医疗事故标准制定:发展医疗事故“安全港”作为医院的新角色?

J. Blumstein
{"title":"医疗事故标准制定:发展医疗事故“安全港”作为医院的新角色?","authors":"J. Blumstein","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.899321","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Recent tort and medical malpractice reform has largely been directed at damages for noneconomic loss, a remedy-centric approach. This article addresses the issue of cost not from a remedy-centric perspective but from the perspective of the impact of the liability-determination process and standards on levels of utilization and therefore cost - the defensive medicine perspective. Establishing medical liability relies on the professional customary practice standard and is premised on the assumption that science determines a standard of care that controls medical decision-making in individual circumstances. Evidence of unexplained practice variation (clinical uncertainty) calls this scientific premise into question in a large number of situations, making compliance with a standard of care difficult, even mythical, in many clinical circumstances. Because the medical profession sets the standard, consideration of cost-benefit issues in individual cases is not part of the liability-determination process in medical malpractice cases. Further, the professional standard of care is established after-the-fact (structural uncertainty) by expert testimony ostensibly based on scientifically validated customary practices. Such ex post standard-setting is understandable in a medical-practice world characterized by scientific evidence, but the evidence on clinical uncertainty undermines that claim. This creates structural uncertainty, which makes compliance with the after-the-fact \"standards of care\" difficult - pursuit of a moving target. The result of clinical and structural uncertainty is an incentive for risk-averse medical decisionmaking - doing more than might be medically optimal to avoid liability. Such defensive medicine is facilitated by the prevalence of third-party payment, which funds this type of risk-averse clinical decisionmaking and reduces the reliability that custom might otherwise reflect in balancing cost and benefit in a less subsidized market. This article proposes the use of ex ante standard-setting to reduce uncertainty faced by medical providers and to allow for the appropriate balancing of costs and benefits in formulating such protocols. Such standards should be symmetrical - the controlling legal standard that serves both as both a liability sword and shield. From a quality-assurance perspective, this sword-and-shield dimension creates a powerful incentive for compliance. To make ex ante standard-setting work, the standard must be the controlling standard. The federal QIO legislation allows QIOs to establish practice standards that become the standards of care. Such QIO-developed standards trump state-created standards by conferring immunity for conduct in compliance with the QIO standards. To be effective as a defense against defensive medicine, such QIO-developed standards must be modest in conception, narrow in design, and targeted in their implementation. They must be targeted at narrow and specific circumstances, providing specific guidance to practitioners in carefully circumscribed situations. They should be conceived of as \"safe harbors,\" not broad parameters of practice. These safe harbors should be aimed at defensive practices that are sub-optimal - areas in which quality can be maintained while reducing cost. That substantial savings are attainable, consistent with the maintenance of quality, is strongly suggested by research that concludes that, at least regarding some types of services, the most important problem is overuse that exposes patients to the risks of unnecessary treatment.","PeriodicalId":238933,"journal":{"name":"Health Care Delivery & Financing","volume":"15 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2006-04-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"11","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Medical Malpractice Standard-Setting: Developing Malpractice 'Safe Harbors' as a New Role for Qios?\",\"authors\":\"J. Blumstein\",\"doi\":\"10.2139/ssrn.899321\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"Recent tort and medical malpractice reform has largely been directed at damages for noneconomic loss, a remedy-centric approach. This article addresses the issue of cost not from a remedy-centric perspective but from the perspective of the impact of the liability-determination process and standards on levels of utilization and therefore cost - the defensive medicine perspective. Establishing medical liability relies on the professional customary practice standard and is premised on the assumption that science determines a standard of care that controls medical decision-making in individual circumstances. Evidence of unexplained practice variation (clinical uncertainty) calls this scientific premise into question in a large number of situations, making compliance with a standard of care difficult, even mythical, in many clinical circumstances. Because the medical profession sets the standard, consideration of cost-benefit issues in individual cases is not part of the liability-determination process in medical malpractice cases. Further, the professional standard of care is established after-the-fact (structural uncertainty) by expert testimony ostensibly based on scientifically validated customary practices. Such ex post standard-setting is understandable in a medical-practice world characterized by scientific evidence, but the evidence on clinical uncertainty undermines that claim. This creates structural uncertainty, which makes compliance with the after-the-fact \\\"standards of care\\\" difficult - pursuit of a moving target. The result of clinical and structural uncertainty is an incentive for risk-averse medical decisionmaking - doing more than might be medically optimal to avoid liability. Such defensive medicine is facilitated by the prevalence of third-party payment, which funds this type of risk-averse clinical decisionmaking and reduces the reliability that custom might otherwise reflect in balancing cost and benefit in a less subsidized market. This article proposes the use of ex ante standard-setting to reduce uncertainty faced by medical providers and to allow for the appropriate balancing of costs and benefits in formulating such protocols. Such standards should be symmetrical - the controlling legal standard that serves both as both a liability sword and shield. From a quality-assurance perspective, this sword-and-shield dimension creates a powerful incentive for compliance. To make ex ante standard-setting work, the standard must be the controlling standard. The federal QIO legislation allows QIOs to establish practice standards that become the standards of care. Such QIO-developed standards trump state-created standards by conferring immunity for conduct in compliance with the QIO standards. To be effective as a defense against defensive medicine, such QIO-developed standards must be modest in conception, narrow in design, and targeted in their implementation. They must be targeted at narrow and specific circumstances, providing specific guidance to practitioners in carefully circumscribed situations. They should be conceived of as \\\"safe harbors,\\\" not broad parameters of practice. These safe harbors should be aimed at defensive practices that are sub-optimal - areas in which quality can be maintained while reducing cost. That substantial savings are attainable, consistent with the maintenance of quality, is strongly suggested by research that concludes that, at least regarding some types of services, the most important problem is overuse that exposes patients to the risks of unnecessary treatment.\",\"PeriodicalId\":238933,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Health Care Delivery & Financing\",\"volume\":\"15 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2006-04-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"11\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Health Care Delivery & Financing\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.899321\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Health Care Delivery & Financing","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.899321","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 11

摘要

最近的侵权和医疗事故改革主要针对非经济损失的损害赔偿,这是一种以救济为中心的方法。本文不是从以补救为中心的角度来解决成本问题,而是从责任确定过程和标准对利用水平的影响的角度来解决成本问题-防御性医学的角度。确立医疗责任依赖于专业惯例标准,前提是科学决定了在个人情况下控制医疗决策的护理标准。在许多情况下,无法解释的实践变化(临床不确定性)的证据使这一科学前提受到质疑,使得在许多临床情况下难以遵守护理标准,甚至是神话。由于医疗行业设定了标准,在医疗事故案件中,考虑个别案件的成本效益问题并不是责任确定过程的一部分。此外,专业的护理标准是事后建立的(结构上的不确定性),由表面上基于科学验证的习惯做法的专家证词。在以科学证据为特征的医疗实践世界中,这种事后标准的制定是可以理解的,但临床不确定性的证据破坏了这种说法。这造成了结构上的不确定性,使得事后的“护理标准”难以遵守——这是一个不断变化的目标。临床和结构上的不确定性的结果是对规避风险的医疗决策的一种激励——为了避免责任,做了比医学上最优的更多的事情。第三方支付的盛行为这种防御性医疗提供了便利,第三方支付为这种规避风险的临床决策提供了资金,并降低了在补贴较少的市场中,习惯在平衡成本和收益方面可能反映的可靠性。本文建议采用事前标准制定,以减少医疗服务提供者面临的不确定性,并在制定此类议定书时适当平衡成本和收益。这样的标准应该是对称的——既是责任之剑又是责任之盾的控制性法律标准。从质量保证的角度来看,这个剑与盾的维度为遵从性创造了强大的激励。为了使事先制定的标准发挥作用,该标准必须是控制标准。联邦QIO立法允许QIO建立成为护理标准的实践标准。这种由QIO制定的标准优于国家制定的标准,赋予符合QIO标准的行为豁免权。为了有效地防御防御性医学,这种qio开发的标准必须在概念上适度,在设计上狭隘,在实施上有针对性。它们必须针对狭窄和特定的情况,在仔细限定的情况下为从业者提供具体的指导。它们应该被视为“安全港”,而不是广泛的实践参数。这些安全港的目标应该是次优的防御措施,即在降低成本的同时保持质量的领域。大量的节省是可以实现的,与保持质量相一致,研究强烈表明,至少就某些类型的服务而言,最重要的问题是过度使用,使患者面临不必要治疗的风险。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Medical Malpractice Standard-Setting: Developing Malpractice 'Safe Harbors' as a New Role for Qios?
Recent tort and medical malpractice reform has largely been directed at damages for noneconomic loss, a remedy-centric approach. This article addresses the issue of cost not from a remedy-centric perspective but from the perspective of the impact of the liability-determination process and standards on levels of utilization and therefore cost - the defensive medicine perspective. Establishing medical liability relies on the professional customary practice standard and is premised on the assumption that science determines a standard of care that controls medical decision-making in individual circumstances. Evidence of unexplained practice variation (clinical uncertainty) calls this scientific premise into question in a large number of situations, making compliance with a standard of care difficult, even mythical, in many clinical circumstances. Because the medical profession sets the standard, consideration of cost-benefit issues in individual cases is not part of the liability-determination process in medical malpractice cases. Further, the professional standard of care is established after-the-fact (structural uncertainty) by expert testimony ostensibly based on scientifically validated customary practices. Such ex post standard-setting is understandable in a medical-practice world characterized by scientific evidence, but the evidence on clinical uncertainty undermines that claim. This creates structural uncertainty, which makes compliance with the after-the-fact "standards of care" difficult - pursuit of a moving target. The result of clinical and structural uncertainty is an incentive for risk-averse medical decisionmaking - doing more than might be medically optimal to avoid liability. Such defensive medicine is facilitated by the prevalence of third-party payment, which funds this type of risk-averse clinical decisionmaking and reduces the reliability that custom might otherwise reflect in balancing cost and benefit in a less subsidized market. This article proposes the use of ex ante standard-setting to reduce uncertainty faced by medical providers and to allow for the appropriate balancing of costs and benefits in formulating such protocols. Such standards should be symmetrical - the controlling legal standard that serves both as both a liability sword and shield. From a quality-assurance perspective, this sword-and-shield dimension creates a powerful incentive for compliance. To make ex ante standard-setting work, the standard must be the controlling standard. The federal QIO legislation allows QIOs to establish practice standards that become the standards of care. Such QIO-developed standards trump state-created standards by conferring immunity for conduct in compliance with the QIO standards. To be effective as a defense against defensive medicine, such QIO-developed standards must be modest in conception, narrow in design, and targeted in their implementation. They must be targeted at narrow and specific circumstances, providing specific guidance to practitioners in carefully circumscribed situations. They should be conceived of as "safe harbors," not broad parameters of practice. These safe harbors should be aimed at defensive practices that are sub-optimal - areas in which quality can be maintained while reducing cost. That substantial savings are attainable, consistent with the maintenance of quality, is strongly suggested by research that concludes that, at least regarding some types of services, the most important problem is overuse that exposes patients to the risks of unnecessary treatment.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信