股市上涨和“泡沫”的原因和动力:从19世纪40年代英国铁路狂热的繁荣和萧条中吸取的教训

IF 1.4 Q4 BUSINESS, FINANCE
Vaska Atta-Darkua, Robert F. Bruner, Scott C. Miller
{"title":"股市上涨和“泡沫”的原因和动力:从19世纪40年代英国铁路狂热的繁荣和萧条中吸取的教训","authors":"Vaska Atta-Darkua,&nbsp;Robert F. Bruner,&nbsp;Scott C. Miller","doi":"10.1111/jacf.12673","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>Equity market run-ups (also known by the fraught term, “bubbles”) have riveted the attention of investors, asset managers, regulators, and central bankers for centuries. Commonly defined as a departure of prices from fundamental values dominated by a self-fulfilling feedback loop between expected prices and current prices, such episodes summon the conventional view that run-ups reflect market irrationality. Some run-ups preceded spectacular crashes and spawned serious economic contractions, from which new regimes of prudential regulation and pre-emption followed. Iconic examples were the Mississippi Bubble (1720), the South Sea Bubble (1720), the “Roaring Twenties” (1924–1929), and the Housing Bubble (of 2003–2008). Yet other run-ups have produced no long-lasting effects.3 Success in distinguishing malign run-ups from their benign counterparts depends on a deep understanding of their causes and dynamics.</p><p>Making use of these four propositions, we offer insights into the causes of one of the most prominent run-ups of the 19th century and then offer reflections upon their implications.</p><p>Yet why does discernment about run-ups matter? Central bankers and regulators often debate whether and how to intervene in run-ups and slumps. Household investors and professional asset managers struggle to adjust portfolios to unusual market conditions. CEOs and CFOs labor to make sense of unusual changes in their share prices in an effort to sustain efficient capital allocation. As a result, the astute official, investor, or executive should: (1) look for economic shocks that might explain the run-up; (2) assess the sufficiency and quality of information about them; and (3) ascertain which investors are trading—who is at the margin?</p><p>New research on Britain's “Railway Mania” of the 1840s by Atta-Darkua, Bruner, and Miller (<span>2024</span>) provides the foundation for this discussion. In 1844, British Prime Minister Robert Peel commenced a legislative reform of laws, regulations, and customs that constrained economic growth, restricted foreign trade, limited the ability of entrepreneurs to form new companies, checked the Bank of England's lending, challenged investors’ property rights, and constrained governance in the burgeoning railway industry. Altogether, Peel's initiative amounted to one of the most significant liberalizations in economic history.5 This programmatic onslaught coincided with a remarkable run-up in British railway equity prices from early 1844 to August 1845. Charles Mackay, a contemporary writer described the “mania” as the “greatest example in British history of the infatuation of the people for commercial gambling” ([1841], <span>1980</span>, p. 88). Then in the fall of 1845, the run-up turned into an equity price slump, followed by a modest recovery, and then a long and deep deflation in both stock prices and economic activity. This process triggered serious civil unrest in Britain. Indeed, Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels (Marx &amp; Engels, <span>1850</span>) went so far as to suggest that the railway “mania” and subsequent commercial crisis were capable of setting off a communist revolution across Europe.</p><p>Our earlier study was the first to confirm the association of a government policy shock with the run-up of 1844–1845.10 In this article, we build upon the insights of that study to explore the inflation and deflation stages of the run-up, and to consider the <i>why</i> and the <i>how</i> of run-ups. The discussion here offers preliminary evidence about the dynamics of the run-up, on which we hope to stimulate research on run-ups and careful reflection for policymakers.11</p><p>Markus Brunnermeier (<span>2018</span>) summarizes a growing literature on bubbles by attributing these events to limits to arbitrage, asymmetric information,12 overconfidence,13 and cognitive biases.14 Austrian economists and monetarists argue that expansion of the money supply and availability of credit presage runups.15 However, none of these theories suggests <i>why</i> a run-up starts, or <i>how</i> it advances.</p><p>The Conservative (Tory) Party gained a parliamentary majority in the British general election of July 1841, which presaged the rise of Robert Peel as Prime Minister. He led a party sustained by the nobility, gentry, industrialists, and rising middle class. As a reform-oriented conservative, he stood apart from the more reactionary elements in his party. Peel recoiled from the social privations and civil unrest associated with the Industrial Revolution its business cycles. However, he sensed that intra-party resistance to his reform ideas would erode his political power. “Peel's convictions became firmer and his language harsher and more defiant,” wrote his biographer (Hurd, <span>2007</span>, 255). By the start of the 1844 parliamentary session, Peel decided to wager his political capital on a range of laws addressing social, political, and economic problems.</p><p>The diffusion of railway technology had been growing for years, beginning with the founding of the first inter-city steam-driven railway, the Liverpool and Manchester, in 1830. A smaller boom of railway expansion occurred in the mid-1830s, only to recede with depressed conditions in the late 1830s. After a recession that lasted from 1841 to 1843,22 the run-up popularly known as the “railway mania” began in earnest.</p><p>Figure 1 depicts the equity market23 run-up (January 1, 1844–August 9, 1845) and slump (late August and thereafter). Cumulative returns associated with the run-up amounted to 29.7% on a broad portfolio of stocks, and 63.5% on a portfolio of railway stocks.</p><p>Our analysis of the returns to shareholders yields three important insights. First, the equity market run-up was a <i>railway sector</i> phenomenon. We examined equities in other industrial sectors and found only modest positive cumulative returns to shareholders. Spillovers from the railway sector to other sectors seem to have been scant: returns were small and generally insignificant—but positive—for a portfolio of banks, and smaller yet among firms in the insurance, metals, and shipping sectors over the same period.</p><p>Second, the run-up was significantly associated with events in Peel's liberalization program. Drawing on hand-collected data and an empirical research method not previously used in the analysis of run-ups, our study found a significant association between events in Peel's liberalizing program and returns to shareholders. From January 1, 1844 to August 9, 1845, event returns accumulated to 58.7% for railways and 46.2% for the broader diversified portfolio.25 Further analysis revealed that railways in the South and Midlands regions of England (areas with dense populations and concentrations of manufacturing and trading firms) saw significantly greater returns to railway shareholders. Finally, the largest firms (those that led a process of industry consolidation into country-wide systems) experienced significantly greater shareholder returns.</p><p>Third, as Figure 1 shows, the run-up was not a monotonic advance. Two phases emerged—a slower gain on railway equities of 24% January–August 1844, and a greater gain of 32.5% January–August 1845.26 It is important to note that the two phases of high returns were contemporaneous with sessions of Parliament which typically met from January to the end of August each year.</p><p>The run-up peaked on August 9, 1845, followed by a decline that began slowly and then accelerated. Fears of wars in Mexico and Oregon, reports of a catastrophic potato harvest in Ireland, and eyewitness accounts of shareholder defaults on call loans occupied news stories in September and October. On October 16, the Bank of England raised its base rate to 3% (from 2.5%)—and the next month would raise it to 3.5%.44 Then on November 17, <i>The Times of London</i> printed an investigative tally of the capital required to finance the railway expansion proposed by existing and new firms: the startling sum was £590 million,45 more than Britain's gross domestic product in 1845 and more than twice its monetary base.46 During parliamentary debates over the railway mania in 1846, members anguished over the ability of Britain's financial markets to fund the expansion.</p><p>Associated with the adverse news, share prices of railway companies fell about 20% from August to December 1845. By the end of 1848, the declines had erased the entire run-up. As Figure 1 shows, the deflation in railway share prices occurred in two phases. The first phase from August to December 1845 looked more like a simple equity market “correction.” The 4-month market slump may have frightened speculators but was unlikely to create the kind of severe wealth effect necessary to destabilize a financial system.</p><p>A brief rebound in the winter and spring of 1846 seemed to imply the end of the railway selloff. The rebound coincided with another round of railway legislation aimed at improving transparency, suppressing frauds, and simplifying the resolution of firms in bankruptcy. Meanwhile, as Figure 2 shows, the momentum for railway construction and sale of shares in new companies continued unabated through much of 1846.</p><p>Arguably, the share price decline from mid-1846 to 1848 is not simply a continuation of the slump in railway share prices in late 1845, but rather a new slump of broader and more serious proportions.</p><p>In sum, the years following August 1845 saw a collection of powerful adversities. As Figure 4 shows, economic growth in Britain stalled beginning in 1847.</p><p>The distance between the solid and dotted lines in Figure 4 is an indication of the output gap between potential and actual economic performance. The recession of 1847–1850 was not followed by a ‘V-shaped’ recovery, but was associated with lingering underperformance. The grand narrative of Britain's financial markets in the 1840s is one of boom and bust. The long slump in railway shares after August 1845 features prominently in the conventional views about the impact of the railway run-up. Sir Ralph L. Wedgewood, General Manager of the London and Northwest Railway wrote, “The railway mania ran its course with disaster in its train, and with abiding injury to the railway structure of the country.”48 However, the macroeconomic problems beginning in 1846 seem equally, if not more, likely to be the cause of the “disaster” that ensued.</p><p>We have argued that shocks such as sudden and consequential changes in government policy or the diffusion of a new technology can drive a run-up. Prior research sustains the impact of new technology as a driver of economic growth and equity market trends.49 Similarly, prior scholarship supports our argument that sudden and consequential changes in government policy can stimulate a run-up. Regulatory changes represent fundamental mechanisms through which governments can affect the economy and stock prices. Roberts (<span>1990</span>) demonstrates how anticipated policy shifts can substantially impact stock returns, particularly in politically sensitive sectors like defense, where regulatory decisions can dramatically alter firm cash flows. Similarly, Leblang and Mukherjee (<span>2005</span>) and Fuss and Bechtel (<span>2008</span>) provide comprehensive examinations on how political transitions create variations in stock market returns.</p><p>Monetary policy emerges as another critical domain of regulatory intervention. Kindleberger (<span>1978</span>) examines how expansionary monetary policies and credit market access can amplify stock prices and contribute to market run-ups. Bernanke and Kuttner (<span>2005</span>) further clarify this interaction, showing that unanticipated monetary policy interventions can produce significant effects on stock prices.</p><p>Regulatory changes that open stock markets to new investors can also have significant price impacts. Henry (<span>2000, 2007</span>) documents positive returns around market liberalization episodes that reduce barriers to foreign investment.</p><p>The economic impact of liberalization extends beyond immediate price effects to broader economic outcomes. Bekaert et al. (<span>2001</span>) show that financial liberalization is associated with increased real economic growth, primarily through expanded investment in local markets. This growth impact can appear as one-off increases around liberalizing episodes (Henry, <span>2000, 2007</span>) and as permanent increases in growth rates (Fuchs-Schundeln &amp; Funke, <span>2003</span>). While liberalization stimulates growth, this benefit comes with increased systemic risks. Tornell et al. (<span>2004</span>) demonstrate that economies experiencing higher growth become more susceptible to boom-bust cycles. This relationship between growth and market instability has sparked debate about the predictability of market downturns.</p><p>This discussion of Britain's railway mania of the 1840s sheds light on five challenges for decision-makers.</p><p>Economic history can inform one's understanding of run-ups and slumps. Mark Twain supposedly said that history does not repeat itself, but it rhymes.54 In that sense, a deeper grasp of Britain's railway mania of the 1840s can help to illuminate equity market responses to other policy and technology shocks, including those in the U.S. oil and steel industries (1870–1890), automobiles (1890–1930), telephones (1910–1920), hydrocarbons (1970–1980), media (1980–2000), internet search (1990–2010), airlines (2000–2015), and chemicals (2015–2020).55</p>","PeriodicalId":46789,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Applied Corporate Finance","volume":"37 2","pages":"46-59"},"PeriodicalIF":1.4000,"publicationDate":"2025-07-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/jacf.12673","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Causes and dynamics of equity market run-ups and “bubbles”: Lessons from the boom and bust of Britain's railway mania of the 1840s\",\"authors\":\"Vaska Atta-Darkua,&nbsp;Robert F. Bruner,&nbsp;Scott C. Miller\",\"doi\":\"10.1111/jacf.12673\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p>Equity market run-ups (also known by the fraught term, “bubbles”) have riveted the attention of investors, asset managers, regulators, and central bankers for centuries. Commonly defined as a departure of prices from fundamental values dominated by a self-fulfilling feedback loop between expected prices and current prices, such episodes summon the conventional view that run-ups reflect market irrationality. Some run-ups preceded spectacular crashes and spawned serious economic contractions, from which new regimes of prudential regulation and pre-emption followed. Iconic examples were the Mississippi Bubble (1720), the South Sea Bubble (1720), the “Roaring Twenties” (1924–1929), and the Housing Bubble (of 2003–2008). Yet other run-ups have produced no long-lasting effects.3 Success in distinguishing malign run-ups from their benign counterparts depends on a deep understanding of their causes and dynamics.</p><p>Making use of these four propositions, we offer insights into the causes of one of the most prominent run-ups of the 19th century and then offer reflections upon their implications.</p><p>Yet why does discernment about run-ups matter? Central bankers and regulators often debate whether and how to intervene in run-ups and slumps. Household investors and professional asset managers struggle to adjust portfolios to unusual market conditions. CEOs and CFOs labor to make sense of unusual changes in their share prices in an effort to sustain efficient capital allocation. As a result, the astute official, investor, or executive should: (1) look for economic shocks that might explain the run-up; (2) assess the sufficiency and quality of information about them; and (3) ascertain which investors are trading—who is at the margin?</p><p>New research on Britain's “Railway Mania” of the 1840s by Atta-Darkua, Bruner, and Miller (<span>2024</span>) provides the foundation for this discussion. In 1844, British Prime Minister Robert Peel commenced a legislative reform of laws, regulations, and customs that constrained economic growth, restricted foreign trade, limited the ability of entrepreneurs to form new companies, checked the Bank of England's lending, challenged investors’ property rights, and constrained governance in the burgeoning railway industry. Altogether, Peel's initiative amounted to one of the most significant liberalizations in economic history.5 This programmatic onslaught coincided with a remarkable run-up in British railway equity prices from early 1844 to August 1845. Charles Mackay, a contemporary writer described the “mania” as the “greatest example in British history of the infatuation of the people for commercial gambling” ([1841], <span>1980</span>, p. 88). Then in the fall of 1845, the run-up turned into an equity price slump, followed by a modest recovery, and then a long and deep deflation in both stock prices and economic activity. This process triggered serious civil unrest in Britain. Indeed, Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels (Marx &amp; Engels, <span>1850</span>) went so far as to suggest that the railway “mania” and subsequent commercial crisis were capable of setting off a communist revolution across Europe.</p><p>Our earlier study was the first to confirm the association of a government policy shock with the run-up of 1844–1845.10 In this article, we build upon the insights of that study to explore the inflation and deflation stages of the run-up, and to consider the <i>why</i> and the <i>how</i> of run-ups. The discussion here offers preliminary evidence about the dynamics of the run-up, on which we hope to stimulate research on run-ups and careful reflection for policymakers.11</p><p>Markus Brunnermeier (<span>2018</span>) summarizes a growing literature on bubbles by attributing these events to limits to arbitrage, asymmetric information,12 overconfidence,13 and cognitive biases.14 Austrian economists and monetarists argue that expansion of the money supply and availability of credit presage runups.15 However, none of these theories suggests <i>why</i> a run-up starts, or <i>how</i> it advances.</p><p>The Conservative (Tory) Party gained a parliamentary majority in the British general election of July 1841, which presaged the rise of Robert Peel as Prime Minister. He led a party sustained by the nobility, gentry, industrialists, and rising middle class. As a reform-oriented conservative, he stood apart from the more reactionary elements in his party. Peel recoiled from the social privations and civil unrest associated with the Industrial Revolution its business cycles. However, he sensed that intra-party resistance to his reform ideas would erode his political power. “Peel's convictions became firmer and his language harsher and more defiant,” wrote his biographer (Hurd, <span>2007</span>, 255). By the start of the 1844 parliamentary session, Peel decided to wager his political capital on a range of laws addressing social, political, and economic problems.</p><p>The diffusion of railway technology had been growing for years, beginning with the founding of the first inter-city steam-driven railway, the Liverpool and Manchester, in 1830. A smaller boom of railway expansion occurred in the mid-1830s, only to recede with depressed conditions in the late 1830s. After a recession that lasted from 1841 to 1843,22 the run-up popularly known as the “railway mania” began in earnest.</p><p>Figure 1 depicts the equity market23 run-up (January 1, 1844–August 9, 1845) and slump (late August and thereafter). Cumulative returns associated with the run-up amounted to 29.7% on a broad portfolio of stocks, and 63.5% on a portfolio of railway stocks.</p><p>Our analysis of the returns to shareholders yields three important insights. First, the equity market run-up was a <i>railway sector</i> phenomenon. We examined equities in other industrial sectors and found only modest positive cumulative returns to shareholders. Spillovers from the railway sector to other sectors seem to have been scant: returns were small and generally insignificant—but positive—for a portfolio of banks, and smaller yet among firms in the insurance, metals, and shipping sectors over the same period.</p><p>Second, the run-up was significantly associated with events in Peel's liberalization program. Drawing on hand-collected data and an empirical research method not previously used in the analysis of run-ups, our study found a significant association between events in Peel's liberalizing program and returns to shareholders. From January 1, 1844 to August 9, 1845, event returns accumulated to 58.7% for railways and 46.2% for the broader diversified portfolio.25 Further analysis revealed that railways in the South and Midlands regions of England (areas with dense populations and concentrations of manufacturing and trading firms) saw significantly greater returns to railway shareholders. Finally, the largest firms (those that led a process of industry consolidation into country-wide systems) experienced significantly greater shareholder returns.</p><p>Third, as Figure 1 shows, the run-up was not a monotonic advance. Two phases emerged—a slower gain on railway equities of 24% January–August 1844, and a greater gain of 32.5% January–August 1845.26 It is important to note that the two phases of high returns were contemporaneous with sessions of Parliament which typically met from January to the end of August each year.</p><p>The run-up peaked on August 9, 1845, followed by a decline that began slowly and then accelerated. Fears of wars in Mexico and Oregon, reports of a catastrophic potato harvest in Ireland, and eyewitness accounts of shareholder defaults on call loans occupied news stories in September and October. On October 16, the Bank of England raised its base rate to 3% (from 2.5%)—and the next month would raise it to 3.5%.44 Then on November 17, <i>The Times of London</i> printed an investigative tally of the capital required to finance the railway expansion proposed by existing and new firms: the startling sum was £590 million,45 more than Britain's gross domestic product in 1845 and more than twice its monetary base.46 During parliamentary debates over the railway mania in 1846, members anguished over the ability of Britain's financial markets to fund the expansion.</p><p>Associated with the adverse news, share prices of railway companies fell about 20% from August to December 1845. By the end of 1848, the declines had erased the entire run-up. As Figure 1 shows, the deflation in railway share prices occurred in two phases. The first phase from August to December 1845 looked more like a simple equity market “correction.” The 4-month market slump may have frightened speculators but was unlikely to create the kind of severe wealth effect necessary to destabilize a financial system.</p><p>A brief rebound in the winter and spring of 1846 seemed to imply the end of the railway selloff. The rebound coincided with another round of railway legislation aimed at improving transparency, suppressing frauds, and simplifying the resolution of firms in bankruptcy. Meanwhile, as Figure 2 shows, the momentum for railway construction and sale of shares in new companies continued unabated through much of 1846.</p><p>Arguably, the share price decline from mid-1846 to 1848 is not simply a continuation of the slump in railway share prices in late 1845, but rather a new slump of broader and more serious proportions.</p><p>In sum, the years following August 1845 saw a collection of powerful adversities. As Figure 4 shows, economic growth in Britain stalled beginning in 1847.</p><p>The distance between the solid and dotted lines in Figure 4 is an indication of the output gap between potential and actual economic performance. The recession of 1847–1850 was not followed by a ‘V-shaped’ recovery, but was associated with lingering underperformance. The grand narrative of Britain's financial markets in the 1840s is one of boom and bust. The long slump in railway shares after August 1845 features prominently in the conventional views about the impact of the railway run-up. Sir Ralph L. Wedgewood, General Manager of the London and Northwest Railway wrote, “The railway mania ran its course with disaster in its train, and with abiding injury to the railway structure of the country.”48 However, the macroeconomic problems beginning in 1846 seem equally, if not more, likely to be the cause of the “disaster” that ensued.</p><p>We have argued that shocks such as sudden and consequential changes in government policy or the diffusion of a new technology can drive a run-up. Prior research sustains the impact of new technology as a driver of economic growth and equity market trends.49 Similarly, prior scholarship supports our argument that sudden and consequential changes in government policy can stimulate a run-up. Regulatory changes represent fundamental mechanisms through which governments can affect the economy and stock prices. Roberts (<span>1990</span>) demonstrates how anticipated policy shifts can substantially impact stock returns, particularly in politically sensitive sectors like defense, where regulatory decisions can dramatically alter firm cash flows. Similarly, Leblang and Mukherjee (<span>2005</span>) and Fuss and Bechtel (<span>2008</span>) provide comprehensive examinations on how political transitions create variations in stock market returns.</p><p>Monetary policy emerges as another critical domain of regulatory intervention. Kindleberger (<span>1978</span>) examines how expansionary monetary policies and credit market access can amplify stock prices and contribute to market run-ups. Bernanke and Kuttner (<span>2005</span>) further clarify this interaction, showing that unanticipated monetary policy interventions can produce significant effects on stock prices.</p><p>Regulatory changes that open stock markets to new investors can also have significant price impacts. Henry (<span>2000, 2007</span>) documents positive returns around market liberalization episodes that reduce barriers to foreign investment.</p><p>The economic impact of liberalization extends beyond immediate price effects to broader economic outcomes. Bekaert et al. (<span>2001</span>) show that financial liberalization is associated with increased real economic growth, primarily through expanded investment in local markets. This growth impact can appear as one-off increases around liberalizing episodes (Henry, <span>2000, 2007</span>) and as permanent increases in growth rates (Fuchs-Schundeln &amp; Funke, <span>2003</span>). While liberalization stimulates growth, this benefit comes with increased systemic risks. Tornell et al. (<span>2004</span>) demonstrate that economies experiencing higher growth become more susceptible to boom-bust cycles. This relationship between growth and market instability has sparked debate about the predictability of market downturns.</p><p>This discussion of Britain's railway mania of the 1840s sheds light on five challenges for decision-makers.</p><p>Economic history can inform one's understanding of run-ups and slumps. Mark Twain supposedly said that history does not repeat itself, but it rhymes.54 In that sense, a deeper grasp of Britain's railway mania of the 1840s can help to illuminate equity market responses to other policy and technology shocks, including those in the U.S. oil and steel industries (1870–1890), automobiles (1890–1930), telephones (1910–1920), hydrocarbons (1970–1980), media (1980–2000), internet search (1990–2010), airlines (2000–2015), and chemicals (2015–2020).55</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":46789,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Journal of Applied Corporate Finance\",\"volume\":\"37 2\",\"pages\":\"46-59\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":1.4000,\"publicationDate\":\"2025-07-30\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/jacf.12673\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Journal of Applied Corporate Finance\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jacf.12673\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q4\",\"JCRName\":\"BUSINESS, FINANCE\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of Applied Corporate Finance","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jacf.12673","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q4","JCRName":"BUSINESS, FINANCE","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

几个世纪以来,股市上涨(也被称为令人担忧的术语“泡沫”)一直吸引着投资者、资产管理公司、监管机构和央行行长的注意力。这种情况通常被定义为价格偏离基本价值,并受到预期价格与当前价格之间自我实现的反馈循环的支配。这种情况让人产生了一种传统观点,即上涨反映了市场的非理性。一些涨势出现在壮观的崩盘之前,并引发了严重的经济收缩,随后出现了审慎监管和先发制人的新体制。典型的例子是密西西比泡沫(1720年)、南海泡沫(1720年)、“咆哮的20年代”(1924-1929年)和房地产泡沫(2003-2008年)。然而,其他的跑步运动并没有产生持久的影响要成功区分恶性和良性增长,取决于对其原因和动态的深刻理解。利用这四个命题,我们提供了对19世纪最突出的跑步之一的原因的见解,然后提供了对其含义的反思。然而,为什么对跑步的辨别很重要呢?央行行长和监管机构经常就是否以及如何干预上涨和下跌进行辩论。家庭投资者和专业资产管理公司难以根据不同寻常的市场状况调整投资组合。为了维持有效的资本配置,首席执行官和首席财务官们努力弄清楚股价的异常变化。因此,精明的官员、投资者或高管应该:(1)寻找可能解释上涨的经济冲击;(2)评估有关他们的信息的充分性和质量;(3)确定哪些投资者在交易——谁在获利?Atta-Darkua、Bruner和Miller(2024)对19世纪40年代英国“铁路狂热”的新研究为这一讨论提供了基础。1844年,英国首相罗伯特·皮尔开始对法律、法规和习俗进行立法改革,这些法律、法规和习俗限制了经济增长,限制了对外贸易,限制了企业家组建新公司的能力,检查了英格兰银行的贷款,挑战了投资者的财产权,限制了新兴铁路行业的治理。总之,皮尔的倡议是经济史上最重要的自由化之一从1844年初到1845年8月,这种计划性的冲击与英国铁路股票价格的显著上涨相吻合。当代作家查尔斯·麦凯(Charles Mackay)将这种“狂热”描述为“英国历史上人们迷恋商业赌博的最伟大的例子”([1841],1980,第88页)。然后在1845年秋天,上涨变成了股票价格的暴跌,随后是温和的复苏,然后是股票价格和经济活动的长期深度通缩。这一过程在英国引发了严重的内乱。事实上,卡尔·马克思和弗里德里希·恩格斯(马克思和恩格斯,1850年)甚至认为,铁路“狂热”和随后的商业危机有可能在整个欧洲掀起一场共产主义革命。我们早期的研究首次证实了政府政策冲击与1844年至1845.10年的上涨之间的联系。在本文中,我们以该研究的见解为基础,探讨了上涨的通胀和通缩阶段,并考虑了上涨的原因和方式。这里的讨论提供了关于上涨动力的初步证据,我们希望以此刺激对上涨的研究,并为政策制定者提供仔细的反思。markus Brunnermeier(2018)总结了越来越多关于泡沫的文献,将这些事件归因于套利限制、信息不对称、过度自信、认知偏见奥地利经济学家和货币主义者认为,货币供应的扩大和信贷的可获得性预示着经济增长然而,这些理论都没有说明牛市为何开始,或者它是如何发展的。保守党在1841年7月的英国大选中获得议会多数席位,这预示着罗伯特·皮尔(Robert Peel)成为首相。他领导了一个由贵族、绅士、实业家和新兴中产阶级支持的政党。作为一个以改革为导向的保守派,他与党内较为反动的分子保持着距离。皮尔在工业革命和商业周期带来的社会贫困和内乱中退缩了。然而,他感觉到党内对他的改革思想的抵制会削弱他的政治权力。皮尔的传记作者写道:“皮尔的信念变得更加坚定,他的语言变得更加严厉和挑衅。”到1844年议会会议开始时,皮尔决定把他的政治资本押在一系列解决社会、政治和经济问题的法律上。 从1830年第一条城际蒸汽铁路——利物浦和曼彻斯特铁路的建成开始,铁路技术的传播已经持续了多年。19世纪30年代中期出现了一个较小的铁路扩张热潮,但在19世纪30年代后期由于经济不景气而消退。在经历了从1841年到1843年的经济衰退之后,人们熟知的“铁路热”正式开始了。图1描述了股票市场的上涨(1844年1月1日至1845年8月9日)和下跌(8月下旬及之后)。总体股票投资组合的累计回报率为29.7%,铁路类股票投资组合的累计回报率为63.5%。我们对股东回报的分析得出了三个重要的见解。首先,股市上涨是铁路行业的现象。我们考察了其他工业部门的股票,发现股东的累计回报只有适度的正回报。从铁路部门到其他部门的溢出效应似乎很少:回报很小,总体上微不足道,但对银行的投资组合来说是正的,而同期保险、金属和航运部门的公司则更小。其次,这一上涨与皮尔的自由化计划的事件密切相关。根据手工收集的数据和以前未用于分析上市公司的实证研究方法,我们的研究发现,皮尔自由化计划中的事件与股东回报之间存在显著关联。从1844年1月1日到1845年8月9日,铁路的事件收益率累计为58.7%,而更广泛的多元化投资组合的事件收益率累计为46.2%进一步的分析表明,在英格兰南部和中部地区(人口密集、制造业和贸易公司集中的地区),铁路股东的回报要高得多。最后,最大的公司(那些引领行业整合过程进入全国范围系统的公司)经历了显著更高的股东回报。第三,如图1所示,上涨并不是单调的上涨。出现了两个阶段——1844年1月至8月铁路股票缓慢增长24%,1845.26年1月至8月铁路股票大幅增长32.5%。值得注意的是,高回报的两个阶段与议会会议同时发生,议会会议通常在每年1月至8月底举行。上涨在1845年8月9日达到顶峰,随后开始缓慢下跌,然后加速下跌。对墨西哥和俄勒冈州战争的担忧,爱尔兰马铃薯灾难性收成的报道,以及股东拖欠即期贷款的目击者描述,占据了9月和10月的新闻报道。10月16日,英格兰银行将基准利率从2.5%上调至3%,下个月将上调至3.5%然后在11月17日,伦敦的《泰晤士报》刊登了一份由现有公司和新公司提出的铁路扩建所需资金的调查统计:惊人的数字是5.9亿英镑,比英国1845年的国内生产总值还多,是其货币基础的两倍多在1846年议会关于铁路狂热的辩论中,议员们对英国金融市场为扩张提供资金的能力感到痛苦。受不利消息的影响,铁路公司的股价从1845年8月到12月下跌了约20%。到1848年底,下跌抹去了整个上涨。如图1所示,铁路股价的通缩分两个阶段发生。从1845年8月到12月的第一阶段看起来更像是一次简单的股票市场“调整”。持续4个月的市场暴跌可能吓坏了投机者,但不太可能产生破坏金融体系稳定所必需的那种严重的财富效应。1846年冬季和春季的短暂反弹似乎意味着铁路抛售的结束。这一反弹恰逢另一轮旨在提高透明度、打击欺诈和简化破产公司处理程序的铁路立法。与此同时,如图2所示,在1846年的大部分时间里,铁路建设和新公司股票销售的势头一直有增无减。可以说,1846年中期到1848年的股价下跌不仅仅是1845年末铁路股价暴跌的延续,而是更广泛、更严重的新一轮暴跌。总之,在1845年8月之后的几年里,我们看到了一系列强大的逆境。如图4所示,英国的经济增长从1847年开始陷入停滞。图4中实线和虚线之间的距离表明了潜在经济表现和实际经济表现之间的产出差距。1847-1850年的经济衰退之后并没有出现v型复苏,而是伴随着持续的表现不佳。19世纪40年代英国金融市场的宏大叙事是一种繁荣与萧条。 铁路股在1845年8月之后的长期暴跌,在有关铁路上涨影响的传统观点中占有显著地位。拉尔夫·l·韦奇伍德爵士是伦敦和西北铁路公司的总经理,他写道:“铁路狂热伴随着灾难的到来,对国家的铁路结构造成了持久的伤害。48然而,从1846年开始的宏观经济问题似乎同样(如果不是更大的话)可能是随后发生的“灾难”的原因。我们认为,政府政策的突然和相应的变化或新技术的传播等冲击可以推动上涨。先前的研究支持新技术作为经济增长和股票市场趋势的驱动因素的影响同样,先前的学术研究也支持我们的观点,即政府政策的突然和相应的变化可以刺激股市上涨。监管变化代表了政府影响经济和股价的基本机制。罗伯茨(1990)证明了预期的政策变化如何实质性地影响股票回报,特别是在国防等政治敏感领域,监管决策可以极大地改变公司的现金流。同样,Leblang和Mukherjee(2005)以及Fuss和Bechtel(2008)对政治转型如何造成股市回报的变化进行了全面的研究。货币政策成为监管干预的另一个重要领域。Kindleberger(1978)研究了扩张性货币政策和信贷市场准入如何放大股票价格并促进市场上涨。Bernanke和Kuttner(2005)进一步阐明了这种相互作用,表明意外的货币政策干预可以对股票价格产生显著影响。向新投资者开放股市的监管改革也会对股价产生重大影响。Henry(2000,2007)记录了市场自由化时期减少外国投资壁垒的积极回报。自由化的经济影响超越了直接的价格影响,延伸到更广泛的经济结果。Bekaert等人(2001)表明,金融自由化与实体经济增长的增加有关,主要是通过扩大对当地市场的投资。这种增长影响可以表现为自由化时期的一次性增长(Henry, 2000,2007),也可以表现为增长率的永久性增长(Fuchs-Schundeln & Funke, 2003)。在自由化刺激增长的同时,这种好处也伴随着系统性风险的增加。Tornell等人(2004)证明,经历高增长的经济体更容易受到繁荣-萧条周期的影响。增长与市场不稳定之间的这种关系,引发了有关市场低迷可预测性的辩论。对19世纪40年代英国铁路狂热的讨论,揭示了决策者面临的五大挑战。经济史可以帮助我们理解上升和下降。据说马克·吐温曾说过,历史不会重演,但它是押韵的从这个意义上说,对19世纪40年代英国铁路狂热的更深入了解,可以帮助阐明股市对其他政策和技术冲击的反应,包括美国石油和钢铁行业(1870-1890)、汽车行业(1890-1930)、电话行业(1910-1920)、碳氢燃料行业(1970-1980)、媒体行业(1980-2000)、互联网搜索行业(1990-2010)、航空公司(2000-2015)和化工行业(2015-2020)
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。

Causes and dynamics of equity market run-ups and “bubbles”: Lessons from the boom and bust of Britain's railway mania of the 1840s

Causes and dynamics of equity market run-ups and “bubbles”: Lessons from the boom and bust of Britain's railway mania of the 1840s

Equity market run-ups (also known by the fraught term, “bubbles”) have riveted the attention of investors, asset managers, regulators, and central bankers for centuries. Commonly defined as a departure of prices from fundamental values dominated by a self-fulfilling feedback loop between expected prices and current prices, such episodes summon the conventional view that run-ups reflect market irrationality. Some run-ups preceded spectacular crashes and spawned serious economic contractions, from which new regimes of prudential regulation and pre-emption followed. Iconic examples were the Mississippi Bubble (1720), the South Sea Bubble (1720), the “Roaring Twenties” (1924–1929), and the Housing Bubble (of 2003–2008). Yet other run-ups have produced no long-lasting effects.3 Success in distinguishing malign run-ups from their benign counterparts depends on a deep understanding of their causes and dynamics.

Making use of these four propositions, we offer insights into the causes of one of the most prominent run-ups of the 19th century and then offer reflections upon their implications.

Yet why does discernment about run-ups matter? Central bankers and regulators often debate whether and how to intervene in run-ups and slumps. Household investors and professional asset managers struggle to adjust portfolios to unusual market conditions. CEOs and CFOs labor to make sense of unusual changes in their share prices in an effort to sustain efficient capital allocation. As a result, the astute official, investor, or executive should: (1) look for economic shocks that might explain the run-up; (2) assess the sufficiency and quality of information about them; and (3) ascertain which investors are trading—who is at the margin?

New research on Britain's “Railway Mania” of the 1840s by Atta-Darkua, Bruner, and Miller (2024) provides the foundation for this discussion. In 1844, British Prime Minister Robert Peel commenced a legislative reform of laws, regulations, and customs that constrained economic growth, restricted foreign trade, limited the ability of entrepreneurs to form new companies, checked the Bank of England's lending, challenged investors’ property rights, and constrained governance in the burgeoning railway industry. Altogether, Peel's initiative amounted to one of the most significant liberalizations in economic history.5 This programmatic onslaught coincided with a remarkable run-up in British railway equity prices from early 1844 to August 1845. Charles Mackay, a contemporary writer described the “mania” as the “greatest example in British history of the infatuation of the people for commercial gambling” ([1841], 1980, p. 88). Then in the fall of 1845, the run-up turned into an equity price slump, followed by a modest recovery, and then a long and deep deflation in both stock prices and economic activity. This process triggered serious civil unrest in Britain. Indeed, Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels (Marx & Engels, 1850) went so far as to suggest that the railway “mania” and subsequent commercial crisis were capable of setting off a communist revolution across Europe.

Our earlier study was the first to confirm the association of a government policy shock with the run-up of 1844–1845.10 In this article, we build upon the insights of that study to explore the inflation and deflation stages of the run-up, and to consider the why and the how of run-ups. The discussion here offers preliminary evidence about the dynamics of the run-up, on which we hope to stimulate research on run-ups and careful reflection for policymakers.11

Markus Brunnermeier (2018) summarizes a growing literature on bubbles by attributing these events to limits to arbitrage, asymmetric information,12 overconfidence,13 and cognitive biases.14 Austrian economists and monetarists argue that expansion of the money supply and availability of credit presage runups.15 However, none of these theories suggests why a run-up starts, or how it advances.

The Conservative (Tory) Party gained a parliamentary majority in the British general election of July 1841, which presaged the rise of Robert Peel as Prime Minister. He led a party sustained by the nobility, gentry, industrialists, and rising middle class. As a reform-oriented conservative, he stood apart from the more reactionary elements in his party. Peel recoiled from the social privations and civil unrest associated with the Industrial Revolution its business cycles. However, he sensed that intra-party resistance to his reform ideas would erode his political power. “Peel's convictions became firmer and his language harsher and more defiant,” wrote his biographer (Hurd, 2007, 255). By the start of the 1844 parliamentary session, Peel decided to wager his political capital on a range of laws addressing social, political, and economic problems.

The diffusion of railway technology had been growing for years, beginning with the founding of the first inter-city steam-driven railway, the Liverpool and Manchester, in 1830. A smaller boom of railway expansion occurred in the mid-1830s, only to recede with depressed conditions in the late 1830s. After a recession that lasted from 1841 to 1843,22 the run-up popularly known as the “railway mania” began in earnest.

Figure 1 depicts the equity market23 run-up (January 1, 1844–August 9, 1845) and slump (late August and thereafter). Cumulative returns associated with the run-up amounted to 29.7% on a broad portfolio of stocks, and 63.5% on a portfolio of railway stocks.

Our analysis of the returns to shareholders yields three important insights. First, the equity market run-up was a railway sector phenomenon. We examined equities in other industrial sectors and found only modest positive cumulative returns to shareholders. Spillovers from the railway sector to other sectors seem to have been scant: returns were small and generally insignificant—but positive—for a portfolio of banks, and smaller yet among firms in the insurance, metals, and shipping sectors over the same period.

Second, the run-up was significantly associated with events in Peel's liberalization program. Drawing on hand-collected data and an empirical research method not previously used in the analysis of run-ups, our study found a significant association between events in Peel's liberalizing program and returns to shareholders. From January 1, 1844 to August 9, 1845, event returns accumulated to 58.7% for railways and 46.2% for the broader diversified portfolio.25 Further analysis revealed that railways in the South and Midlands regions of England (areas with dense populations and concentrations of manufacturing and trading firms) saw significantly greater returns to railway shareholders. Finally, the largest firms (those that led a process of industry consolidation into country-wide systems) experienced significantly greater shareholder returns.

Third, as Figure 1 shows, the run-up was not a monotonic advance. Two phases emerged—a slower gain on railway equities of 24% January–August 1844, and a greater gain of 32.5% January–August 1845.26 It is important to note that the two phases of high returns were contemporaneous with sessions of Parliament which typically met from January to the end of August each year.

The run-up peaked on August 9, 1845, followed by a decline that began slowly and then accelerated. Fears of wars in Mexico and Oregon, reports of a catastrophic potato harvest in Ireland, and eyewitness accounts of shareholder defaults on call loans occupied news stories in September and October. On October 16, the Bank of England raised its base rate to 3% (from 2.5%)—and the next month would raise it to 3.5%.44 Then on November 17, The Times of London printed an investigative tally of the capital required to finance the railway expansion proposed by existing and new firms: the startling sum was £590 million,45 more than Britain's gross domestic product in 1845 and more than twice its monetary base.46 During parliamentary debates over the railway mania in 1846, members anguished over the ability of Britain's financial markets to fund the expansion.

Associated with the adverse news, share prices of railway companies fell about 20% from August to December 1845. By the end of 1848, the declines had erased the entire run-up. As Figure 1 shows, the deflation in railway share prices occurred in two phases. The first phase from August to December 1845 looked more like a simple equity market “correction.” The 4-month market slump may have frightened speculators but was unlikely to create the kind of severe wealth effect necessary to destabilize a financial system.

A brief rebound in the winter and spring of 1846 seemed to imply the end of the railway selloff. The rebound coincided with another round of railway legislation aimed at improving transparency, suppressing frauds, and simplifying the resolution of firms in bankruptcy. Meanwhile, as Figure 2 shows, the momentum for railway construction and sale of shares in new companies continued unabated through much of 1846.

Arguably, the share price decline from mid-1846 to 1848 is not simply a continuation of the slump in railway share prices in late 1845, but rather a new slump of broader and more serious proportions.

In sum, the years following August 1845 saw a collection of powerful adversities. As Figure 4 shows, economic growth in Britain stalled beginning in 1847.

The distance between the solid and dotted lines in Figure 4 is an indication of the output gap between potential and actual economic performance. The recession of 1847–1850 was not followed by a ‘V-shaped’ recovery, but was associated with lingering underperformance. The grand narrative of Britain's financial markets in the 1840s is one of boom and bust. The long slump in railway shares after August 1845 features prominently in the conventional views about the impact of the railway run-up. Sir Ralph L. Wedgewood, General Manager of the London and Northwest Railway wrote, “The railway mania ran its course with disaster in its train, and with abiding injury to the railway structure of the country.”48 However, the macroeconomic problems beginning in 1846 seem equally, if not more, likely to be the cause of the “disaster” that ensued.

We have argued that shocks such as sudden and consequential changes in government policy or the diffusion of a new technology can drive a run-up. Prior research sustains the impact of new technology as a driver of economic growth and equity market trends.49 Similarly, prior scholarship supports our argument that sudden and consequential changes in government policy can stimulate a run-up. Regulatory changes represent fundamental mechanisms through which governments can affect the economy and stock prices. Roberts (1990) demonstrates how anticipated policy shifts can substantially impact stock returns, particularly in politically sensitive sectors like defense, where regulatory decisions can dramatically alter firm cash flows. Similarly, Leblang and Mukherjee (2005) and Fuss and Bechtel (2008) provide comprehensive examinations on how political transitions create variations in stock market returns.

Monetary policy emerges as another critical domain of regulatory intervention. Kindleberger (1978) examines how expansionary monetary policies and credit market access can amplify stock prices and contribute to market run-ups. Bernanke and Kuttner (2005) further clarify this interaction, showing that unanticipated monetary policy interventions can produce significant effects on stock prices.

Regulatory changes that open stock markets to new investors can also have significant price impacts. Henry (2000, 2007) documents positive returns around market liberalization episodes that reduce barriers to foreign investment.

The economic impact of liberalization extends beyond immediate price effects to broader economic outcomes. Bekaert et al. (2001) show that financial liberalization is associated with increased real economic growth, primarily through expanded investment in local markets. This growth impact can appear as one-off increases around liberalizing episodes (Henry, 2000, 2007) and as permanent increases in growth rates (Fuchs-Schundeln & Funke, 2003). While liberalization stimulates growth, this benefit comes with increased systemic risks. Tornell et al. (2004) demonstrate that economies experiencing higher growth become more susceptible to boom-bust cycles. This relationship between growth and market instability has sparked debate about the predictability of market downturns.

This discussion of Britain's railway mania of the 1840s sheds light on five challenges for decision-makers.

Economic history can inform one's understanding of run-ups and slumps. Mark Twain supposedly said that history does not repeat itself, but it rhymes.54 In that sense, a deeper grasp of Britain's railway mania of the 1840s can help to illuminate equity market responses to other policy and technology shocks, including those in the U.S. oil and steel industries (1870–1890), automobiles (1890–1930), telephones (1910–1920), hydrocarbons (1970–1980), media (1980–2000), internet search (1990–2010), airlines (2000–2015), and chemicals (2015–2020).55

求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
11.10%
发文量
44
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信