放宽地方教育经费的选举限制

IF 2.4 3区 管理学 Q2 ECONOMICS
Michel Grosz, Ross Milton
{"title":"放宽地方教育经费的选举限制","authors":"Michel Grosz,&nbsp;Ross Milton","doi":"10.1002/pam.70023","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>If voters do not like federal tax policy, they can elect new representatives. At the local level, though, voters can directly deny the tax increases their elected officials propose. All but three states have a limit on either the taxing or spending abilities of local governments and, most commonly, state laws require that increases in local taxes receive a public referendum before they are enacted (Mullins, <span>2010</span>). In the November 2020 election, voters nationwide decided on the fate of $52.7 billion of proposed funding, down from $70 billion 4 years prior (Pierog, <span>2020</span>).</p><p>Requirements that budgeting questions be put to a vote reduce the level of spending (Feld &amp; Matsusaka, <span>2003</span>; Funk &amp; Gathmann, <span>2011</span>). However, the rules that govern these votes vary in myriad ways. States differ in the types of taxes or spending the rules cover: Some only allow proposals for capital spending, while others also include current expenditure spending. States also often limit the total amount of tax revenue or the tax rate governments can propose, and vary in whether they adjust for inflation, for changes in population, or for growth in the property tax base. Certain election rules limit the timing of when governments can put proposals on the ballot, since local governments may use this timing flexibility strategically (Anzia, <span>2011</span>; Kogan et al., <span>2018</span>; Meredith, <span>2009</span>). States also differ in the vote share required to approve the proposals, with many proposals requiring more than a simple majority. There is little empirical research, however, documenting how these differences in voting requirements may affect government budgets, local spending, and the provision of public goods and services. This is a significant gap in the literature given the millions of dollars in funding at stake in each local referendum and the billions at stake nationwide.</p><p>In this paper, we study a proposition in California that weakened the constraints on some local governments by lowering the vote share required to approve capital funding for schools and community colleges. We use a difference-in-differences design around this policy change and data for over 4,000 local elections across the state over 2 decades. We estimate the effects of this policy change on the proposals made by affected districts, their outcomes at the ballot box, and on the eventual funding outcomes.</p><p>We develop a theoretical model of the interaction between a school board and voters, building on the literature in local political economy (Barseghyan &amp; Coate, <span>2014</span>; Coate &amp; Ma, <span>2017</span>; Romer &amp; Rosenthal, <span>1982</span>). In our model, the school board makes a tax proposal that the voter can accept or reject. Thus, the school board has “agenda-setting” power to extract policies closer to its preferences than those of the voter. However, uncertainty in how residents will vote hinders the exercise of this agenda-setting power. We use this model to show how a change in the required vote share affects the size of the proposals and the vote outcomes, and to show how these effects depend on the divergence in preferences between voters and elected officials.</p><p>We study how the policy change affected the funding outcomes of local governments. We find that Proposition 39 led to an additional $57 per resident in approved local government bonds, a more than 100% increase. This is a large impact, and one that affects governments unequally. There were larger effects on funding outcomes in more racially and ethnically diverse districts. Similarly, we find larger effects in jurisdictions with moderate levels of poverty, moderate White population shares, and fewer older residents. These results shed light on the characteristics of places where funding is most constrained by referendum requirements. Our model shows that the extent of a community's responsiveness to a change in the vote share requirement depends on the extent of disagreement between voters and their elected representatives, as well as the level of uncertainty in referenda outcomes that the elected officials face. Thus, the empirical results show what types of communities have larger disagreements or more uncertain election outcomes.</p><p>There are two channels through which these effects could occur: the behavior of elected officials when proposing funding and of voters when voting on the proposals. We find that the policy change made treated districts no more likely to propose a bond relative to other jurisdictions. However, the size of the bond proposals increased substantially, by $48 per resident, or a 59% increase. Naturally, the larger bond proposals may result in lower vote shares. Conditional on proposing a bond, we find that the policy change resulted in bond proposals receiving a lower percentage of votes in favor. However, this decline was smaller than the 11.7 percentage point decrease in the vote share requirement. In other words, school boards and community college districts experienced declines in support for their proposals that were smaller than the full amount of the policy change. Thus, we observe no change in the probability that affected districts approved any kind of new funding, and large increases in the probability that they approved new bonds. Even though these districts submitted larger proposals that had less support from the electorate, they resulted in increases in the probability of success. These results—a positive effect on proposal size and a negative effect on vote shares—are consistent with the politician preferring higher spending than the voters, when interpreted through the lens of our model.</p><p>Our paper contributes to several strands of research. First, we contribute to empirical evidence on the fiscal and policy effects of tax limits. This literature builds on the work of Romer and Rosenthal (<span>1978, 1979</span>, <span>1982</span>), which modeled the constraint on government in contexts where government officials have agenda setting power. Balsdon et al. (<span>2003</span>) applied the logic of these agenda-setting models to proposals of and voting on school bonds. The authors estimated a structural model of school boards and voters and found that school boards favor a higher level of spending than voters but are risk averse in their proposals. We extend this line of research by leveraging a policy change, and our finding that relaxing the voting threshold results in larger proposals is consistent with their result.</p><p>We also contribute to an empirical literature on the effects of tax limits on the quality of public services (Dye &amp; McGuire, <span>1997</span>; Figlio &amp; Rueben, <span>2001</span>; Poterba &amp; Rueben, <span>1995</span>; Rose, <span>2010</span>). These papers study the effect of the existence of local tax limits. By contrast, in this paper we study a change in a particular characteristic of the limit itself. Romer et al. (<span>1992</span>) shared that aim and considered the effects of matching aid and supermajority requirements in the context of their structural model. However, their data did not contain any heterogeneity in the vote requirements. We show that the vote share required to pass public spending has large effects on the amount of spending both proposed and implemented.</p><p>While this paper is the first to our knowledge to study the effects of the change in the voting threshold, two papers have studied voting on the constitutional amendment that resulted in this policy change. Brunner and Ross (<span>2010</span>) developed a model of voter support for supermajority rules and showed that voter support for the supermajority rules is related to the income distribution in their school district. Balsdon et al. (<span>2005</span>) showed that voters in metropolitan areas with a more fragmented set of school districts were more likely to vote for the reduction in the threshold. An existing literature has studied supermajority voting rules in the context of legislative voting (Crain &amp; Miller, <span>1989</span>; Messner &amp; Polborn, <span>2004</span>). Most related to our work is Knight (<span>2000</span>), which instrumented for supermajority requirements with the ease of amending state constitutions and found that supermajority requirements lead to lower taxes. This paper complements these analyses by examining the effect of a change in the severity of a supermajority requirement in the context of public referenda.</p><p>The environment of voting on school financing and the effect of the resulting funding has received significant study. Cerdán and Rueben (<span>2003</span>) detailed the history of school funding referenda in California. While we study the process of the school votes themselves, Cellini et al. (<span>2010</span>) studied the effects of the resulting capital investments on house prices and Cellini (<span>2009</span>) examined their effects on higher education. These papers are part of a broader literature that studies the effects of school construction; the evidence on its effect on student outcomes is mixed. Large school construction projects may lead to improved student outcomes (Aaronson &amp; Mazumder, <span>2011</span>; Conlin &amp; Thompson, <span>2017</span>; Duflo, <span>2001</span>; Neilson &amp; Zimmerman, <span>2014</span>). However, studies using regression discontinuity approaches to study school capital improvement bond referenda, like those we study, have found limited evidence of positive effects on student outcomes (Cellini et al., <span>2010</span>; Choi, <span>2019</span>; Martorell et al., <span>2016</span>). An exception is Hong and Zimmer (<span>2016</span>), which found positive long-run effects on test scores in Michigan. Biasi et al. (<span>2024</span>) found generally positive effects of capital improvements on test scores, and Jackson and Mackevicius (<span>2024</span>) found generally positive effects of spending on student outcomes, as have studies that focused on particular targets of spending like air conditioning (Park et al., <span>2020</span>). These studies have consistently found positive, sometimes large, effects on house prices, suggesting that households care a great deal about school facilities and school quality.</p><p>Lastly, we contribute to a literature on the support for public goods in diverse communities. We show how the effects of the loosened electoral constraint differ by the racial makeup of the jurisdiction. A broad literature has found that diversity is related to decreased support for government (Alesina et al., <span>1999</span>; Dahlberg et al., <span>2012</span>). However, some of these findings are not robust to alternative specifications (Boustan et al., <span>2013</span>). Closely related to our work is Rugh and Trounstine (<span>2011</span>), which showed that more diverse cities propose fewer, larger municipal bonds than less diverse cities but end up authorizing similar levels of debt. The strategic proposals they documented could drive the differential response to the policy change we study. Recent work has shown that increased diversity among local elected officials results in less spending on public goods (Beach &amp; Jones, <span>2017</span>). Our results suggest that in more diverse places, elected officials would prefer a higher level of spending than the voters.</p><p>The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the following section, we provide further detail about local government funding and the policy change we study; in “Conceptual Framework” we describe our model; in “Data” we describe the data we use; in “Empirical Approach” we explain the empirical method; in “Results” we describe our results; and in “Conclusion” we conclude.</p><p>Our study focuses on funding for capital investments in local governments in California. Local governments with the power to tax include cities, school districts, community college districts, counties, and special districts that provide a particular service, such as airports, parks, water, and transit. In this section, we outline the options for these governments in generating revenue for investments.</p><p>Before describing the quantitative estimates of the effect of Proposition 39, we turn to a disagreement voting model to explore the implications of the policy change. The model shows how a change in the vote share required to pass a funding referendum can change the funding amounts that local politicians will propose, the probability that those referenda will prevail, and the resulting funding. In this section, we outline the model and describe the main results. Derivations and further details of the model are in Appendix Section A2.</p><p>Our model builds on the framework developed by Romer and Rosenthal (<span>1979, 1978</span>, <span>1982</span>), who studied the interaction between a bureaucrat with agenda setting powers and voters who must approve their decisions in referenda. We extend this model by studying the role of the voting thresholds that referenda are required to achieve. In this, our model is similar to Brunner and Ross (<span>2010</span>), who studied voting behavior on Proposition 39 itself.10</p><p>Our model considers the interaction between voters and a representative politician in setting a local government's expenditure on a public good. There is a status quo level of funding, denoted <i>g</i>. The politician has the option to make a proposal for additional spending on the public good. If the politician makes no proposal or if the proposal fails to receive the required support among voters, the status quo level of funding is implemented.</p><p>The voters desire a certain level of funding, denoted <i>θ</i>. The voter utility reflects their opinion on the value of the public good and the cost of the taxes that would be necessary to fund it. We assume voter utility declines symmetrically as the funding level diverges from the ideal point, with quadratic distance policy preferences given by −(<i>g</i> − <i>θ</i>)<sup>2</sup>.</p><p>We assume the politician's ideal funding is at least as much as what the voters desire. The politician's ideal level is <i>θ</i> + <i>b</i>, where <i>b</i> represents the disagreement between the politician and the voters. We assume that <i>b</i> is non-negative, which is consistent with the common justification of referendum requirements, that limiting the politician's authority will lower spending. When <i>b</i> is equal to zero there is no disagreement. As with the voters, the politician has preferences, −(<i>g</i> − <i>θ</i> − <i>b</i>)<sup>2,</sup> that are symmetric in the distance of the funding level from their ideal level of funding.</p><p>The sequence of events in the model is as follows. First, the politician chooses whether to propose a referendum to adopt a public good level, <i>g’</i>, rather than the reversion level, <i>g</i>. Should they decide against proposing a referendum, the reversion level is adopted. Conversely, if they propose a referendum, the voters then vote yes or no. If at least <i>v</i> share of voters vote in favor, then <i>g’</i> is adopted, where <i>v</i> is the vote share requirement, the focus of this paper. Otherwise, the status quo <i>g</i> is adopted. We assume that <i>v</i> is at least one half. Further, we assume that the politician's preferred level of the public good, <i>θ</i> + <i>b</i>, exceeds <i>g</i>. In order to introduce uncertainty in the outcomes of proposals, and hence allow the model to rationalize failed proposals, we assume that there are shocks to the voter preferences that the politician does not know at the time they make proposals. The probability that proposal <i>g’</i> will prevail given the vote share required is <i>p</i>(<i>g’</i>; <i>v</i>). Since politicians are uncertain whether any proposal they make would pass, they will choose their proposal so as to maximize their expected utility over the possible outcomes.</p><p>The policy change we study empirically is equivalent to a change in the vote requirement, <i>v</i>. We are interested in how changing <i>v</i> alters the proposed level of investment (<i>g’</i> − <i>g</i>), its likelihood of success (<i>p</i>(<i>g’</i>; <i>v</i>)), and the resulting public good levels, which we describe as the expected level of investment, <i>p</i>(<i>g’;v</i>)(<i>g’</i> − <i>g</i>).11</p><p>Table 1 describes the effect of a decrease in the vote requirement on each outcome when there is and is not disagreement between voters and the politician on the optimal level of provision. When the politician and voters prefer the same level of spending, a decrease in the threshold does not change the proposal or the fraction of votes in favor. Nevertheless, the probability of the proposal prevailing will increase and, as a result, the expected level of investment will also increase. When the politician prefers higher spending than the voter, a decrease in the threshold will result in larger proposals and, consequently, lower vote shares in favor. However, since the threshold is lower, the probability that the proposal prevails increases, leading to an increase in investment.</p><p>In sum, the model presents a framework for understanding the effect of a change in the vote requirement on the behavior of local politicians and voters. It shows how the policy change that we study affects the proposals made by politicians and how voters will vote on them. It has clear predictions for the importance of disagreement between voters and elected politicians.</p><p>We combine various sources of administrative and publicly available data on all public schools in California over the past 2 decades. Our main source of data is the set of all election results for all local measures in California between 1995 and 2016. These data, similar to what Cellini et al. (<span>2010</span>) and others have used, come from the California Election Data Archive (CEDA), a project of the Center for California Studies at California State University, Sacramento. We include elections from counties, municipalities, community college districts, and K–12 school districts. Our set of measures includes all those that would have authorized new, increased, or renewed taxes. Our main estimates are limited to only general obligation bonds, but we include other funding measures in robustness checks.12</p><p>For each measure in the CEDA dataset, we observe the full text of the ballot question, which includes the proposed dollar amounts for general obligation bonds. We also observe whether the measure passed and the number of votes for and against, from which we calculate the share of voters who voted for passage. During the period we study there were 4,520 tax-related measures. There are 10 different types of measures included among these: GO bonds, other bonds, business taxes, overrides of the Gann limit, Mello/Roos bonds, parcel taxes, sales taxes, transient occupancy (hotel) taxes, and utility taxes. Of all the measures, 2,075 (46%) were for GO bonds, which are the main measure we focus on in the primary analyses.</p><p>We complement the CEDA dataset with other sources of publicly available information. We use school- and district-level information on student demographics and proficiency on standardized tests from the Common Core of Data. We use Decennial Census information from 2000 for population counts, demographics, and socioeconomic characteristics of each local jurisdiction. Counts from the census are readily available for counties, municipalities, and school districts. Census tabulations are not available for community college districts, however. To produce counts of the number of residents in a community college district, we overlaid their current boundaries, available from the Foundation for California Community Colleges, with a map of census tracts. We then estimated the proportional overlap of tract-level population with the college districts.13</p><p>In sum, we create two analysis datasets. The first is a “jurisdiction-level” panel dataset. This panel consists of 1,589 jurisdiction-year observations from 1995 to 2016, comprising 977 K–12 districts, 482 cities, 72 community college districts, and 58 counties. For each observation, we observe the number of relevant elections held and passed, the number of GO bonds proposed and approved, and the amount of GO funding per capita proposed and approved.</p><p>The second dataset is an “election-level” dataset with the full set of 4,520 elections between 1995 and 2016. For these, we observe the jurisdiction, purpose, and vote share. Notably, this dataset includes GO bonds as well as the nine other types of measures.</p><p>Table 2 shows summary statistics of the jurisdiction-level panel, by jurisdiction type, prior to the passage of Proposition 39. Between 1995 and 2000, almost half of the school districts proposed a GO bond, as did one fifth of community college districts. The other jurisdictions in the sample—cities and counties—were much less likely to propose this type of funding. This makes sense given that these jurisdictions have a wider set of fundraising tools than school and community college districts. On the other hand, cities and counties were much more likely to put other types of funding proposals, primarily changes in parcel taxes, on the ballot. Passage rates of GO bonds and other elections did not vary across jurisdiction type. Education-related GO bonds tended to be much larger than the GO bonds proposed by counties and cities.</p><p>In this section, we describe our strategy to empirically investigate the effect of the change in vote requirements on the spending proposals made by the governments, the support the spending proposals received from voters, and the resulting capital spending of local governments. We use a difference-in-differences strategy to identify all effects. However, they require two different types of datasets. We first describe the unconditional approach, which we use to answer the questions regarding government proposals and funding outcomes. We then describe the approach we use to answer questions regarding voting, which conditions on local governments that proposed a bond.</p><p>We organize the results into three sections. First, we examine whether Proposition 39 changed the proposal behavior of school boards and community college districts in terms of their likelihood of proposing a GO bond, and the size of the proposals. This uses the methods described in “Estimating Effects on Government Behavior and Funding Outcomes.” Second, we ask whether the performance of GO bonds from educational jurisdictions changed as a result of Proposition 39. This uses the methods described in “Estimating Effects on Election Outcomes.” Third, we study the overall effects of Proposition 39 on funding outcomes, which combines the effect on government behavior and the effect on voting outcomes. This again uses the methods described in “Estimating Effects on Government Behavior and Funding Outcomes.” After discussing the main results we then move to heterogeneity analysis across jurisdiction types, and robustness checks.</p><p>In this paper, we analyze how a constitutional change to the voting threshold required for passing a school bond in California affected the share of voters who supported such bonds. We find that schools more than doubled their bond funding per resident due to the change. In addition, we show that governments were no more likely to propose a measure but are more likely to pass a general obligation bond due to the policy change. School bonds saw a drop of 6 percentage points in voter support following a decrease in the voting threshold by 11 percentage points from two thirds to 55%.</p><p>We interpret these results in the context of a political economy model of the interaction between a voter and an elected official. With no disagreement between voters and elected officials, a lowering of the vote share would not affect the proposals made. It would, however, increase the probability that they prevail. Yet, we do find an increase in both the proposals made and the probability that they prevail. This suggests that there is disagreement between the voters and the elected officials. The elected officials use their expanded flexibility to both request more spending and ensure that it passes with a higher probability. Together these result in a large increase in the amount of funding approved.</p><p>We note that our results should be interpreted with some deference to potential spillover effects. School districts share a common property tax base with the overlapping jurisdictions that were not subject to the policy change. Thus, changes in the tax rate imposed by school districts could affect voting behavior in these overlapping jurisdictions. For example, additional capital funding in a school district might make it less likely that voters would support higher tax rates for the city or county in which they live. If that were the case, the estimated treatment effects presented in the paper are the combination of these two effects, not simply the effect on the school districts.</p><p>Policies that limit the unilateral power of local elected officials and require tax policies to be approved via referendum are common throughout the United States. We study an incremental change in this requirement and show that it had large effects. Lowering the vote threshold worked as intended and more than doubled funding from GO bonds. However, the policy change did not expand the set of school districts that proposed a GO bond. In that sense, Proposition 39 likely increased funding among districts that would have proposed bonds even without the change. This occurred both because districts whose proposals may have failed saw them succeed and because districts proposed larger bonds.</p><p>The policy change did not have equal effects across all jurisdictions. Its effects were concentrated in jurisdictions that were not racially and ethnically homogenous. This suggests that relaxing or removing constraints on local elected leaders increases spending more in places with more diverse populations. Our analysis points to two possible reasons for why this may be. Elected officials in those places may have larger disagreements with referendum voters over their preferred level of spending or have less uncertainty over referendum outcomes.</p><p>These results have implications for policy discussions that involve changes to local tax limits. Some states frequently modify the terms of these limits. States change the latitude with which local officials can set policy without a voter referendum, in some cases through annual adjustments to allowable budget increases. States also change the rules for referenda, as in the case studied. Our results suggest that the details of how these policies are designed matter. It can affect the amount of funding that occurs, and hence taxes that residents must pay. Since it deferentially affects jurisdictions with different characteristics, it has important distributional consequences.</p>","PeriodicalId":48105,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Policy Analysis and Management","volume":"44 4","pages":"1394-1416"},"PeriodicalIF":2.4000,"publicationDate":"2025-05-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1002/pam.70023","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Relaxing electoral constraints in local education funding\",\"authors\":\"Michel Grosz,&nbsp;Ross Milton\",\"doi\":\"10.1002/pam.70023\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"<p>If voters do not like federal tax policy, they can elect new representatives. At the local level, though, voters can directly deny the tax increases their elected officials propose. All but three states have a limit on either the taxing or spending abilities of local governments and, most commonly, state laws require that increases in local taxes receive a public referendum before they are enacted (Mullins, <span>2010</span>). In the November 2020 election, voters nationwide decided on the fate of $52.7 billion of proposed funding, down from $70 billion 4 years prior (Pierog, <span>2020</span>).</p><p>Requirements that budgeting questions be put to a vote reduce the level of spending (Feld &amp; Matsusaka, <span>2003</span>; Funk &amp; Gathmann, <span>2011</span>). However, the rules that govern these votes vary in myriad ways. States differ in the types of taxes or spending the rules cover: Some only allow proposals for capital spending, while others also include current expenditure spending. States also often limit the total amount of tax revenue or the tax rate governments can propose, and vary in whether they adjust for inflation, for changes in population, or for growth in the property tax base. Certain election rules limit the timing of when governments can put proposals on the ballot, since local governments may use this timing flexibility strategically (Anzia, <span>2011</span>; Kogan et al., <span>2018</span>; Meredith, <span>2009</span>). States also differ in the vote share required to approve the proposals, with many proposals requiring more than a simple majority. There is little empirical research, however, documenting how these differences in voting requirements may affect government budgets, local spending, and the provision of public goods and services. This is a significant gap in the literature given the millions of dollars in funding at stake in each local referendum and the billions at stake nationwide.</p><p>In this paper, we study a proposition in California that weakened the constraints on some local governments by lowering the vote share required to approve capital funding for schools and community colleges. We use a difference-in-differences design around this policy change and data for over 4,000 local elections across the state over 2 decades. We estimate the effects of this policy change on the proposals made by affected districts, their outcomes at the ballot box, and on the eventual funding outcomes.</p><p>We develop a theoretical model of the interaction between a school board and voters, building on the literature in local political economy (Barseghyan &amp; Coate, <span>2014</span>; Coate &amp; Ma, <span>2017</span>; Romer &amp; Rosenthal, <span>1982</span>). In our model, the school board makes a tax proposal that the voter can accept or reject. Thus, the school board has “agenda-setting” power to extract policies closer to its preferences than those of the voter. However, uncertainty in how residents will vote hinders the exercise of this agenda-setting power. We use this model to show how a change in the required vote share affects the size of the proposals and the vote outcomes, and to show how these effects depend on the divergence in preferences between voters and elected officials.</p><p>We study how the policy change affected the funding outcomes of local governments. We find that Proposition 39 led to an additional $57 per resident in approved local government bonds, a more than 100% increase. This is a large impact, and one that affects governments unequally. There were larger effects on funding outcomes in more racially and ethnically diverse districts. Similarly, we find larger effects in jurisdictions with moderate levels of poverty, moderate White population shares, and fewer older residents. These results shed light on the characteristics of places where funding is most constrained by referendum requirements. Our model shows that the extent of a community's responsiveness to a change in the vote share requirement depends on the extent of disagreement between voters and their elected representatives, as well as the level of uncertainty in referenda outcomes that the elected officials face. Thus, the empirical results show what types of communities have larger disagreements or more uncertain election outcomes.</p><p>There are two channels through which these effects could occur: the behavior of elected officials when proposing funding and of voters when voting on the proposals. We find that the policy change made treated districts no more likely to propose a bond relative to other jurisdictions. However, the size of the bond proposals increased substantially, by $48 per resident, or a 59% increase. Naturally, the larger bond proposals may result in lower vote shares. Conditional on proposing a bond, we find that the policy change resulted in bond proposals receiving a lower percentage of votes in favor. However, this decline was smaller than the 11.7 percentage point decrease in the vote share requirement. In other words, school boards and community college districts experienced declines in support for their proposals that were smaller than the full amount of the policy change. Thus, we observe no change in the probability that affected districts approved any kind of new funding, and large increases in the probability that they approved new bonds. Even though these districts submitted larger proposals that had less support from the electorate, they resulted in increases in the probability of success. These results—a positive effect on proposal size and a negative effect on vote shares—are consistent with the politician preferring higher spending than the voters, when interpreted through the lens of our model.</p><p>Our paper contributes to several strands of research. First, we contribute to empirical evidence on the fiscal and policy effects of tax limits. This literature builds on the work of Romer and Rosenthal (<span>1978, 1979</span>, <span>1982</span>), which modeled the constraint on government in contexts where government officials have agenda setting power. Balsdon et al. (<span>2003</span>) applied the logic of these agenda-setting models to proposals of and voting on school bonds. The authors estimated a structural model of school boards and voters and found that school boards favor a higher level of spending than voters but are risk averse in their proposals. We extend this line of research by leveraging a policy change, and our finding that relaxing the voting threshold results in larger proposals is consistent with their result.</p><p>We also contribute to an empirical literature on the effects of tax limits on the quality of public services (Dye &amp; McGuire, <span>1997</span>; Figlio &amp; Rueben, <span>2001</span>; Poterba &amp; Rueben, <span>1995</span>; Rose, <span>2010</span>). These papers study the effect of the existence of local tax limits. By contrast, in this paper we study a change in a particular characteristic of the limit itself. Romer et al. (<span>1992</span>) shared that aim and considered the effects of matching aid and supermajority requirements in the context of their structural model. However, their data did not contain any heterogeneity in the vote requirements. We show that the vote share required to pass public spending has large effects on the amount of spending both proposed and implemented.</p><p>While this paper is the first to our knowledge to study the effects of the change in the voting threshold, two papers have studied voting on the constitutional amendment that resulted in this policy change. Brunner and Ross (<span>2010</span>) developed a model of voter support for supermajority rules and showed that voter support for the supermajority rules is related to the income distribution in their school district. Balsdon et al. (<span>2005</span>) showed that voters in metropolitan areas with a more fragmented set of school districts were more likely to vote for the reduction in the threshold. An existing literature has studied supermajority voting rules in the context of legislative voting (Crain &amp; Miller, <span>1989</span>; Messner &amp; Polborn, <span>2004</span>). Most related to our work is Knight (<span>2000</span>), which instrumented for supermajority requirements with the ease of amending state constitutions and found that supermajority requirements lead to lower taxes. This paper complements these analyses by examining the effect of a change in the severity of a supermajority requirement in the context of public referenda.</p><p>The environment of voting on school financing and the effect of the resulting funding has received significant study. Cerdán and Rueben (<span>2003</span>) detailed the history of school funding referenda in California. While we study the process of the school votes themselves, Cellini et al. (<span>2010</span>) studied the effects of the resulting capital investments on house prices and Cellini (<span>2009</span>) examined their effects on higher education. These papers are part of a broader literature that studies the effects of school construction; the evidence on its effect on student outcomes is mixed. Large school construction projects may lead to improved student outcomes (Aaronson &amp; Mazumder, <span>2011</span>; Conlin &amp; Thompson, <span>2017</span>; Duflo, <span>2001</span>; Neilson &amp; Zimmerman, <span>2014</span>). However, studies using regression discontinuity approaches to study school capital improvement bond referenda, like those we study, have found limited evidence of positive effects on student outcomes (Cellini et al., <span>2010</span>; Choi, <span>2019</span>; Martorell et al., <span>2016</span>). An exception is Hong and Zimmer (<span>2016</span>), which found positive long-run effects on test scores in Michigan. Biasi et al. (<span>2024</span>) found generally positive effects of capital improvements on test scores, and Jackson and Mackevicius (<span>2024</span>) found generally positive effects of spending on student outcomes, as have studies that focused on particular targets of spending like air conditioning (Park et al., <span>2020</span>). These studies have consistently found positive, sometimes large, effects on house prices, suggesting that households care a great deal about school facilities and school quality.</p><p>Lastly, we contribute to a literature on the support for public goods in diverse communities. We show how the effects of the loosened electoral constraint differ by the racial makeup of the jurisdiction. A broad literature has found that diversity is related to decreased support for government (Alesina et al., <span>1999</span>; Dahlberg et al., <span>2012</span>). However, some of these findings are not robust to alternative specifications (Boustan et al., <span>2013</span>). Closely related to our work is Rugh and Trounstine (<span>2011</span>), which showed that more diverse cities propose fewer, larger municipal bonds than less diverse cities but end up authorizing similar levels of debt. The strategic proposals they documented could drive the differential response to the policy change we study. Recent work has shown that increased diversity among local elected officials results in less spending on public goods (Beach &amp; Jones, <span>2017</span>). Our results suggest that in more diverse places, elected officials would prefer a higher level of spending than the voters.</p><p>The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the following section, we provide further detail about local government funding and the policy change we study; in “Conceptual Framework” we describe our model; in “Data” we describe the data we use; in “Empirical Approach” we explain the empirical method; in “Results” we describe our results; and in “Conclusion” we conclude.</p><p>Our study focuses on funding for capital investments in local governments in California. Local governments with the power to tax include cities, school districts, community college districts, counties, and special districts that provide a particular service, such as airports, parks, water, and transit. In this section, we outline the options for these governments in generating revenue for investments.</p><p>Before describing the quantitative estimates of the effect of Proposition 39, we turn to a disagreement voting model to explore the implications of the policy change. The model shows how a change in the vote share required to pass a funding referendum can change the funding amounts that local politicians will propose, the probability that those referenda will prevail, and the resulting funding. In this section, we outline the model and describe the main results. Derivations and further details of the model are in Appendix Section A2.</p><p>Our model builds on the framework developed by Romer and Rosenthal (<span>1979, 1978</span>, <span>1982</span>), who studied the interaction between a bureaucrat with agenda setting powers and voters who must approve their decisions in referenda. We extend this model by studying the role of the voting thresholds that referenda are required to achieve. In this, our model is similar to Brunner and Ross (<span>2010</span>), who studied voting behavior on Proposition 39 itself.10</p><p>Our model considers the interaction between voters and a representative politician in setting a local government's expenditure on a public good. There is a status quo level of funding, denoted <i>g</i>. The politician has the option to make a proposal for additional spending on the public good. If the politician makes no proposal or if the proposal fails to receive the required support among voters, the status quo level of funding is implemented.</p><p>The voters desire a certain level of funding, denoted <i>θ</i>. The voter utility reflects their opinion on the value of the public good and the cost of the taxes that would be necessary to fund it. We assume voter utility declines symmetrically as the funding level diverges from the ideal point, with quadratic distance policy preferences given by −(<i>g</i> − <i>θ</i>)<sup>2</sup>.</p><p>We assume the politician's ideal funding is at least as much as what the voters desire. The politician's ideal level is <i>θ</i> + <i>b</i>, where <i>b</i> represents the disagreement between the politician and the voters. We assume that <i>b</i> is non-negative, which is consistent with the common justification of referendum requirements, that limiting the politician's authority will lower spending. When <i>b</i> is equal to zero there is no disagreement. As with the voters, the politician has preferences, −(<i>g</i> − <i>θ</i> − <i>b</i>)<sup>2,</sup> that are symmetric in the distance of the funding level from their ideal level of funding.</p><p>The sequence of events in the model is as follows. First, the politician chooses whether to propose a referendum to adopt a public good level, <i>g’</i>, rather than the reversion level, <i>g</i>. Should they decide against proposing a referendum, the reversion level is adopted. Conversely, if they propose a referendum, the voters then vote yes or no. If at least <i>v</i> share of voters vote in favor, then <i>g’</i> is adopted, where <i>v</i> is the vote share requirement, the focus of this paper. Otherwise, the status quo <i>g</i> is adopted. We assume that <i>v</i> is at least one half. Further, we assume that the politician's preferred level of the public good, <i>θ</i> + <i>b</i>, exceeds <i>g</i>. In order to introduce uncertainty in the outcomes of proposals, and hence allow the model to rationalize failed proposals, we assume that there are shocks to the voter preferences that the politician does not know at the time they make proposals. The probability that proposal <i>g’</i> will prevail given the vote share required is <i>p</i>(<i>g’</i>; <i>v</i>). Since politicians are uncertain whether any proposal they make would pass, they will choose their proposal so as to maximize their expected utility over the possible outcomes.</p><p>The policy change we study empirically is equivalent to a change in the vote requirement, <i>v</i>. We are interested in how changing <i>v</i> alters the proposed level of investment (<i>g’</i> − <i>g</i>), its likelihood of success (<i>p</i>(<i>g’</i>; <i>v</i>)), and the resulting public good levels, which we describe as the expected level of investment, <i>p</i>(<i>g’;v</i>)(<i>g’</i> − <i>g</i>).11</p><p>Table 1 describes the effect of a decrease in the vote requirement on each outcome when there is and is not disagreement between voters and the politician on the optimal level of provision. When the politician and voters prefer the same level of spending, a decrease in the threshold does not change the proposal or the fraction of votes in favor. Nevertheless, the probability of the proposal prevailing will increase and, as a result, the expected level of investment will also increase. When the politician prefers higher spending than the voter, a decrease in the threshold will result in larger proposals and, consequently, lower vote shares in favor. However, since the threshold is lower, the probability that the proposal prevails increases, leading to an increase in investment.</p><p>In sum, the model presents a framework for understanding the effect of a change in the vote requirement on the behavior of local politicians and voters. It shows how the policy change that we study affects the proposals made by politicians and how voters will vote on them. It has clear predictions for the importance of disagreement between voters and elected politicians.</p><p>We combine various sources of administrative and publicly available data on all public schools in California over the past 2 decades. Our main source of data is the set of all election results for all local measures in California between 1995 and 2016. These data, similar to what Cellini et al. (<span>2010</span>) and others have used, come from the California Election Data Archive (CEDA), a project of the Center for California Studies at California State University, Sacramento. We include elections from counties, municipalities, community college districts, and K–12 school districts. Our set of measures includes all those that would have authorized new, increased, or renewed taxes. Our main estimates are limited to only general obligation bonds, but we include other funding measures in robustness checks.12</p><p>For each measure in the CEDA dataset, we observe the full text of the ballot question, which includes the proposed dollar amounts for general obligation bonds. We also observe whether the measure passed and the number of votes for and against, from which we calculate the share of voters who voted for passage. During the period we study there were 4,520 tax-related measures. There are 10 different types of measures included among these: GO bonds, other bonds, business taxes, overrides of the Gann limit, Mello/Roos bonds, parcel taxes, sales taxes, transient occupancy (hotel) taxes, and utility taxes. Of all the measures, 2,075 (46%) were for GO bonds, which are the main measure we focus on in the primary analyses.</p><p>We complement the CEDA dataset with other sources of publicly available information. We use school- and district-level information on student demographics and proficiency on standardized tests from the Common Core of Data. We use Decennial Census information from 2000 for population counts, demographics, and socioeconomic characteristics of each local jurisdiction. Counts from the census are readily available for counties, municipalities, and school districts. Census tabulations are not available for community college districts, however. To produce counts of the number of residents in a community college district, we overlaid their current boundaries, available from the Foundation for California Community Colleges, with a map of census tracts. We then estimated the proportional overlap of tract-level population with the college districts.13</p><p>In sum, we create two analysis datasets. The first is a “jurisdiction-level” panel dataset. This panel consists of 1,589 jurisdiction-year observations from 1995 to 2016, comprising 977 K–12 districts, 482 cities, 72 community college districts, and 58 counties. For each observation, we observe the number of relevant elections held and passed, the number of GO bonds proposed and approved, and the amount of GO funding per capita proposed and approved.</p><p>The second dataset is an “election-level” dataset with the full set of 4,520 elections between 1995 and 2016. For these, we observe the jurisdiction, purpose, and vote share. Notably, this dataset includes GO bonds as well as the nine other types of measures.</p><p>Table 2 shows summary statistics of the jurisdiction-level panel, by jurisdiction type, prior to the passage of Proposition 39. Between 1995 and 2000, almost half of the school districts proposed a GO bond, as did one fifth of community college districts. The other jurisdictions in the sample—cities and counties—were much less likely to propose this type of funding. This makes sense given that these jurisdictions have a wider set of fundraising tools than school and community college districts. On the other hand, cities and counties were much more likely to put other types of funding proposals, primarily changes in parcel taxes, on the ballot. Passage rates of GO bonds and other elections did not vary across jurisdiction type. Education-related GO bonds tended to be much larger than the GO bonds proposed by counties and cities.</p><p>In this section, we describe our strategy to empirically investigate the effect of the change in vote requirements on the spending proposals made by the governments, the support the spending proposals received from voters, and the resulting capital spending of local governments. We use a difference-in-differences strategy to identify all effects. However, they require two different types of datasets. We first describe the unconditional approach, which we use to answer the questions regarding government proposals and funding outcomes. We then describe the approach we use to answer questions regarding voting, which conditions on local governments that proposed a bond.</p><p>We organize the results into three sections. First, we examine whether Proposition 39 changed the proposal behavior of school boards and community college districts in terms of their likelihood of proposing a GO bond, and the size of the proposals. This uses the methods described in “Estimating Effects on Government Behavior and Funding Outcomes.” Second, we ask whether the performance of GO bonds from educational jurisdictions changed as a result of Proposition 39. This uses the methods described in “Estimating Effects on Election Outcomes.” Third, we study the overall effects of Proposition 39 on funding outcomes, which combines the effect on government behavior and the effect on voting outcomes. This again uses the methods described in “Estimating Effects on Government Behavior and Funding Outcomes.” After discussing the main results we then move to heterogeneity analysis across jurisdiction types, and robustness checks.</p><p>In this paper, we analyze how a constitutional change to the voting threshold required for passing a school bond in California affected the share of voters who supported such bonds. We find that schools more than doubled their bond funding per resident due to the change. In addition, we show that governments were no more likely to propose a measure but are more likely to pass a general obligation bond due to the policy change. School bonds saw a drop of 6 percentage points in voter support following a decrease in the voting threshold by 11 percentage points from two thirds to 55%.</p><p>We interpret these results in the context of a political economy model of the interaction between a voter and an elected official. With no disagreement between voters and elected officials, a lowering of the vote share would not affect the proposals made. It would, however, increase the probability that they prevail. Yet, we do find an increase in both the proposals made and the probability that they prevail. This suggests that there is disagreement between the voters and the elected officials. The elected officials use their expanded flexibility to both request more spending and ensure that it passes with a higher probability. Together these result in a large increase in the amount of funding approved.</p><p>We note that our results should be interpreted with some deference to potential spillover effects. School districts share a common property tax base with the overlapping jurisdictions that were not subject to the policy change. Thus, changes in the tax rate imposed by school districts could affect voting behavior in these overlapping jurisdictions. For example, additional capital funding in a school district might make it less likely that voters would support higher tax rates for the city or county in which they live. If that were the case, the estimated treatment effects presented in the paper are the combination of these two effects, not simply the effect on the school districts.</p><p>Policies that limit the unilateral power of local elected officials and require tax policies to be approved via referendum are common throughout the United States. We study an incremental change in this requirement and show that it had large effects. Lowering the vote threshold worked as intended and more than doubled funding from GO bonds. However, the policy change did not expand the set of school districts that proposed a GO bond. In that sense, Proposition 39 likely increased funding among districts that would have proposed bonds even without the change. This occurred both because districts whose proposals may have failed saw them succeed and because districts proposed larger bonds.</p><p>The policy change did not have equal effects across all jurisdictions. Its effects were concentrated in jurisdictions that were not racially and ethnically homogenous. This suggests that relaxing or removing constraints on local elected leaders increases spending more in places with more diverse populations. Our analysis points to two possible reasons for why this may be. Elected officials in those places may have larger disagreements with referendum voters over their preferred level of spending or have less uncertainty over referendum outcomes.</p><p>These results have implications for policy discussions that involve changes to local tax limits. Some states frequently modify the terms of these limits. States change the latitude with which local officials can set policy without a voter referendum, in some cases through annual adjustments to allowable budget increases. States also change the rules for referenda, as in the case studied. Our results suggest that the details of how these policies are designed matter. It can affect the amount of funding that occurs, and hence taxes that residents must pay. Since it deferentially affects jurisdictions with different characteristics, it has important distributional consequences.</p>\",\"PeriodicalId\":48105,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Journal of Policy Analysis and Management\",\"volume\":\"44 4\",\"pages\":\"1394-1416\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":2.4000,\"publicationDate\":\"2025-05-27\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1002/pam.70023\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Journal of Policy Analysis and Management\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"91\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/pam.70023\",\"RegionNum\":3,\"RegionCategory\":\"管理学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q2\",\"JCRName\":\"ECONOMICS\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of Policy Analysis and Management","FirstCategoryId":"91","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1002/pam.70023","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"管理学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

如果选民不喜欢联邦税收政策,他们可以选举新的代表。然而,在地方一级,选民可以直接拒绝他们选出的官员提出的增税提议。除了三个州外,所有州都对地方政府的征税或支出能力有限制,而且,最常见的是,州法律要求地方税收的增加在颁布之前必须经过公民投票(Mullins, 2010)。在2020年11月的选举中,全国选民决定了527亿美元拟议资金的命运,低于4年前的700亿美元(Pierog, 2020)。对预算问题进行投票的要求降低了支出水平(Feld & Matsusaka, 2003; Funk & Gathmann, 2011)。然而,管理这些投票的规则千差万别。各州的税收或支出类型不同:一些州只允许资本支出提案,而另一些州也包括经常性支出支出。各州还经常限制税收总额或政府可以提出的税率,并且在是否根据通货膨胀、人口变化或财产税基数的增长进行调整方面有所不同。某些选举规则限制了政府将提案提交投票的时间,因为地方政府可能会战略性地利用这种时间灵活性(Anzia, 2011; Kogan et al., 2018; Meredith, 2009)。各国批准提案所需的投票份额也各不相同,许多提案需要的不仅仅是简单多数。然而,很少有实证研究记录这些投票要求的差异如何影响政府预算、地方支出以及公共产品和服务的提供。鉴于每次地方公投涉及数百万美元的资金,而在全国范围内涉及数十亿美元的资金,这是文献中的一个重大空白。在本文中,我们研究了加利福尼亚州的一项提案,该提案通过降低批准学校和社区学院资本资金所需的投票份额来削弱对一些地方政府的约束。我们采用了一种差异中差异的设计,围绕这一政策变化和20年来全州4000多个地方选举的数据。我们估计这一政策变化对受影响地区的提案、他们在投票箱中的结果以及最终的资助结果的影响。我们基于地方政治经济学的文献(Barseghyan & Coate, 2014; Coate & Ma, 2017; Romer & Rosenthal, 1982),建立了一个关于学校董事会和选民之间互动的理论模型。在我们的模型中,学校董事会提出一项税收提案,选民可以接受或拒绝。因此,学校董事会拥有“议程设置”的权力,可以制定出比选民更接近自己偏好的政策。然而,居民如何投票的不确定性阻碍了这种议程设定权力的行使。我们使用该模型来显示所需投票份额的变化如何影响提案的大小和投票结果,并显示这些影响如何取决于选民和当选官员之间的偏好差异。我们研究了政策变化对地方政府融资结果的影响。我们发现,39号提案导致每个居民在批准的地方政府债券上增加了57美元,增幅超过100%。这是一个巨大的影响,而且对政府的影响是不平等的。在种族和民族更多样化的地区,对资助结果的影响更大。同样,我们发现,在贫困程度适中、白人人口比例适中、老年居民较少的司法管辖区,这种影响更大。这些结果揭示了资金最受公民投票要求限制的地方的特点。我们的模型表明,一个社区对投票权份额要求变化的反应程度取决于选民与其当选代表之间的分歧程度,以及当选官员面临的公投结果的不确定性程度。因此,实证结果显示了哪种类型的社区有更大的分歧或更不确定的选举结果。这些影响可能通过两个渠道产生:当选官员在提议拨款时的行为,以及选民在对提议进行投票时的行为。我们发现,政策的变化使得被处理的地区不太可能提出相对于其他司法管辖区的债券。然而,债券提案的规模大幅增加,每位居民增加了48美元,即增加了59%。当然,更大的债券提案可能导致更低的投票权。在提出债券的条件下,我们发现政策变化导致债券提案获得较低的赞成率。不过,这一降幅小于投票份额要求11.7个百分点的降幅。 换句话说,学校董事会和社区大学学区的提案支持率下降,而这些提案的支持率低于政策变化的全部金额。因此,我们观察到受影响地区批准任何新资金的概率没有变化,而它们批准新债券的概率大幅增加。尽管这些地区提交的提案规模较大,选民支持较少,但成功的可能性有所增加。这些结果——对提案规模的积极影响和对投票份额的消极影响——与政治家比选民更倾向于更高的支出是一致的,当通过我们的模型来解释时。我们的论文对几方面的研究都有贡献。首先,我们提供了关于税收限制的财政和政策影响的经验证据。这些文献建立在Romer和Rosenthal(1978, 1979, 1982)的工作基础上,他们在政府官员拥有议程设定权的背景下对政府的约束进行了建模。Balsdon et al.(2003)将这些议程设置模型的逻辑应用于学校债券的提案和投票。作者估计了学校董事会和选民的结构模型,发现学校董事会比选民更倾向于更高的支出水平,但在他们的提议中却规避风险。我们通过利用政策变化来扩展这条研究线,我们发现放宽投票门槛会导致更大的提案,这与他们的结果是一致的。我们还撰写了关于税收限制对公共服务质量影响的实证文献(Dye & McGuire, 1997; Figlio & Rueben, 2001; Poterba & Rueben, 1995; Rose, 2010)。这些论文研究了地方税限额存在的影响。与此相反,本文研究了极限本身某一特性的变化。Romer等人(1992)分享了这一目标,并在其结构模型的背景下考虑了匹配援助和绝对多数要求的影响。但是,他们的数据在投票要求方面没有任何异质性。我们表明,通过公共支出所需的投票份额对提议和实施的支出都有很大的影响。虽然这篇论文是我们所知的第一篇研究投票门槛变化影响的论文,但有两篇论文研究了导致这一政策变化的宪法修正案的投票情况。Brunner和Ross(2010)建立了一个选民对绝对多数规则的支持模型,并表明选民对绝对多数规则的支持与其所在学区的收入分配有关。Balsdon等人(2005)表明,在学区较为分散的大都市地区,选民更有可能投票支持降低门槛。现有文献研究了立法投票背景下的绝对多数投票规则(Crain & Miller, 1989; Messner & Polborn, 2004)。与我们的工作最相关的是Knight(2000),他利用修改州宪法的便利来实现绝对多数要求,并发现绝对多数要求会导致税收降低。本文通过研究在公民投票背景下绝对多数要求的严重程度变化的影响来补充这些分析。对学校融资的投票环境和由此产生的资金效果进行了大量的研究。Cerdán和Rueben(2003)详细介绍了加州学校经费公投的历史。当我们研究学校投票本身的过程时,Cellini等人(2010)研究了由此产生的资本投资对房价的影响,Cellini(2009)研究了它们对高等教育的影响。这些论文是研究学校建设影响的更广泛文献的一部分;有关它对学生成绩影响的证据好坏参半。大型学校建设项目可能会改善学生的学习成绩(Aaronson & Mazumder, 2011; Conlin & Thompson, 2017; Duflo, 2001; Neilson & Zimmerman, 2014)。然而,与我们的研究一样,使用回归不连续方法研究学校资本改善债券公投的研究发现,对学生成绩产生积极影响的证据有限(Cellini等人,2010;Choi, 2019; Martorell等人,2016)。Hong和Zimmer(2016)是一个例外,他们发现密歇根州的考试成绩存在积极的长期影响。Biasi等人(2024)发现资本改善对考试成绩的总体积极影响,Jackson和Mackevicius(2024)发现支出对学生成绩的总体积极影响,专注于空调等特定支出目标的研究(Park等人,2020)也是如此。这些研究一致发现了对房价的积极影响,有时是很大的影响,这表明家庭非常关心学校设施和学校质量。 最后,我们撰写了一篇关于不同社区对公共产品支持的文献。我们展示了放松选举约束的影响如何因司法管辖区的种族构成而有所不同。大量文献发现,多样性与政府支持率下降有关(Alesina et al., 1999; Dahlberg et al., 2012)。然而,其中一些发现并不适用于其他规范(Boustan et al., 2013)。与我们的工作密切相关的是Rugh和Trounstine(2011),该研究表明,与多元化程度较低的城市相比,多元化程度较高的城市提出的市政债券数量较少,规模较大,但最终授权的债务水平相似。他们所记录的战略建议可以推动对我们所研究的政策变化的不同反应。最近的研究表明,地方民选官员的多样性增加导致公共产品支出减少(Beach & Jones, 2017)。我们的研究结果表明,在更多样化的地方,民选官员比选民更喜欢更高的支出水平。本文的其余部分组织如下。在下一节中,我们将提供有关地方政府资助和我们研究的政策变化的进一步细节;在“概念框架”中,我们描述了我们的模型;在“数据”中,我们描述了我们使用的数据;在“实证方法”中,我们解释了实证方法;在“结果”中,我们描述了我们的结果;在“结论”中,我们得出结论。我们的研究重点是加州地方政府的资本投资资金。拥有征税权的地方政府包括市、学区、社区大学区、县和提供机场、公园、水、交通等特定服务的特区。在本节中,我们概述了这些政府在为投资创造收入方面的选择。在描述39号提案影响的定量估计之前,我们转向一个分歧投票模型来探索政策变化的影响。该模型显示了通过拨款公投所需的投票份额的变化如何改变地方政客提出的拨款数额、公投获胜的可能性以及由此产生的拨款。在本节中,我们概述了模型并描述了主要结果。该模型的推导和进一步细节见附录章节A2。我们的模型建立在Romer和Rosenthal(1979,1978, 1982)开发的框架之上,他们研究了具有议程设定权力的官僚与必须在公民投票中批准其决定的选民之间的相互作用。我们通过研究全民公决需要达到的投票阈值的作用来扩展这个模型。在这一点上,我们的模型与Brunner和Ross(2010)相似,他们研究了39号提案本身的投票行为。我们的模型考虑了选民与代议制政治家在设定地方政府公共产品支出时的相互作用。政治家可以选择为公共利益提出增加开支的建议。如果政治家没有提出提案,或者提案未能获得选民所需的支持,则执行现有的资金水平。选民希望得到一定程度的资助,用θ表示。选民效用反映了他们对公共产品价值的看法,以及为公共产品提供资金所需的税收成本。我们假设选民效用随着资助水平偏离理想点而对称下降,政策偏好为- (g−θ)2给出的二次距离。我们假设政治家的理想资金至少与选民所希望的一样多。政治家的理想水平是θ + b,其中b代表政治家与选民之间的分歧。我们假设b是非负的,这与公民投票要求的一般理由一致,即限制政治家的权威将降低支出。当b = 0时,没有分歧。与选民一样,政治家的偏好是−(g−θ−b)2,这与他们理想的资助水平之间的距离是对称的。模型中的事件顺序如下:首先,政治家选择是否提议全民公决采用公共产品水平g’,而不是回归水平g。如果他们决定不提议全民公决,则采用回归水平g。相反,如果他们提议举行全民公决,选民就会投票赞成或反对。如果至少有v份额的选民投票赞成,则采用g ',其中v为投票份额要求,这是本文的重点。否则,保持现状。我们假设v至少是1 / 2。进一步,我们假设政治家对公共产品的偏好水平θ + b超过g。 为了引入提案结果的不确定性,从而允许模型合理化失败的提案,我们假设选民的偏好受到冲击,而政治家在提出提案时并不知道这些冲击。鉴于所需的投票份额,提案g ‘获得通过的概率为p(g ’; v)。由于政治家们不确定他们提出的任何提案是否会通过,他们会选择他们的提案,以最大限度地提高他们对可能结果的预期效用。我们经验研究的政策变化相当于投票要求的变化,v。我们感兴趣的是改变v如何改变建议的投资水平(g ' - g),其成功的可能性(p(g '; v)),以及由此产生的公共产品水平,我们将其描述为预期的投资水平,p(g '; v);v)(g′−g).11表1描述了当选民和政治家之间在最优供给水平上存在分歧或不存在分歧时,投票要求减少对每种结果的影响。当政治家和选民倾向于相同的支出水平时,降低门槛不会改变提案或支持的选票比例。然而,提案获得通过的可能性会增加,因此,预期的投资水平也会增加。当政治家比选民更喜欢更高的支出时,降低门槛将导致更大的提案,从而降低赞成的投票份额。但是,由于门槛较低,提案通过的可能性增加,从而导致投资增加。总而言之,该模型提供了一个框架,用于理解投票要求变化对地方政治家和选民行为的影响。它显示了我们研究的政策变化如何影响政治家提出的建议,以及选民将如何对这些建议投票。它清楚地预测了选民和当选政客之间分歧的重要性。我们综合了过去20年加州所有公立学校的各种行政和公开数据来源。我们的主要数据来源是1995年至2016年间加州所有地方措施的所有选举结果集。这些数据与Cellini et al.(2010)等人使用的数据类似,来自加州选举数据档案(CEDA),这是萨克拉门托加州州立大学加州研究中心的一个项目。我们包括县、市、社区大学学区和K-12学区的选举。我们的一套措施包括所有那些将批准新的、增加的或更新的税收。我们的主要估计仅限于一般义务债券,但我们在稳健性检查中纳入了其他融资措施。12 .对于CEDA数据集中的每项措施,我们观察了投票问题的全文,其中包括一般义务债券的拟议美元金额。我们还观察该措施是否通过,以及赞成和反对的票数,从中我们计算投票通过的选民的比例。在我们研究期间,有4520项与税收相关的措施。其中包括GO债券、其他债券、营业税、超过江恩限额的债券、梅洛/鲁斯债券、包裹税、销售税、临时入住(酒店)税、公用事业税等10种不同的措施。在所有措施中,2075(46%)是GO债券,这是我们在主要分析中关注的主要措施。我们用其他公开信息来源补充了CEDA数据集。我们使用学校和学区层面的学生人口统计信息以及来自共同核心数据的标准化测试的熟练程度。我们使用2000年以来每十年一次的人口普查信息来统计每个地方辖区的人口数量、人口统计和社会经济特征。县、市和学区的人口普查数据很容易获得。然而,社区大学学区的人口普查数据还没有公布。为了计算一个社区学院区居民的数量,我们用一张人口普查区地图覆盖了加州社区学院基金会(Foundation for California community Colleges)提供的现有边界。然后,我们估计了地区人口与大学学区的重叠比例。总之,我们创建了两个分析数据集。第一个是“司法管辖区”面板数据集。该小组由1995年至2016年的1589个司法管辖区的观察结果组成,包括977个K-12区,482个城市,72个社区学院区和58个县。对于每一次观察,我们观察相关选举的举行次数和通过次数、提出和批准的政府债券数量、提出和批准的人均政府资金数额。第二个数据集是“选举级别”数据集,包含1995年至2016年期间的4520次选举的全部数据集。 对于这些,我们遵守管辖权、目的和投票权。值得注意的是,该数据集包括政府债券以及其他九种类型的指标。表2显示了在第39号提案通过之前,按管辖权类型划分的管辖权级小组的汇总统计数据。1995年至2000年间,几乎有一半的学区和五分之一的社区学院学区提出了政府债券。样本城市和县的其他司法管辖区提出这种资助的可能性要小得多。考虑到这些辖区比学校和社区大学辖区拥有更广泛的筹款工具,这是有道理的。另一方面,城市和县更有可能把其他类型的资金提案,主要是改变包裹税,放在投票上。政府债券和其他选举的通过率没有因司法管辖区类型而异。与教育相关的政府债券规模往往远大于县市政府债券。在本节中,我们描述了我们的策略,以实证调查投票要求的变化对政府提出的支出提案、选民对支出提案的支持以及由此产生的地方政府资本支出的影响。我们使用差异中的差异策略来识别所有影响。然而,它们需要两种不同类型的数据集。我们首先描述无条件方法,我们用它来回答有关政府提案和资助结果的问题。然后,我们描述了我们用来回答有关投票的问题的方法,即提出债券的地方政府的条件。我们将结果分成三个部分。首先,我们考察了第39号提案是否改变了学校董事会和社区大学学区提出GO债券的可能性,以及提案的规模。这使用了“评估对政府行为和资助结果的影响”中描述的方法。其次,我们询问39号提案是否改变了教育辖区政府债券的绩效。这使用了“估计对选举结果的影响”中描述的方法。第三,我们研究了39号提案对拨款结果的整体影响,它结合了对政府行为的影响和对投票结果的影响。这再次使用了“评估对政府行为和资助结果的影响”中描述的方法。在讨论了主要结果之后,我们将转向跨司法管辖区类型的异质性分析和稳健性检查。在本文中,我们分析了宪法对通过加州学校债券所需的投票门槛的改变如何影响支持这种债券的选民比例。我们发现,由于这一变化,学校的人均债券资金增加了一倍多。此外,我们表明,由于政策变化,政府不太可能提出一项措施,而是更有可能通过一般义务债券。在投票门槛从三分之二下降到55%之后,学校债券的选民支持率下降了6个百分点。我们在选民和当选官员之间互动的政治经济模型的背景下解释这些结果。由于选民和当选官员之间没有分歧,降低投票份额不会影响所提出的建议。然而,这将增加他们获胜的可能性。然而,我们确实发现提出的建议和它们获得通过的可能性都有所增加。这表明选民和当选官员之间存在分歧。民选官员利用他们扩大的灵活性,既要求更多的支出,又确保该法案更有可能通过。这些因素共同导致核准的资金数额大幅增加。我们注意到,在解释我们的研究结果时,应考虑到潜在的溢出效应。学区与重叠的辖区共享一个共同的财产税税基,这些辖区不受政策变化的影响。因此,学区税率的变化可能会影响这些重叠辖区的投票行为。例如,为学区提供额外的资金可能会使选民不太可能支持他们所居住的城市或县提高税率。如果是这样的话,论文中提出的估计治疗效果是这两种效果的结合,而不仅仅是对学区的影响。限制地方民选官员单方面权力和要求税收政策通过全民公决的政策在美国很常见。我们研究了这个需求的增量变化,并表明它有很大的影响。降低投票门槛起到了预期的作用,来自政府债券的资金增加了一倍多。 然而,这一政策变化并没有扩大提出GO债券的学区。从这个意义上说,39号提案可能会增加那些即使没有改变也会提出债券的地区的资金。这种情况的发生,一方面是因为那些提案可能失败的地区却成功了,另一方面是因为地区提出了更大的债券。政策变化对所有司法管辖区的影响并不相同。其影响主要集中在种族和民族不统一的司法管辖区。这表明,放松或取消对地方民选领导人的限制,会在人口更多样化的地方增加更多的支出。我们的分析指出了两个可能的原因。这些地方的民选官员可能在他们偏好的支出水平上与公投选民有更大的分歧,或者对公投结果的不确定性更小。这些结果对涉及改变地方税收限制的政策讨论具有启示意义。一些州经常修改这些限制的条款。各州改变了地方官员制定政策的自由度,而无需选民投票,在某些情况下,通过每年调整可允许的预算增长。正如上述案例所示,各州也会改变全民公决的规则。我们的研究结果表明,如何设计这些政策的细节很重要。它会影响到发生的资金数量,从而影响到居民必须支付的税收。由于它恭恭敬敬地影响不同特征的司法管辖区,它具有重要的分配后果。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。

Relaxing electoral constraints in local education funding

Relaxing electoral constraints in local education funding

If voters do not like federal tax policy, they can elect new representatives. At the local level, though, voters can directly deny the tax increases their elected officials propose. All but three states have a limit on either the taxing or spending abilities of local governments and, most commonly, state laws require that increases in local taxes receive a public referendum before they are enacted (Mullins, 2010). In the November 2020 election, voters nationwide decided on the fate of $52.7 billion of proposed funding, down from $70 billion 4 years prior (Pierog, 2020).

Requirements that budgeting questions be put to a vote reduce the level of spending (Feld & Matsusaka, 2003; Funk & Gathmann, 2011). However, the rules that govern these votes vary in myriad ways. States differ in the types of taxes or spending the rules cover: Some only allow proposals for capital spending, while others also include current expenditure spending. States also often limit the total amount of tax revenue or the tax rate governments can propose, and vary in whether they adjust for inflation, for changes in population, or for growth in the property tax base. Certain election rules limit the timing of when governments can put proposals on the ballot, since local governments may use this timing flexibility strategically (Anzia, 2011; Kogan et al., 2018; Meredith, 2009). States also differ in the vote share required to approve the proposals, with many proposals requiring more than a simple majority. There is little empirical research, however, documenting how these differences in voting requirements may affect government budgets, local spending, and the provision of public goods and services. This is a significant gap in the literature given the millions of dollars in funding at stake in each local referendum and the billions at stake nationwide.

In this paper, we study a proposition in California that weakened the constraints on some local governments by lowering the vote share required to approve capital funding for schools and community colleges. We use a difference-in-differences design around this policy change and data for over 4,000 local elections across the state over 2 decades. We estimate the effects of this policy change on the proposals made by affected districts, their outcomes at the ballot box, and on the eventual funding outcomes.

We develop a theoretical model of the interaction between a school board and voters, building on the literature in local political economy (Barseghyan & Coate, 2014; Coate & Ma, 2017; Romer & Rosenthal, 1982). In our model, the school board makes a tax proposal that the voter can accept or reject. Thus, the school board has “agenda-setting” power to extract policies closer to its preferences than those of the voter. However, uncertainty in how residents will vote hinders the exercise of this agenda-setting power. We use this model to show how a change in the required vote share affects the size of the proposals and the vote outcomes, and to show how these effects depend on the divergence in preferences between voters and elected officials.

We study how the policy change affected the funding outcomes of local governments. We find that Proposition 39 led to an additional $57 per resident in approved local government bonds, a more than 100% increase. This is a large impact, and one that affects governments unequally. There were larger effects on funding outcomes in more racially and ethnically diverse districts. Similarly, we find larger effects in jurisdictions with moderate levels of poverty, moderate White population shares, and fewer older residents. These results shed light on the characteristics of places where funding is most constrained by referendum requirements. Our model shows that the extent of a community's responsiveness to a change in the vote share requirement depends on the extent of disagreement between voters and their elected representatives, as well as the level of uncertainty in referenda outcomes that the elected officials face. Thus, the empirical results show what types of communities have larger disagreements or more uncertain election outcomes.

There are two channels through which these effects could occur: the behavior of elected officials when proposing funding and of voters when voting on the proposals. We find that the policy change made treated districts no more likely to propose a bond relative to other jurisdictions. However, the size of the bond proposals increased substantially, by $48 per resident, or a 59% increase. Naturally, the larger bond proposals may result in lower vote shares. Conditional on proposing a bond, we find that the policy change resulted in bond proposals receiving a lower percentage of votes in favor. However, this decline was smaller than the 11.7 percentage point decrease in the vote share requirement. In other words, school boards and community college districts experienced declines in support for their proposals that were smaller than the full amount of the policy change. Thus, we observe no change in the probability that affected districts approved any kind of new funding, and large increases in the probability that they approved new bonds. Even though these districts submitted larger proposals that had less support from the electorate, they resulted in increases in the probability of success. These results—a positive effect on proposal size and a negative effect on vote shares—are consistent with the politician preferring higher spending than the voters, when interpreted through the lens of our model.

Our paper contributes to several strands of research. First, we contribute to empirical evidence on the fiscal and policy effects of tax limits. This literature builds on the work of Romer and Rosenthal (1978, 1979, 1982), which modeled the constraint on government in contexts where government officials have agenda setting power. Balsdon et al. (2003) applied the logic of these agenda-setting models to proposals of and voting on school bonds. The authors estimated a structural model of school boards and voters and found that school boards favor a higher level of spending than voters but are risk averse in their proposals. We extend this line of research by leveraging a policy change, and our finding that relaxing the voting threshold results in larger proposals is consistent with their result.

We also contribute to an empirical literature on the effects of tax limits on the quality of public services (Dye & McGuire, 1997; Figlio & Rueben, 2001; Poterba & Rueben, 1995; Rose, 2010). These papers study the effect of the existence of local tax limits. By contrast, in this paper we study a change in a particular characteristic of the limit itself. Romer et al. (1992) shared that aim and considered the effects of matching aid and supermajority requirements in the context of their structural model. However, their data did not contain any heterogeneity in the vote requirements. We show that the vote share required to pass public spending has large effects on the amount of spending both proposed and implemented.

While this paper is the first to our knowledge to study the effects of the change in the voting threshold, two papers have studied voting on the constitutional amendment that resulted in this policy change. Brunner and Ross (2010) developed a model of voter support for supermajority rules and showed that voter support for the supermajority rules is related to the income distribution in their school district. Balsdon et al. (2005) showed that voters in metropolitan areas with a more fragmented set of school districts were more likely to vote for the reduction in the threshold. An existing literature has studied supermajority voting rules in the context of legislative voting (Crain & Miller, 1989; Messner & Polborn, 2004). Most related to our work is Knight (2000), which instrumented for supermajority requirements with the ease of amending state constitutions and found that supermajority requirements lead to lower taxes. This paper complements these analyses by examining the effect of a change in the severity of a supermajority requirement in the context of public referenda.

The environment of voting on school financing and the effect of the resulting funding has received significant study. Cerdán and Rueben (2003) detailed the history of school funding referenda in California. While we study the process of the school votes themselves, Cellini et al. (2010) studied the effects of the resulting capital investments on house prices and Cellini (2009) examined their effects on higher education. These papers are part of a broader literature that studies the effects of school construction; the evidence on its effect on student outcomes is mixed. Large school construction projects may lead to improved student outcomes (Aaronson & Mazumder, 2011; Conlin & Thompson, 2017; Duflo, 2001; Neilson & Zimmerman, 2014). However, studies using regression discontinuity approaches to study school capital improvement bond referenda, like those we study, have found limited evidence of positive effects on student outcomes (Cellini et al., 2010; Choi, 2019; Martorell et al., 2016). An exception is Hong and Zimmer (2016), which found positive long-run effects on test scores in Michigan. Biasi et al. (2024) found generally positive effects of capital improvements on test scores, and Jackson and Mackevicius (2024) found generally positive effects of spending on student outcomes, as have studies that focused on particular targets of spending like air conditioning (Park et al., 2020). These studies have consistently found positive, sometimes large, effects on house prices, suggesting that households care a great deal about school facilities and school quality.

Lastly, we contribute to a literature on the support for public goods in diverse communities. We show how the effects of the loosened electoral constraint differ by the racial makeup of the jurisdiction. A broad literature has found that diversity is related to decreased support for government (Alesina et al., 1999; Dahlberg et al., 2012). However, some of these findings are not robust to alternative specifications (Boustan et al., 2013). Closely related to our work is Rugh and Trounstine (2011), which showed that more diverse cities propose fewer, larger municipal bonds than less diverse cities but end up authorizing similar levels of debt. The strategic proposals they documented could drive the differential response to the policy change we study. Recent work has shown that increased diversity among local elected officials results in less spending on public goods (Beach & Jones, 2017). Our results suggest that in more diverse places, elected officials would prefer a higher level of spending than the voters.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the following section, we provide further detail about local government funding and the policy change we study; in “Conceptual Framework” we describe our model; in “Data” we describe the data we use; in “Empirical Approach” we explain the empirical method; in “Results” we describe our results; and in “Conclusion” we conclude.

Our study focuses on funding for capital investments in local governments in California. Local governments with the power to tax include cities, school districts, community college districts, counties, and special districts that provide a particular service, such as airports, parks, water, and transit. In this section, we outline the options for these governments in generating revenue for investments.

Before describing the quantitative estimates of the effect of Proposition 39, we turn to a disagreement voting model to explore the implications of the policy change. The model shows how a change in the vote share required to pass a funding referendum can change the funding amounts that local politicians will propose, the probability that those referenda will prevail, and the resulting funding. In this section, we outline the model and describe the main results. Derivations and further details of the model are in Appendix Section A2.

Our model builds on the framework developed by Romer and Rosenthal (1979, 1978, 1982), who studied the interaction between a bureaucrat with agenda setting powers and voters who must approve their decisions in referenda. We extend this model by studying the role of the voting thresholds that referenda are required to achieve. In this, our model is similar to Brunner and Ross (2010), who studied voting behavior on Proposition 39 itself.10

Our model considers the interaction between voters and a representative politician in setting a local government's expenditure on a public good. There is a status quo level of funding, denoted g. The politician has the option to make a proposal for additional spending on the public good. If the politician makes no proposal or if the proposal fails to receive the required support among voters, the status quo level of funding is implemented.

The voters desire a certain level of funding, denoted θ. The voter utility reflects their opinion on the value of the public good and the cost of the taxes that would be necessary to fund it. We assume voter utility declines symmetrically as the funding level diverges from the ideal point, with quadratic distance policy preferences given by −(gθ)2.

We assume the politician's ideal funding is at least as much as what the voters desire. The politician's ideal level is θ + b, where b represents the disagreement between the politician and the voters. We assume that b is non-negative, which is consistent with the common justification of referendum requirements, that limiting the politician's authority will lower spending. When b is equal to zero there is no disagreement. As with the voters, the politician has preferences, −(gθb)2, that are symmetric in the distance of the funding level from their ideal level of funding.

The sequence of events in the model is as follows. First, the politician chooses whether to propose a referendum to adopt a public good level, g’, rather than the reversion level, g. Should they decide against proposing a referendum, the reversion level is adopted. Conversely, if they propose a referendum, the voters then vote yes or no. If at least v share of voters vote in favor, then g’ is adopted, where v is the vote share requirement, the focus of this paper. Otherwise, the status quo g is adopted. We assume that v is at least one half. Further, we assume that the politician's preferred level of the public good, θ + b, exceeds g. In order to introduce uncertainty in the outcomes of proposals, and hence allow the model to rationalize failed proposals, we assume that there are shocks to the voter preferences that the politician does not know at the time they make proposals. The probability that proposal g’ will prevail given the vote share required is p(g’; v). Since politicians are uncertain whether any proposal they make would pass, they will choose their proposal so as to maximize their expected utility over the possible outcomes.

The policy change we study empirically is equivalent to a change in the vote requirement, v. We are interested in how changing v alters the proposed level of investment (g’g), its likelihood of success (p(g’; v)), and the resulting public good levels, which we describe as the expected level of investment, p(g’;v)(g’g).11

Table 1 describes the effect of a decrease in the vote requirement on each outcome when there is and is not disagreement between voters and the politician on the optimal level of provision. When the politician and voters prefer the same level of spending, a decrease in the threshold does not change the proposal or the fraction of votes in favor. Nevertheless, the probability of the proposal prevailing will increase and, as a result, the expected level of investment will also increase. When the politician prefers higher spending than the voter, a decrease in the threshold will result in larger proposals and, consequently, lower vote shares in favor. However, since the threshold is lower, the probability that the proposal prevails increases, leading to an increase in investment.

In sum, the model presents a framework for understanding the effect of a change in the vote requirement on the behavior of local politicians and voters. It shows how the policy change that we study affects the proposals made by politicians and how voters will vote on them. It has clear predictions for the importance of disagreement between voters and elected politicians.

We combine various sources of administrative and publicly available data on all public schools in California over the past 2 decades. Our main source of data is the set of all election results for all local measures in California between 1995 and 2016. These data, similar to what Cellini et al. (2010) and others have used, come from the California Election Data Archive (CEDA), a project of the Center for California Studies at California State University, Sacramento. We include elections from counties, municipalities, community college districts, and K–12 school districts. Our set of measures includes all those that would have authorized new, increased, or renewed taxes. Our main estimates are limited to only general obligation bonds, but we include other funding measures in robustness checks.12

For each measure in the CEDA dataset, we observe the full text of the ballot question, which includes the proposed dollar amounts for general obligation bonds. We also observe whether the measure passed and the number of votes for and against, from which we calculate the share of voters who voted for passage. During the period we study there were 4,520 tax-related measures. There are 10 different types of measures included among these: GO bonds, other bonds, business taxes, overrides of the Gann limit, Mello/Roos bonds, parcel taxes, sales taxes, transient occupancy (hotel) taxes, and utility taxes. Of all the measures, 2,075 (46%) were for GO bonds, which are the main measure we focus on in the primary analyses.

We complement the CEDA dataset with other sources of publicly available information. We use school- and district-level information on student demographics and proficiency on standardized tests from the Common Core of Data. We use Decennial Census information from 2000 for population counts, demographics, and socioeconomic characteristics of each local jurisdiction. Counts from the census are readily available for counties, municipalities, and school districts. Census tabulations are not available for community college districts, however. To produce counts of the number of residents in a community college district, we overlaid their current boundaries, available from the Foundation for California Community Colleges, with a map of census tracts. We then estimated the proportional overlap of tract-level population with the college districts.13

In sum, we create two analysis datasets. The first is a “jurisdiction-level” panel dataset. This panel consists of 1,589 jurisdiction-year observations from 1995 to 2016, comprising 977 K–12 districts, 482 cities, 72 community college districts, and 58 counties. For each observation, we observe the number of relevant elections held and passed, the number of GO bonds proposed and approved, and the amount of GO funding per capita proposed and approved.

The second dataset is an “election-level” dataset with the full set of 4,520 elections between 1995 and 2016. For these, we observe the jurisdiction, purpose, and vote share. Notably, this dataset includes GO bonds as well as the nine other types of measures.

Table 2 shows summary statistics of the jurisdiction-level panel, by jurisdiction type, prior to the passage of Proposition 39. Between 1995 and 2000, almost half of the school districts proposed a GO bond, as did one fifth of community college districts. The other jurisdictions in the sample—cities and counties—were much less likely to propose this type of funding. This makes sense given that these jurisdictions have a wider set of fundraising tools than school and community college districts. On the other hand, cities and counties were much more likely to put other types of funding proposals, primarily changes in parcel taxes, on the ballot. Passage rates of GO bonds and other elections did not vary across jurisdiction type. Education-related GO bonds tended to be much larger than the GO bonds proposed by counties and cities.

In this section, we describe our strategy to empirically investigate the effect of the change in vote requirements on the spending proposals made by the governments, the support the spending proposals received from voters, and the resulting capital spending of local governments. We use a difference-in-differences strategy to identify all effects. However, they require two different types of datasets. We first describe the unconditional approach, which we use to answer the questions regarding government proposals and funding outcomes. We then describe the approach we use to answer questions regarding voting, which conditions on local governments that proposed a bond.

We organize the results into three sections. First, we examine whether Proposition 39 changed the proposal behavior of school boards and community college districts in terms of their likelihood of proposing a GO bond, and the size of the proposals. This uses the methods described in “Estimating Effects on Government Behavior and Funding Outcomes.” Second, we ask whether the performance of GO bonds from educational jurisdictions changed as a result of Proposition 39. This uses the methods described in “Estimating Effects on Election Outcomes.” Third, we study the overall effects of Proposition 39 on funding outcomes, which combines the effect on government behavior and the effect on voting outcomes. This again uses the methods described in “Estimating Effects on Government Behavior and Funding Outcomes.” After discussing the main results we then move to heterogeneity analysis across jurisdiction types, and robustness checks.

In this paper, we analyze how a constitutional change to the voting threshold required for passing a school bond in California affected the share of voters who supported such bonds. We find that schools more than doubled their bond funding per resident due to the change. In addition, we show that governments were no more likely to propose a measure but are more likely to pass a general obligation bond due to the policy change. School bonds saw a drop of 6 percentage points in voter support following a decrease in the voting threshold by 11 percentage points from two thirds to 55%.

We interpret these results in the context of a political economy model of the interaction between a voter and an elected official. With no disagreement between voters and elected officials, a lowering of the vote share would not affect the proposals made. It would, however, increase the probability that they prevail. Yet, we do find an increase in both the proposals made and the probability that they prevail. This suggests that there is disagreement between the voters and the elected officials. The elected officials use their expanded flexibility to both request more spending and ensure that it passes with a higher probability. Together these result in a large increase in the amount of funding approved.

We note that our results should be interpreted with some deference to potential spillover effects. School districts share a common property tax base with the overlapping jurisdictions that were not subject to the policy change. Thus, changes in the tax rate imposed by school districts could affect voting behavior in these overlapping jurisdictions. For example, additional capital funding in a school district might make it less likely that voters would support higher tax rates for the city or county in which they live. If that were the case, the estimated treatment effects presented in the paper are the combination of these two effects, not simply the effect on the school districts.

Policies that limit the unilateral power of local elected officials and require tax policies to be approved via referendum are common throughout the United States. We study an incremental change in this requirement and show that it had large effects. Lowering the vote threshold worked as intended and more than doubled funding from GO bonds. However, the policy change did not expand the set of school districts that proposed a GO bond. In that sense, Proposition 39 likely increased funding among districts that would have proposed bonds even without the change. This occurred both because districts whose proposals may have failed saw them succeed and because districts proposed larger bonds.

The policy change did not have equal effects across all jurisdictions. Its effects were concentrated in jurisdictions that were not racially and ethnically homogenous. This suggests that relaxing or removing constraints on local elected leaders increases spending more in places with more diverse populations. Our analysis points to two possible reasons for why this may be. Elected officials in those places may have larger disagreements with referendum voters over their preferred level of spending or have less uncertainty over referendum outcomes.

These results have implications for policy discussions that involve changes to local tax limits. Some states frequently modify the terms of these limits. States change the latitude with which local officials can set policy without a voter referendum, in some cases through annual adjustments to allowable budget increases. States also change the rules for referenda, as in the case studied. Our results suggest that the details of how these policies are designed matter. It can affect the amount of funding that occurs, and hence taxes that residents must pay. Since it deferentially affects jurisdictions with different characteristics, it has important distributional consequences.

求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
5.80
自引率
2.60%
发文量
82
期刊介绍: This journal encompasses issues and practices in policy analysis and public management. Listed among the contributors are economists, public managers, and operations researchers. Featured regularly are book reviews and a department devoted to discussing ideas and issues of importance to practitioners, researchers, and academics.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信