2) the role of asset managers in the trans-scalar governance of farmland, coordinating capital flows and shaping land markets through financial rationalities; and (3) the architecture of invisibility and trans-scalar arrangements that conceal ownership patterns while facilitating the incorporation of peripheral territories into global circuits of capital accumulation.</p><p>Almost 15 years have passed since Tania Li's seminal paper, ‘Situating Labour in the Land Grab Debate’ (Li <span>2011</span>), was published. With over 1,200 citations on Google Scholar, one might expect us to have arrived at a profound understanding of the impact of the global land grab on labour regimes and capital–agricultural labour relations across diverse geographies.</p><p>From a broader perspective, the answer to that expectation is ‘yes’. Indeed, a growing body of literature has examined how large-scale investments in agriculture reshape the spheres of production, reproduction and agricultural labour markets at large. This often includes contract-farming arrangements, where these spheres are closely intertwined, as household labour is frequently mobilized—often in cheapened or unpaid forms—to subsidize contract-based agricultural production.</p><p>However, once we centre finance in a more substantial way by looking into financialized farmland or agricultural operations—something Li did not do in her seminal paper—‘labour’ still remains a lacunae. Major empirical works on capital placements in agriculture,<sup>4</sup> such as Fairbairn (<span>2020</span>), Dixon (<span>2023</span>), Langford (<span>2023</span>) and my own (Ouma <span>2020</span>), say very little about labour, class relations and labour struggles (for a constructive critique of this, see also Sturman <span>2024</span>). Cochet's (<span>2018</span>) work on the labour-value nexus in large-scale farming is one of the few major contributions on the topic, yet it has received only 27 citations since its publication. Assuming that large-scale agriculture is defined by a separation of capital and labour, unlike the ‘family farm’, the Cochet's paper focuses on different types of large-scale farming in Ecuador, Ethiopia, Ukraine and South Africa, in order to ‘study the way value added is distributed in order to compare the shares going to labour compensation, capital (investors and financial institutions …) and other actors (rental payments for land, taxes or duties paid to the state)’ (ibid.: 18). Although it is not solely focused on cases where agricultural investment funds drive the expansion of large-scale farming, it is still a useful piece due to its ambition to quantify how value is distributed between capital and labour.</p><p>At the same time, empirical and research-related developments have further complicated the labour question, requiring us to acknowledge the multiple ways to think through the finance-land-labour nexus. In this intervention, I will argue that the financialization of farmland and agricultural production can be connected to labour issues in at least six promising ways. During this, I will stick to my own line of research: the placement of equity capital in production. That said, finance's penetration of agriculture also includes the classic vehicle of ‘credit’ (Green <span>1987</span>; Le Heron <span>1991</span>; Green <span>2022</span>) as well as other stages of the agricultural value chain (Clapp and Isakson <span>2018</span>; Burch and Lawrence <span>2013</span>).</p><p>The first approach discussed here follows on from Li's (<span>2011</span>) original work. This approach directs our attention towards the dynamics of inclusion and exclusion arising from the large-scale placement of capital in agriculture. What labour relations and practices are established on assetized farms? What racialized, gendered and classed legacies do these rely on? How do these arrangements differ from those on farms run as plantations or large-family farms with a long-term farming intention, where rentierism and speculation play less of a role? How do such placements shape labour markets over longer periods of time? In my own research, I demonstrated that investors targeting farms in Aotearoa New Zealand did not need to develop new methods of labour exploitation. Instead, they could build upon three decades of market liberalisation and ‘farm professionalization’, which resulted in the development of a flexible labour market system (Stringer <span>2016</span>). This system often relied on South/Southeast Asian or Pacific Islander workers, who were hired through labour market intermediaries, as seen in the dairy industry. Alternatively, farms could utilize external contractors, or ‘teams for hire’, for specific services, as observed in the fruit industry.</p><p>However, what farm managers and investors pressured by the drive for shareholder value do is think more deeply about labour incentivization and monitoring. This results in a practice that I call ‘dashboard farming’ (Ouma <span>2020</span>, 141). For instance, the Map of Agriculture project<sup>5</sup> emerged from the desire of a New Zealand agri-focused asset manager to create a ‘Bloomberg for agriculture’ so that both the scouting for farms and their management become better aligned with the data-centred work of institutional investors and asset managers.</p><p>This insight comes with two caveats. First, given the wide variety of investment geographies, these findings cannot easily be generalized, and we must always consider the finance capital-labour nexus within its specific historical and geographical context. Secondly, critics might argue that finance underpins <i>all</i> investments in agriculture, whether they are classified as ordinary, so-called strategic agribusiness investments (e.g., Del Monte opening a new pineapple farm), or as instances of assetization, where new players target agriculture solely for the purpose of asset creation. From this perspective, the emerging literature on large-scale land grabs addressing labour issues might be considered a step in the right direction. Indeed, there are cases where both logics cannot be easily separated (Cochet <span>2018</span>). However, we need to operate more carefully and adopt a distinction between the logic of investment—which might shape classical agribusiness decisions—and that of capital placements (see <i>endnote 4</i>), where financiers acquire an asset with the explicit intention of speculation and rent-seeking over a relatively short period of time. We need more research that accounts for this distinct logic and thus examines in detail the impact of a focus on financial objectives, metrics and narratives on on-farm labour relations and labour markets, and the mechanisms through which this occurs. At the same time, we need to consider the exclusionary dynamics induced by large-scale capital placements in farmland in particular. What happens to farmers (as well as fisher folk, hunters, beekeepers, nut collectors and pastoralists, for example) who have been dispossessed and displaced by such placements? What happens to the domain of reproductive labour, as is brilliantly illustrated in great empirical detail in Chung's work on Tanzania (Chung <span>2024</span>)? Although we have seen a lot of good work published in this field in recent years, this work has usually not built a more solid bridge between inclusion–exclusion dynamics and the fundamental logics of capital markets.</p><p>A second way of thinking about the relationship between finance, land and labour is to prioritize social reproduction, which, as of more recently, has become a more central concern in the land grab debate and critical agrarian studies at large (Chung <span>2017</span>; Ossome <span>2022</span>; Shattuck et al. <span>2023</span>; Wolford <span>2021</span>; see also the contribution of Alessandra Mezzadri to this first instalment of this forum). However, it needs to be more explicitly tied to the question of how financialization/assetization dynamics reshape the land–social reproduction nexus. Social reproduction becomes relevant in relation to female farm (or factory) workers, raising the question of how corporate financialization logics shape their lived experiences at the intersection of wage and the household sphere. However, it could also be extended to include the female spouses and children of farmers who are recruited as cheap labour in contract farming, as demonstrated in our own research (Iddrisu et al. <span>2002</span>), building upon an established tradition that goes back to the heydays of the modes of production debate (Carney <span>1988</span>). Lastly, finance and social reproduction might be connected via the issue of ‘credit’ rather than equity. This is superbly demonstrated by Green and Bylander (<span>2021</span>) in their work on microfinance, household indebtedness and distress land sales in Laos. Like the realm of production itself, both aspects might be sites of resistance, and the ‘counter-topographies’ (Del Rio <span>2024</span>) emanating from this hold valuable lessons for imagining alternative production and financing methods.</p><p>Some readers of this journal may find the third approach challenging, as it replaces the traditional Marxist category of ‘labour’ with ‘work’. Of course, many Marxists are not opposed to broadening the category of ‘labour’ per se, as evidenced by more recent work on labour as social reproduction or different classes of labour, as shown in this journal (Barbesgaard <span>2025</span>). However, what might raise a few eyebrows is moving away from the exploited classes—the rural working people, broadly speaking—to encompass all the other players involved in turning agriculture into a financial asset, such as fund managers, placement agents, lawyers, valuers, enterprising family farmers and (internationally mobile) farm managers (Langford <span>2023</span>). Examining how these ‘agents of capital’ assemble an agricultural asset through embodied work builds on a praxeological tradition (Boussard <span>2017</span>) that appears to conflict with Marxist concerns (Fine <span>2003</span>; Preda <span>2013</span>). However, adopting the perspective of the ‘micro-founded political economy of the investment chain’ (Braun <span>2016</span>, 6), which links the concrete actions of sense-making subjects to more abstract ‘operations of capital’ (Mezzadra and Neilson <span>2015</span>; Ouma <span>2016</span>), allows us to salvage the best of both worlds. Andrew Ofstehage's (<span>2025</span>) recent book, which focuses on how migrant farmers from the US contribute to the creation of ‘soylandia’ in Brazil, is a great example of this.</p><p>A fourth way to multiply ‘labour’ within the finance-agriculture context is to introduce non-human labour, taking cues from critical animal and multispecies studies. Financiers, or at least the farm managers they employ, often make conscious decisions about which animal breeds or crops to introduce and how to maximize their output. In my own research into assetized farms in Tanzania and Aotearoa New Zealand, I have observed the impact of factors such as different poultry or dairy breeds or the type of clover planted on the rate at which investment capital is recouped. The concept of non-human labour could also be extended to include the work of microorganisms, which further challenges classic Marxist thinking on labour. This could explain why the seminal book on the subject by Besky and Blanchette (<span>2019</span>) has not yet been cited in any contributions to the ‘land grab literature’ (according to Google Scholar). Similarly, Wolford et al.'s (<span>2024</span>) recent stock-taking article cites an impressive 304 papers but does not mention the words ‘animal’ or ‘non-human labour’ once! While there are limits to how much ‘labour’ we can attribute to animals and other non-human organisms (Marxist Education Project <span>2024</span>), it would be beneficial to further explore this connection, particularly in light of rapid technological advances that facilitate the manipulation and control of organisms of various sizes, incorporating them into capitalist systems in increasingly profound ways (Guthman and Fairbairn <span>2024</span>). As we see the further expansion of venture-capital powered platforms and other ‘AG-tech solutions’ (Reisman et al. <span>2025</span>), this also bears the question of how new forms of precision-farming reshape the labouring capacity of animals, microorganisms and nature at large.</p><p>The fifth way to focus on labour in the context of our debate relates to the long-standing interest of those working on the agrarian question. Might capitalist technological progress render certain forms of labour obsolete? Examples of this include the replacement of manual tasks such as milking and cleaning stalls by robots and the replacement of the cognitive work of farm managers and workers by data-collecting tractors and drones. In certain parts of the world, digital technologies and processes of automation are beginning to reshape the domain of agricultural production and its pre- and post-stages to such extents that the classic Mann–Dickinson thesis, which claimed that agriculture cannot be fully subsumed to capitalist logics because of its metabolism and dependence on family labour, needs to be revisited (Mann and Dickinson <span>1978</span>). When adopting a financialization and assetization optic, new empirical avenues emerge. Financiers tend to prefer lean corporate structures. Reducing capital-intensive costs can improve the appearance of assets on the balance sheet. Similarly, cutting back on human labour, which requires wages and benefits such as health insurance and pension payments and may organize collectively, can also enhance an asset's value. Digital technologies can aid these processes. For example, capital cost expenditure can be closely monitored through dashboards, and production processes can be automated (Rotz et al. <span>2019</span>).</p><p>Lastly, we can problematize labour itself as a source of capital that ultimately finds its way into agriculture. This brings us to Mr and Mrs Scheper, two retired German doctors whom I mention in the epilogue of my book. In 2018, they discovered that their retirement provider, the medical chamber of a German state, had invested in a TIAA-CREF fund in Brazil. In the United States, the institution now simply known as TIAA serves teachers, professors and other professionals as a retirement providers. The said fund had been accused of gross social and environmental misconduct (Schwab <span>2018</span>). As I wrote, ‘Having supported indigenous struggles in Brazil for decades and having personal experience in the field, the Schepers were particularly shocked at what had seemingly happened to their retirement savings’ (Ouma <span>2020</span>, 181). The Schepers' experience highlights an uncomfortable question: Where does all the interest-bearing capital flowing into agriculture come from? While the very rich and ultra-wealthy certainly have a stake in this (Bill Gates is currently the largest private farmland owner in the United States!), a significant proportion of this originates from pension funds centred on the working and middle classes. By 2023, an astonishing 960 active funds had specialized in food and agricultural assets (Seufert et al. <span>2025</span>, 15), managing over US$150 billion in future pensions for workers in countries with capital market-based retirement systems. While the Schepers are not workers in the strict sense of the word, they are still representative of what I have termed the ‘global return society’—a global socio-material formation in which the reproduction of the better-off people of the Global North (and increasingly the Global South) is tied to the reproduction of finance capital, both ‘at home’ and ‘abroad’ (Ouma <span>2020</span>, 135; see also Parfitt <span>2018</span>, for an insightful article). The role of pension funds in the financialization/assetization of agriculture and the underlying politics of reproducing imperial lifestyles of a certain class of labour within transnational ‘value relations’ (Araghi <span>2003</span>) has received little attention from scholars.</p><p>I hope scholars of critical agrarian studies find these reflections useful, and the finance-land-labour nexus will move to the centre of debates for the years to come. Placing labour at the finance-land nexus is not a straightforward affair, as there are multiple entry points for framing the ‘labour question’ in this context.</p><p><b>Acknowledgements</b></p><p>I thank Carla Gras, Youjin Chung and Sara Hayyat for their comments on earlier versions of this paper.</p><p>The finance, land and labour nexus continues to form new assemblages and shift over time. To this mix, we must increasingly add digital technologies as a key element of transformation. Digital agriculture is rapidly changing the ways in which farmland is acquired, managed and turned into a financial asset. These tools are used to make land, labour and production more legible and more visible to a range of agrifood actors, leading to new forms of governance. In this contribution, I examine the growing interconnections between the assetization of land and digital technologies (and their associated data). In turn, I relate these evolving trends to the question of labour, asking: How does the use of new digital tools in assetized and non-assetized contexts affect the nature of agricultural labour?</p><p>In considering how to conceptualize the critical role of technology in new forms of accumulation and the changing dynamics of financialization, I examine the coupling of platform capitalism and surveillance capitalism in agriculture. As we continue to theorize about the power of digital technologies to restructure production, ownership and related material relations, there is a need to apply these concepts to the agrarian questions of land and labour. Studies have demonstrated the ways in which these technologies and their associated data are reinforcing corporate power and reshaping agricultural knowledge production, but little work to date has been done to extend the analysis to the assetization of land and changes in labour regimes. I suggest that emerging forms of agrarian platform and surveillance capitalism—with attention to global forces, such as climate change, and regional differences—are key to understanding contemporary processes of agrarian change.</p><p>The contributions to this Forum provide valuable insight for centering finance within agrarian change. They do this by offering grounds to analyse four interrelated processes: (1) the distinct logic of the assetization of farmland and agricultural operations; (2) the variety of property structures to control land and other elements of agricultural production; (3) the mutually reinforcing ties between assetization, digital technologies and the development of new sites for financial investment in the agricultural sector (i.e., the creation of monetized exchanges involving data and expert knowledge, giving place for new types of service-provision); and (4) the impacts on the demand for labour and labour relations driven by shareholder value. To connect the above contributions with a broader analysis of agrarian change, I synthesize these collective insights with Bernstein's key questions of agrarian political economy (see Bernstein <span>2010</span>).</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":47678,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Journal of Agrarian Change\",\"volume\":\"25 4\",\"pages\":\"\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":2.9000,\"publicationDate\":\"2025-09-15\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/joac.70038\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Journal of Agrarian Change\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"96\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/joac.70038\",\"RegionNum\":2,\"RegionCategory\":\"经济学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q2\",\"JCRName\":\"DEVELOPMENT STUDIES\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of Agrarian Change","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/joac.70038","RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"DEVELOPMENT STUDIES","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

事实上,越来越多的文献研究了大规模农业投资如何重塑生产、再生产和整个农业劳动力市场领域。这通常包括合同农业安排,这些领域紧密交织在一起,因为家庭劳动力经常以廉价或无偿的形式被动员起来,以补贴基于合同的农业生产。然而,一旦我们通过考察金融化的农田或农业经营——李在她的开创性论文中没有这样做——以更实质性的方式将金融集中起来,“劳动”仍然是一个空白。关于农业资本配置的主要实证著作,如Fairbairn(2020)、Dixon(2023)、Langford(2023)和我自己的(Ouma 2020),很少提到劳工、阶级关系和劳工斗争(关于对此的建设性批评,请参见Sturman 2024)。Cochet(2018)关于大规模农业中劳动力价值关系的研究是该主题为数不多的主要贡献之一,但自发表以来仅被引用27次。假设大规模农业的定义是资本和劳动力的分离,与“家庭农场”不同,Cochet的论文将重点放在厄瓜多尔、埃塞俄比亚、乌克兰和南非不同类型的大规模农业上,以“研究附加值的分配方式,以比较劳动力补偿、资本(投资者和金融机构……)和其他参与者(支付土地租金、税收或向国家缴纳的关税)的份额”(同上:18)。尽管它并不仅仅关注农业投资基金推动大规模农业扩张的案例,但它仍然是一篇有用的文章,因为它的目标是量化价值如何在资本和劳动力之间分配。与此同时,实证和相关研究的发展使劳动力问题进一步复杂化,要求我们承认通过财政-土地-劳动力关系思考的多种方式。在本文中,我将论证农田和农业生产的金融化可以以至少六种有希望的方式与劳工问题联系起来。在此期间,我将坚持自己的研究方向:股权资本在生产中的安置。也就是说,金融对农业的渗透还包括“信贷”这一经典工具(Green 1987; Le Heron 1991; Green 2022)以及农业价值链的其他阶段(Clapp and Isakson 2018; Burch and Lawrence 2013)。这里讨论的第一种方法是继李(2011)的原创作品之后。这种方法将我们的注意力引向农业大规模资本投放所产生的包容和排斥的动态。在资产化农场建立了什么样的劳动关系和做法?这些依赖于什么种族化、性别化和阶级化的遗产?这些安排与那些作为种植园经营的农场或具有长期经营意图的大型家庭农场有何不同?在这些农场中,食利主义和投机的作用较小。在较长一段时间内,这种安置如何塑造劳动力市场?在我自己的研究中,我证明了以新西兰奥特罗阿农场为目标的投资者不需要开发新的劳动力剥削方法。相反,它们可以建立在三十年的市场自由化和“农业专业化”的基础上,这导致了灵活的劳动力市场体系的发展(Stringer 2016)。这一制度往往依赖于南亚/东南亚或太平洋岛民工人,他们是通过劳动力市场中介机构雇用的,如在乳制品行业所见。另外,农场可以利用外部承包商或“雇佣团队”提供特定服务,正如水果行业所观察到的那样。然而,在股东价值驱动的压力下,农场经理和投资者所做的是更深入地思考劳动力激励和监督问题。这导致了我称之为“仪表盘农业”的实践(Ouma 2020, 141)。例如,农业地图项目源于新西兰一家专注于农业的资产管理公司的愿望,该公司希望创建一个“农业彭博”,以便农场的寻找和管理与机构投资者和资产管理公司以数据为中心的工作更好地结合起来。这种见解需要注意两点。首先,考虑到投资地域的多样性,这些发现不能轻易概括,我们必须始终在其特定的历史和地理背景下考虑金融资本-劳动关系。其次,批评者可能会认为,金融是所有农业投资的基础,无论这些投资是被归类为普通的、所谓的战略性农业综合企业投资(例如,德尔蒙特公司开设了一个新的菠萝农场),还是作为资产化的例子,新参与者仅仅为了创造资产而瞄准农业。 从这个角度来看,关于解决劳工问题的大规模土地掠夺的新兴文献可能被认为是朝着正确方向迈出的一步。事实上,在某些情况下,这两种逻辑不能轻易分开(Cochet 2018)。然而,我们需要更加谨慎地操作,并在投资逻辑(这可能会影响传统农业企业的决策)和资本配置逻辑(见尾注4)之间采取区别,在资本配置逻辑中,金融家收购资产的明确意图是在相对较短的时间内投机和寻租。我们需要更多的研究来解释这种独特的逻辑,从而详细检查关注财务目标、指标和对农场劳动关系和劳动力市场的叙述的影响,以及发生这种情况的机制。与此同时,我们还需要考虑大规模资本配置(尤其是农田)所引发的排他性动力。农民(以及渔民、猎人、养蜂人、坚果采集者和牧民等)因这种安置而被剥夺财产和流离失所,他们会怎么样?繁殖劳动领域发生了什么,正如Chung关于坦桑尼亚的工作(Chung 2024)中出色的经验细节所说明的那样?尽管近年来我们在这一领域发表了许多优秀的研究成果,但这些工作通常没有在包容-排斥动态和资本市场的基本逻辑之间建立更坚实的桥梁。思考金融、土地和劳动力之间关系的第二种方式是优先考虑社会再生产,最近,社会再生产已成为土地掠夺辩论和重要农业研究的核心问题(Chung 2017; Ossome 2022; Shattuck et al. 2023; Wolford 2021;另见Alessandra Mezzadri对本论坛第一部分的贡献)。然而,它需要更明确地与金融化/资产化动态如何重塑土地-社会再生产关系的问题联系起来。社会再生产与女性农场(或工厂)工人相关,提出了企业金融化逻辑如何在工资和家庭领域的交叉点塑造她们的生活经验的问题。然而,正如我们自己的研究(Iddrisu et al. 2002)所证明的那样,它也可以扩展到包括在合同农业中被招募为廉价劳动力的农民的女性配偶和子女,建立在可以追溯到生产模式辩论全盛期的既定传统之上(Carney 1988)。最后,金融和社会再生产可能通过发行“信贷”而不是股权来联系起来。Green和Bylander(2021)在他们关于老挝小额信贷、家庭负债和不良土地出售的研究中很好地证明了这一点。就像生产领域本身一样,这两个方面都可能是抵抗的场所,由此产生的“反地形”(Del里约热内卢2024)为想象替代生产和融资方法提供了宝贵的经验。本杂志的一些读者可能会发现第三种方法具有挑战性,因为它用“工作”取代了传统的马克思主义“劳动”范畴。当然,许多马克思主义者并不反对扩大“劳动”本身的范畴,正如本刊(Barbesgaard 2025)所示,最近关于劳动作为社会再生产或不同阶级劳动的研究证明了这一点。然而,可能会引起一些人的注意的是,从被剥削阶级——广义上讲,农村劳动人民——转向包括所有其他参与将农业转化为金融资产的参与者,如基金经理、安置代理人、律师、估价师、有进取心的家庭农民和(国际流动的)农场经理(Langford 2023)。研究这些“资本代理人”如何通过具体化的工作来组装农业资产,建立在行动学传统(Boussard 2017)的基础上,这似乎与马克思主义的关注(Fine 2003; Preda 2013)相冲突。然而,采用“投资链的微观政治经济学”(Braun 2016, 6)的观点,将意义建构主体的具体行为与更抽象的“资本运作”(Mezzadra and Neilson 2015; Ouma 2016)联系起来,使我们能够两全美。安德鲁·奥夫斯特赫奇(Andrew Ofstehage, 2025)最近的一本书就是一个很好的例子,该书关注的是来自美国的移民农民如何为巴西“大豆国”的创建做出贡献。在金融农业背景下增加“劳动力”的第四种方法是引入非人类劳动力,从重要的动物和多物种研究中获得线索。金融家,或者至少是他们雇佣的农场管理者,通常会有意识地决定要引进哪些动物品种或作物,以及如何最大限度地提高产量。 在我自己对坦桑尼亚和新西兰Aotearoa的资产化农场的研究中,我观察到各种因素的影响,如不同的家禽或乳制品品种,或种植的三叶草类型,对投资资本回收率的影响。非人类劳动的概念也可以扩展到包括微生物的工作,这进一步挑战了经典的马克思主义劳动思想。这可以解释为什么贝斯基和布兰切特(2019)关于这一主题的开创性著作尚未被引用到“土地掠夺文学”的任何贡献中(根据谷歌Scholar)。同样,Wolford等人(2024)最近的盘点文章引用了令人印象深刻的304篇论文,但一次也没有提到“动物”或“非人类劳动”这个词!虽然我们可以将多少“劳动”归因于动物和其他非人类生物体(马克思主义教育计划2024)是有限的,但进一步探索这种联系将是有益的,特别是考虑到快速的技术进步,促进了对各种大小生物体的操纵和控制,并以越来越深刻的方式将它们纳入资本主义制度(Guthman和Fairbairn 2024)。当我们看到风险资本驱动的平台和其他“农业技术解决方案”的进一步扩张时(Reisman et al. 2025),这也带来了新形式的精准农业如何重塑动物、微生物和大自然的劳动能力的问题。在我们辩论的背景下关注劳工的第五种方式涉及那些致力于农业问题的人的长期利益。资本主义的技术进步会使某些劳动形式过时吗?这方面的例子包括用机器人取代挤奶和清洁摊位等手工任务,以及用数据收集拖拉机和无人机取代农场经理和工人的认知工作。在世界上的某些地区,数字技术和自动化过程正开始重塑农业生产领域及其前后阶段,以至于需要重新审视经典的曼-狄金森论文(Mann - Dickinson thesis),该论文声称,由于农业的新陈代谢和对家庭劳动力的依赖,农业不能完全归入资本主义逻辑(Mann and Dickinson 1978)。当采用金融化和资产化视点时,新的经验途径出现了。金融家往往更喜欢精简的公司结构。降低资本密集型成本可以改善资产负债表上的资产外观。同样,削减需要工资和福利(如医疗保险和养恤金)并可能集体组织的人力劳动也可以提高资产的价值。数字技术可以帮助这些过程。例如,资本成本支出可以通过仪表板密切监控,生产过程可以自动化(Rotz et al. 2019)。最后,我们可以质疑劳动力本身作为最终进入农业的资本来源的问题。这就把我们带到了Scheper先生和夫人,两位退休的德国医生,我在我的书的结语中提到了他们。2018年,他们发现他们的退休提供者——德国一个州的医疗商会——投资了巴西的一个TIAA-CREF基金。在美国,现在简称为TIAA的机构为教师、教授和其他专业人士提供退休服务。该基金被指控存在严重的社会和环境不当行为(Schwab 2018)。正如我所写的,“在巴西支持土著斗争几十年,并在该领域有个人经验,谢珀夫妇对他们的退休储蓄似乎发生了什么感到特别震惊”(Ouma 2020, 181)。谢珀夫妇的经历凸显了一个令人不安的问题:所有流入农业的生息资本都来自哪里?虽然非常富有和超级富有的人肯定在这方面有股份(比尔盖茨目前是美国最大的私人农田所有者!),但其中很大一部分来自以工人和中产阶级为中心的养老基金。到2023年,专门从事食品和农业资产的活跃基金达到了惊人的960只(Seufert et al. 2025, 15),在实行资本市场化退休制度的国家,为工人管理着超过1500亿美元的未来养老金。虽然Schepers不是严格意义上的工人,但他们仍然是我所称的“全球回报社会”的代表,这是一种全球性的社会物质形态,在这种形态中,全球北方(以及越来越多的全球南方)富裕人群的再生产与金融资本的再生产联系在一起,无论是“在国内”还是“在国外”(Ouma 2020, 135;另见Parfitt 2018,一篇有见地的文章)。 养老基金在农业金融化/资产化中的作用,以及在跨国“价值关系”中再现某一劳动阶级的帝国生活方式的潜在政治(Araghi 2003),很少受到学者的关注。我希望批判性农业研究的学者们发现这些反思是有用的,并且财政-土地-劳动力关系将在未来几年成为辩论的中心。将劳动力置于金融与土地的关系中并不是一件简单的事情,因为在这种情况下,构建“劳动力问题”有多个切入点。感谢Carla Gras, Youjin Chung和Sara Hayyat对本文早期版本的评论。金融、土地和劳动力的关系继续形成新的组合,并随着时间的推移而发生变化。在这一组合中,我们必须越来越多地将数字技术作为转型的关键因素。数字农业正在迅速改变农地获取、管理和转化为金融资产的方式。这些工具用于使土地、劳动力和生产对一系列农业食品行为者更清晰、更清晰,从而产生新的治理形式。在这篇文章中,我研究了土地资产化与数字技术(及其相关数据)之间日益增长的相互联系。反过来,我将这些不断发展的趋势与劳动力问题联系起来,提出以下问题:在资产化和非资产化背景下使用新的数字工具如何影响农业劳动力的性质?在考虑如何概念化技术在新形式的积累和金融化动态变化中的关键作用时,我研究了农业中平台资本主义和监督资本主义的耦合。当我们继续理论化数字技术重组生产、所有权和相关物质关系的力量时,有必要将这些概念应用于土地和劳动力的农业问题。研究表明,这些技术及其相关数据正在加强企业权力和重塑农业知识生产,但迄今为止,很少有工作将分析扩展到土地资产化和劳动力制度的变化。我认为新兴形式的农业平台和监视资本主义——关注全球力量,如气候变化和地区差异——是理解当代农业变化过程的关键。对本次论坛的贡献为以农业变化为中心的融资提供了宝贵的见解。为此,他们为分析四个相互关联的过程提供了依据:(1)农田资产化和农业经营的独特逻辑;(2)控制土地和其他农业生产要素的产权结构的多样性;(3)资产化、数字技术与农业部门金融投资新场所的发展之间相互加强的联系(即,创建涉及数据和专业知识的货币化交换,为新型服务提供提供空间);(4)股东价值对劳动需求和劳动关系的影响。为了将上述贡献与对土地变化的更广泛分析联系起来,我将这些集体见解与伯恩斯坦关于农业政治经济学的关键问题综合起来(见Bernstein 2010)。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。

Finance, Land and Labour

Finance, Land and Labour

The dynamics of contemporary capitalism have empowered the role and influence of finance within the realm of agriculture. In response, agri-finance research has focused on the extension of global finance's investment chains and how parts of the agricultural sector—mainly farmland—are transformed into financial assets, where multiple sources of capital seek to make gains. To do so, scholarship on ‘finance going farming’ has directed attention to the variety of financial actors (i.e., pension, endowment and private equity funds, insurance companies and investment banks); their motives to invest; the variegated mechanisms deployed to reformat farmland and agricultural production for financial purposes; and the increasing power of shareholders to shape productive and distributive decisions. While this literature has advanced our understanding of how finance makes its way into agriculture, within agrarian studies, these processes and dynamics raise important conceptual and methodological challenges about how to centre financialization in dynamics of agrarian change. In this exchange, our contributors consider how contemporary trends in agri-finance demand us to rethink relations of production, property and power and processes of accumulation. Key questions that the forum addresses include how and to what extent is finance connected to the restructuring of capital and its modalities of accumulation in agrarian settings? What ties does financialization have to changes in labour regimes? How does it affect productive capital and its associated relations of power? This Forum is part of the 25th Anniversary Forums1, following ‘How is climate change changing agrarian studies?’ (Paprocki et al. 2025), ‘Challenging agroecology—Promise and pitfalls for agrarian studies’ (McKay et al. 2025) and ‘What is the value of value for agrarian studies’ (Akram-Lodhi et al. 2025).

The growing hegemony of finance has been reshaping the mechanisms through which land and nature are appropriated. In global agriculture, institutional investors—such as pension funds, insurance companies, private equity firms and sovereign wealth funds—have become central actors in reorganizing the circuits of accumulation by shifting the focus from production to asset valorization and the extraction of territorialized rents (Cotula 2012; Isakson 2014; Clapp and Isakson 2018). This text contributes to the debate by examining how land is increasingly treated as a financial asset through the articulation of rentier and speculative logics, suggesting that asset managers play a pivotal role as strategic intermediaries who coordinate investment flows, mediate relationships between financial investors and local actors, and embed financial rationalities into the operational logic of farming enterprises (Clapp and Isakson 2018).

Although often grouped under the label of ‘financial capital’, institutional investors differ considerably in their profiles, time horizons and modes of territorialization (Knuth 2015; Ouma 2020). Among them, asset management firms have emerged as key protagonists in the financialization of the global economy (Christophers 2023). Acting as intermediaries, managing pooled resources from pension funds, insurance companies, endowments and high-net-worth individuals, they allocate capital across asset classes to maximize returns, shaping global investment flows and corporate strategies in the agrifood sector.

These dynamics operate through complex trans-scalar arrangements that obscure ownership structures and hinder legal accountability. The ‘architecture of invisibility’ shields asset managers from the social and environmental consequences of their investments, impeding the identification of both investors and land assets. At the same time, such arrangements reveal that financialization is neither de-territorialized nor purely abstract, but materializes through specific actors, institutions and territorial configurations. To address these transformations, this intervention analyzes (1) the conversion of land into a financial asset and its implications for property relations; (2) the role of asset managers in the trans-scalar governance of farmland, coordinating capital flows and shaping land markets through financial rationalities; and (3) the architecture of invisibility and trans-scalar arrangements that conceal ownership patterns while facilitating the incorporation of peripheral territories into global circuits of capital accumulation.

Almost 15 years have passed since Tania Li's seminal paper, ‘Situating Labour in the Land Grab Debate’ (Li 2011), was published. With over 1,200 citations on Google Scholar, one might expect us to have arrived at a profound understanding of the impact of the global land grab on labour regimes and capital–agricultural labour relations across diverse geographies.

From a broader perspective, the answer to that expectation is ‘yes’. Indeed, a growing body of literature has examined how large-scale investments in agriculture reshape the spheres of production, reproduction and agricultural labour markets at large. This often includes contract-farming arrangements, where these spheres are closely intertwined, as household labour is frequently mobilized—often in cheapened or unpaid forms—to subsidize contract-based agricultural production.

However, once we centre finance in a more substantial way by looking into financialized farmland or agricultural operations—something Li did not do in her seminal paper—‘labour’ still remains a lacunae. Major empirical works on capital placements in agriculture,4 such as Fairbairn (2020), Dixon (2023), Langford (2023) and my own (Ouma 2020), say very little about labour, class relations and labour struggles (for a constructive critique of this, see also Sturman 2024). Cochet's (2018) work on the labour-value nexus in large-scale farming is one of the few major contributions on the topic, yet it has received only 27 citations since its publication. Assuming that large-scale agriculture is defined by a separation of capital and labour, unlike the ‘family farm’, the Cochet's paper focuses on different types of large-scale farming in Ecuador, Ethiopia, Ukraine and South Africa, in order to ‘study the way value added is distributed in order to compare the shares going to labour compensation, capital (investors and financial institutions …) and other actors (rental payments for land, taxes or duties paid to the state)’ (ibid.: 18). Although it is not solely focused on cases where agricultural investment funds drive the expansion of large-scale farming, it is still a useful piece due to its ambition to quantify how value is distributed between capital and labour.

At the same time, empirical and research-related developments have further complicated the labour question, requiring us to acknowledge the multiple ways to think through the finance-land-labour nexus. In this intervention, I will argue that the financialization of farmland and agricultural production can be connected to labour issues in at least six promising ways. During this, I will stick to my own line of research: the placement of equity capital in production. That said, finance's penetration of agriculture also includes the classic vehicle of ‘credit’ (Green 1987; Le Heron 1991; Green 2022) as well as other stages of the agricultural value chain (Clapp and Isakson 2018; Burch and Lawrence 2013).

The first approach discussed here follows on from Li's (2011) original work. This approach directs our attention towards the dynamics of inclusion and exclusion arising from the large-scale placement of capital in agriculture. What labour relations and practices are established on assetized farms? What racialized, gendered and classed legacies do these rely on? How do these arrangements differ from those on farms run as plantations or large-family farms with a long-term farming intention, where rentierism and speculation play less of a role? How do such placements shape labour markets over longer periods of time? In my own research, I demonstrated that investors targeting farms in Aotearoa New Zealand did not need to develop new methods of labour exploitation. Instead, they could build upon three decades of market liberalisation and ‘farm professionalization’, which resulted in the development of a flexible labour market system (Stringer 2016). This system often relied on South/Southeast Asian or Pacific Islander workers, who were hired through labour market intermediaries, as seen in the dairy industry. Alternatively, farms could utilize external contractors, or ‘teams for hire’, for specific services, as observed in the fruit industry.

However, what farm managers and investors pressured by the drive for shareholder value do is think more deeply about labour incentivization and monitoring. This results in a practice that I call ‘dashboard farming’ (Ouma 2020, 141). For instance, the Map of Agriculture project5 emerged from the desire of a New Zealand agri-focused asset manager to create a ‘Bloomberg for agriculture’ so that both the scouting for farms and their management become better aligned with the data-centred work of institutional investors and asset managers.

This insight comes with two caveats. First, given the wide variety of investment geographies, these findings cannot easily be generalized, and we must always consider the finance capital-labour nexus within its specific historical and geographical context. Secondly, critics might argue that finance underpins all investments in agriculture, whether they are classified as ordinary, so-called strategic agribusiness investments (e.g., Del Monte opening a new pineapple farm), or as instances of assetization, where new players target agriculture solely for the purpose of asset creation. From this perspective, the emerging literature on large-scale land grabs addressing labour issues might be considered a step in the right direction. Indeed, there are cases where both logics cannot be easily separated (Cochet 2018). However, we need to operate more carefully and adopt a distinction between the logic of investment—which might shape classical agribusiness decisions—and that of capital placements (see endnote 4), where financiers acquire an asset with the explicit intention of speculation and rent-seeking over a relatively short period of time. We need more research that accounts for this distinct logic and thus examines in detail the impact of a focus on financial objectives, metrics and narratives on on-farm labour relations and labour markets, and the mechanisms through which this occurs. At the same time, we need to consider the exclusionary dynamics induced by large-scale capital placements in farmland in particular. What happens to farmers (as well as fisher folk, hunters, beekeepers, nut collectors and pastoralists, for example) who have been dispossessed and displaced by such placements? What happens to the domain of reproductive labour, as is brilliantly illustrated in great empirical detail in Chung's work on Tanzania (Chung 2024)? Although we have seen a lot of good work published in this field in recent years, this work has usually not built a more solid bridge between inclusion–exclusion dynamics and the fundamental logics of capital markets.

A second way of thinking about the relationship between finance, land and labour is to prioritize social reproduction, which, as of more recently, has become a more central concern in the land grab debate and critical agrarian studies at large (Chung 2017; Ossome 2022; Shattuck et al. 2023; Wolford 2021; see also the contribution of Alessandra Mezzadri to this first instalment of this forum). However, it needs to be more explicitly tied to the question of how financialization/assetization dynamics reshape the land–social reproduction nexus. Social reproduction becomes relevant in relation to female farm (or factory) workers, raising the question of how corporate financialization logics shape their lived experiences at the intersection of wage and the household sphere. However, it could also be extended to include the female spouses and children of farmers who are recruited as cheap labour in contract farming, as demonstrated in our own research (Iddrisu et al. 2002), building upon an established tradition that goes back to the heydays of the modes of production debate (Carney 1988). Lastly, finance and social reproduction might be connected via the issue of ‘credit’ rather than equity. This is superbly demonstrated by Green and Bylander (2021) in their work on microfinance, household indebtedness and distress land sales in Laos. Like the realm of production itself, both aspects might be sites of resistance, and the ‘counter-topographies’ (Del Rio 2024) emanating from this hold valuable lessons for imagining alternative production and financing methods.

Some readers of this journal may find the third approach challenging, as it replaces the traditional Marxist category of ‘labour’ with ‘work’. Of course, many Marxists are not opposed to broadening the category of ‘labour’ per se, as evidenced by more recent work on labour as social reproduction or different classes of labour, as shown in this journal (Barbesgaard 2025). However, what might raise a few eyebrows is moving away from the exploited classes—the rural working people, broadly speaking—to encompass all the other players involved in turning agriculture into a financial asset, such as fund managers, placement agents, lawyers, valuers, enterprising family farmers and (internationally mobile) farm managers (Langford 2023). Examining how these ‘agents of capital’ assemble an agricultural asset through embodied work builds on a praxeological tradition (Boussard 2017) that appears to conflict with Marxist concerns (Fine 2003; Preda 2013). However, adopting the perspective of the ‘micro-founded political economy of the investment chain’ (Braun 2016, 6), which links the concrete actions of sense-making subjects to more abstract ‘operations of capital’ (Mezzadra and Neilson 2015; Ouma 2016), allows us to salvage the best of both worlds. Andrew Ofstehage's (2025) recent book, which focuses on how migrant farmers from the US contribute to the creation of ‘soylandia’ in Brazil, is a great example of this.

A fourth way to multiply ‘labour’ within the finance-agriculture context is to introduce non-human labour, taking cues from critical animal and multispecies studies. Financiers, or at least the farm managers they employ, often make conscious decisions about which animal breeds or crops to introduce and how to maximize their output. In my own research into assetized farms in Tanzania and Aotearoa New Zealand, I have observed the impact of factors such as different poultry or dairy breeds or the type of clover planted on the rate at which investment capital is recouped. The concept of non-human labour could also be extended to include the work of microorganisms, which further challenges classic Marxist thinking on labour. This could explain why the seminal book on the subject by Besky and Blanchette (2019) has not yet been cited in any contributions to the ‘land grab literature’ (according to Google Scholar). Similarly, Wolford et al.'s (2024) recent stock-taking article cites an impressive 304 papers but does not mention the words ‘animal’ or ‘non-human labour’ once! While there are limits to how much ‘labour’ we can attribute to animals and other non-human organisms (Marxist Education Project 2024), it would be beneficial to further explore this connection, particularly in light of rapid technological advances that facilitate the manipulation and control of organisms of various sizes, incorporating them into capitalist systems in increasingly profound ways (Guthman and Fairbairn 2024). As we see the further expansion of venture-capital powered platforms and other ‘AG-tech solutions’ (Reisman et al. 2025), this also bears the question of how new forms of precision-farming reshape the labouring capacity of animals, microorganisms and nature at large.

The fifth way to focus on labour in the context of our debate relates to the long-standing interest of those working on the agrarian question. Might capitalist technological progress render certain forms of labour obsolete? Examples of this include the replacement of manual tasks such as milking and cleaning stalls by robots and the replacement of the cognitive work of farm managers and workers by data-collecting tractors and drones. In certain parts of the world, digital technologies and processes of automation are beginning to reshape the domain of agricultural production and its pre- and post-stages to such extents that the classic Mann–Dickinson thesis, which claimed that agriculture cannot be fully subsumed to capitalist logics because of its metabolism and dependence on family labour, needs to be revisited (Mann and Dickinson 1978). When adopting a financialization and assetization optic, new empirical avenues emerge. Financiers tend to prefer lean corporate structures. Reducing capital-intensive costs can improve the appearance of assets on the balance sheet. Similarly, cutting back on human labour, which requires wages and benefits such as health insurance and pension payments and may organize collectively, can also enhance an asset's value. Digital technologies can aid these processes. For example, capital cost expenditure can be closely monitored through dashboards, and production processes can be automated (Rotz et al. 2019).

Lastly, we can problematize labour itself as a source of capital that ultimately finds its way into agriculture. This brings us to Mr and Mrs Scheper, two retired German doctors whom I mention in the epilogue of my book. In 2018, they discovered that their retirement provider, the medical chamber of a German state, had invested in a TIAA-CREF fund in Brazil. In the United States, the institution now simply known as TIAA serves teachers, professors and other professionals as a retirement providers. The said fund had been accused of gross social and environmental misconduct (Schwab 2018). As I wrote, ‘Having supported indigenous struggles in Brazil for decades and having personal experience in the field, the Schepers were particularly shocked at what had seemingly happened to their retirement savings’ (Ouma 2020, 181). The Schepers' experience highlights an uncomfortable question: Where does all the interest-bearing capital flowing into agriculture come from? While the very rich and ultra-wealthy certainly have a stake in this (Bill Gates is currently the largest private farmland owner in the United States!), a significant proportion of this originates from pension funds centred on the working and middle classes. By 2023, an astonishing 960 active funds had specialized in food and agricultural assets (Seufert et al. 2025, 15), managing over US$150 billion in future pensions for workers in countries with capital market-based retirement systems. While the Schepers are not workers in the strict sense of the word, they are still representative of what I have termed the ‘global return society’—a global socio-material formation in which the reproduction of the better-off people of the Global North (and increasingly the Global South) is tied to the reproduction of finance capital, both ‘at home’ and ‘abroad’ (Ouma 2020, 135; see also Parfitt 2018, for an insightful article). The role of pension funds in the financialization/assetization of agriculture and the underlying politics of reproducing imperial lifestyles of a certain class of labour within transnational ‘value relations’ (Araghi 2003) has received little attention from scholars.

I hope scholars of critical agrarian studies find these reflections useful, and the finance-land-labour nexus will move to the centre of debates for the years to come. Placing labour at the finance-land nexus is not a straightforward affair, as there are multiple entry points for framing the ‘labour question’ in this context.

Acknowledgements

I thank Carla Gras, Youjin Chung and Sara Hayyat for their comments on earlier versions of this paper.

The finance, land and labour nexus continues to form new assemblages and shift over time. To this mix, we must increasingly add digital technologies as a key element of transformation. Digital agriculture is rapidly changing the ways in which farmland is acquired, managed and turned into a financial asset. These tools are used to make land, labour and production more legible and more visible to a range of agrifood actors, leading to new forms of governance. In this contribution, I examine the growing interconnections between the assetization of land and digital technologies (and their associated data). In turn, I relate these evolving trends to the question of labour, asking: How does the use of new digital tools in assetized and non-assetized contexts affect the nature of agricultural labour?

In considering how to conceptualize the critical role of technology in new forms of accumulation and the changing dynamics of financialization, I examine the coupling of platform capitalism and surveillance capitalism in agriculture. As we continue to theorize about the power of digital technologies to restructure production, ownership and related material relations, there is a need to apply these concepts to the agrarian questions of land and labour. Studies have demonstrated the ways in which these technologies and their associated data are reinforcing corporate power and reshaping agricultural knowledge production, but little work to date has been done to extend the analysis to the assetization of land and changes in labour regimes. I suggest that emerging forms of agrarian platform and surveillance capitalism—with attention to global forces, such as climate change, and regional differences—are key to understanding contemporary processes of agrarian change.

The contributions to this Forum provide valuable insight for centering finance within agrarian change. They do this by offering grounds to analyse four interrelated processes: (1) the distinct logic of the assetization of farmland and agricultural operations; (2) the variety of property structures to control land and other elements of agricultural production; (3) the mutually reinforcing ties between assetization, digital technologies and the development of new sites for financial investment in the agricultural sector (i.e., the creation of monetized exchanges involving data and expert knowledge, giving place for new types of service-provision); and (4) the impacts on the demand for labour and labour relations driven by shareholder value. To connect the above contributions with a broader analysis of agrarian change, I synthesize these collective insights with Bernstein's key questions of agrarian political economy (see Bernstein 2010).

求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
5.20
自引率
8.00%
发文量
54
期刊介绍: The Journal of Agrarian Change is a journal of agrarian political economy. It promotes investigation of the social relations and dynamics of production, property and power in agrarian formations and their processes of change, both historical and contemporary. It encourages work within a broad interdisciplinary framework, informed by theory, and serves as a forum for serious comparative analysis and scholarly debate. Contributions are welcomed from political economists, historians, anthropologists, sociologists, political scientists, economists, geographers, lawyers, and others committed to the rigorous study and analysis of agrarian structure and change, past and present, in different parts of the world.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信