平台与理性法则:美国运通案例

Herbert Hovenkamp
{"title":"平台与理性法则:美国运通案例","authors":"Herbert Hovenkamp","doi":"10.7916/CBLR.V2019I1.1688","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"In Ohio v. American Express Co., the Supreme Court applied antitrust’s rule of reason to a two-sided platform. The challenge was to an “anti-steering” rule, a vertical restraint preventing merchants from shifting customers who offered an AmEx card from to a less costly alternative such as Visa or Mastercard. \n \nA two-sided platform is a business that depends on relationships between two different, noncompeting groups of transaction partners. For example, a printed periodical such as a newspaper earns revenue by selling both advertising and subscriptions to the paper itself. Success depends on a platform’s ability to maintain the appropriate balance between participation on one side and the other. For example, if Uber, a two-sided platform offering transportation services, sets too high a fare it will have enough drivers but too few passengers. If the price is too low, it will have too many passengers in relation to available drivers. \n \nAdministering antitrust under the rule of reason depends on careful fact finding. Under antitrust’s per se rule, once a practice is proven little evidence of anticompetitive effects is relevant. By contrast, the rule of reason requires a searching factual examination of a record, enabling the court to understand the effects of the defendant’s activities. This obliges appellate courts to review the record, and the Supreme Court’s AmEx opinion should be tested against this requirement. The Court ignored specific district court fact findings to the effect that AmEx’s anti-steering rule imposed higher costs on everyone, including customers who purchased with cash. \n \nThe Court also concluded that AmEx’s anti-steering rule combatted free riding, because otherwise competing card issuers could profit from AmEx’s business model. That might be true if one could obtain AmEx’s perks merely by owning the card, but here one received the perks only for transactions actually made with the card, so there was no free riding. \n \nMore generally, the Court’s analysis assumed that costs on one side of a two-sided platform are offset by gains on the other side. In some situations, such as the Uber example above, that may be true. But in the AmEx case both sides of the platform were harmed by the anti-steering rule. Both customers and merchants lost an opportunity to bargain around Amex’s higher fees. In addition, competing platforms were also worse off because whey were denied the opportunity to offer a lower cost substitute transaction. \n \nCompetition always exists at the margin. One cannot evaluate the competitive effects of a particular restraint by considering whether the overall costs of a defendant’s business practices exceed the benefits. The AmEx challengers were not trying to tear down AmEx’s entire business, but only to enjoin its anti-steering rule. That requires assessing the marginal costs and benefits of the anti-steering rule. The record was clear that at the margin each merchant affected by the steering rule was worse off, and each cardholder was worse off as well. \n \nThe Court’s assumption about offsetting cost and benefits also led it to conclude that in a qualifying two-sided platform, both sides should be included in the market definition. The two sides are, of course, complements in production, not substitutes. This holding is thus in conflict with an idea that is central to antitrust analysis, which is that relevant markets consists of a “collusive group,” or substitutes. \n \nFurther, the Court exacerbated this problem by holding that in a case involving a vertical restraint a relevant market must be defined, even if market power is based on direct effects. That conclusion, which was never briefed or argued and never cited any of the economic literature on the question, flies in the face of decades of progress toward more accurate methodologies for assessing power. Further, it turns into a question of law something that is clearly an issue of fact – namely whether the defendant has sufficient power to produce an anticompetitive restraint. \n \nThe Court did limit the scope of its holding to situations involving a simultaneous one-to-one transaction across the two sides of the platform. That would include credit card networks as well as other direct transactional networks such as Uber. However, it would exclude situations where there is not a simultaneous one-to-one relationship between transactions on the two sides, such as Netflix or music streaming services, periodicals or search engines partially supported by advertising, or most exchanges on sports networks. Neither would it include situations where the relationship between the transactions on the two sides is actuarial, such as health insurance networks.","PeriodicalId":105752,"journal":{"name":"IRPN: Innovation & Regulatory Law & Policy (Topic)","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2019-03-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"20","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Platforms and the Rule of Reason: The American Express Case\",\"authors\":\"Herbert Hovenkamp\",\"doi\":\"10.7916/CBLR.V2019I1.1688\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"In Ohio v. American Express Co., the Supreme Court applied antitrust’s rule of reason to a two-sided platform. The challenge was to an “anti-steering” rule, a vertical restraint preventing merchants from shifting customers who offered an AmEx card from to a less costly alternative such as Visa or Mastercard. \\n \\nA two-sided platform is a business that depends on relationships between two different, noncompeting groups of transaction partners. For example, a printed periodical such as a newspaper earns revenue by selling both advertising and subscriptions to the paper itself. Success depends on a platform’s ability to maintain the appropriate balance between participation on one side and the other. For example, if Uber, a two-sided platform offering transportation services, sets too high a fare it will have enough drivers but too few passengers. If the price is too low, it will have too many passengers in relation to available drivers. \\n \\nAdministering antitrust under the rule of reason depends on careful fact finding. Under antitrust’s per se rule, once a practice is proven little evidence of anticompetitive effects is relevant. By contrast, the rule of reason requires a searching factual examination of a record, enabling the court to understand the effects of the defendant’s activities. This obliges appellate courts to review the record, and the Supreme Court’s AmEx opinion should be tested against this requirement. The Court ignored specific district court fact findings to the effect that AmEx’s anti-steering rule imposed higher costs on everyone, including customers who purchased with cash. \\n \\nThe Court also concluded that AmEx’s anti-steering rule combatted free riding, because otherwise competing card issuers could profit from AmEx’s business model. That might be true if one could obtain AmEx’s perks merely by owning the card, but here one received the perks only for transactions actually made with the card, so there was no free riding. \\n \\nMore generally, the Court’s analysis assumed that costs on one side of a two-sided platform are offset by gains on the other side. In some situations, such as the Uber example above, that may be true. But in the AmEx case both sides of the platform were harmed by the anti-steering rule. Both customers and merchants lost an opportunity to bargain around Amex’s higher fees. In addition, competing platforms were also worse off because whey were denied the opportunity to offer a lower cost substitute transaction. \\n \\nCompetition always exists at the margin. One cannot evaluate the competitive effects of a particular restraint by considering whether the overall costs of a defendant’s business practices exceed the benefits. The AmEx challengers were not trying to tear down AmEx’s entire business, but only to enjoin its anti-steering rule. That requires assessing the marginal costs and benefits of the anti-steering rule. The record was clear that at the margin each merchant affected by the steering rule was worse off, and each cardholder was worse off as well. \\n \\nThe Court’s assumption about offsetting cost and benefits also led it to conclude that in a qualifying two-sided platform, both sides should be included in the market definition. The two sides are, of course, complements in production, not substitutes. This holding is thus in conflict with an idea that is central to antitrust analysis, which is that relevant markets consists of a “collusive group,” or substitutes. \\n \\nFurther, the Court exacerbated this problem by holding that in a case involving a vertical restraint a relevant market must be defined, even if market power is based on direct effects. That conclusion, which was never briefed or argued and never cited any of the economic literature on the question, flies in the face of decades of progress toward more accurate methodologies for assessing power. Further, it turns into a question of law something that is clearly an issue of fact – namely whether the defendant has sufficient power to produce an anticompetitive restraint. \\n \\nThe Court did limit the scope of its holding to situations involving a simultaneous one-to-one transaction across the two sides of the platform. That would include credit card networks as well as other direct transactional networks such as Uber. However, it would exclude situations where there is not a simultaneous one-to-one relationship between transactions on the two sides, such as Netflix or music streaming services, periodicals or search engines partially supported by advertising, or most exchanges on sports networks. Neither would it include situations where the relationship between the transactions on the two sides is actuarial, such as health insurance networks.\",\"PeriodicalId\":105752,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"IRPN: Innovation & Regulatory Law & Policy (Topic)\",\"volume\":\"1 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2019-03-05\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"20\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"IRPN: Innovation & Regulatory Law & Policy (Topic)\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.7916/CBLR.V2019I1.1688\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"IRPN: Innovation & Regulatory Law & Policy (Topic)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.7916/CBLR.V2019I1.1688","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 20

摘要

在俄亥俄州诉美国运通公司(American Express Co.)案中,最高法院将反垄断的理性原则适用于一个双边平台。挑战在于“反导向”规则,这是一种纵向限制,防止商家将提供运通卡的客户从Visa或万事达(Mastercard)等成本更低的选择中转移。双边平台是一种依赖于两个不同的、不竞争的交易伙伴之间的关系的业务。例如,像报纸这样的印刷期刊通过向报纸本身出售广告和订阅来获得收入。成功与否取决于平台是否有能力在一方和另一方的参与之间保持适当的平衡。例如,如果提供交通服务的双边平台优步(Uber)定价过高,就会导致司机足够多,但乘客太少。如果价格过低,相对于可用的司机,它将有太多的乘客。在理性原则下实施反垄断取决于仔细的事实发现。根据反垄断本身的规则,一旦一种做法被证明具有反竞争影响,就没有什么证据是相关的。相比之下,理性原则要求对记录进行彻底的事实审查,使法院能够了解被告活动的影响。这迫使上诉法院审查记录,最高法院的运通卡意见应该与这一要求进行检验。法院忽略了具体的地区法院事实调查结果,大意是美国运通的反操纵规则给每个人带来了更高的成本,包括用现金购买的客户。法院还得出结论,美国运通的反转向规则打击了免费乘车,因为否则竞争的发卡机构可以从美国运通的商业模式中获利。如果一个人仅仅因为拥有这张卡就能获得美国运通卡的特权,这可能是对的,但在这里,一个人只有在用这张卡进行交易时才能获得特权,所以没有搭便车。更一般地说,法院的分析假设双边平台一方的成本被另一方的收益抵消。在某些情况下,比如优步的例子,这可能是真的。但在美国运通的案例中,平台的双方都受到了反转向规则的伤害。客户和商家都失去了讨价还价的机会。此外,竞争平台的情况也更糟,因为乳清被剥夺了提供成本更低的替代交易的机会。竞争总是存在于边缘。人们不能通过考虑被告商业行为的总成本是否超过收益来评估某一特定限制的竞争效应。美国运通业的挑战者并没有试图摧毁美国运通业的整个业务,而只是想禁止它的反操纵规则。这需要评估反转向规则的边际成本和收益。记录清楚地表明,在边际上,受操纵规则影响的每个商人的情况都更糟,每个持卡人的情况也更糟。法院关于抵消成本和收益的假设也使其得出结论,在合格的双边平台中,双方都应包括在市场定义中。当然,双方在生产上是互补的,而不是替代的。因此,这种观点与反垄断分析的核心观点相冲突,即相关市场由“串通集团”或替代品组成。此外,法院认为,在涉及垂直限制的案件中,必须界定相关市场,即使市场力量是基于直接影响,这也加剧了这一问题。这一结论从未被简要介绍或论证过,也从未引用过任何有关这一问题的经济学文献,它与几十年来朝着更准确的权力评估方法取得的进展背道而驰。此外,它还把一个显然是事实问题的问题变成了一个法律问题——即被告是否有足够的权力来实施反竞争限制。法院确实将其裁定的范围限制在涉及平台双方同时进行一对一交易的情况下。这将包括信用卡网络以及优步(Uber)等其他直接交易网络。然而,它将排除双方交易之间不存在同时一对一关系的情况,例如Netflix或音乐流媒体服务,部分由广告支持的期刊或搜索引擎,或体育网络上的大多数交易。它也不包括双方交易之间的关系是精算的情况,例如健康保险网络。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Platforms and the Rule of Reason: The American Express Case
In Ohio v. American Express Co., the Supreme Court applied antitrust’s rule of reason to a two-sided platform. The challenge was to an “anti-steering” rule, a vertical restraint preventing merchants from shifting customers who offered an AmEx card from to a less costly alternative such as Visa or Mastercard. A two-sided platform is a business that depends on relationships between two different, noncompeting groups of transaction partners. For example, a printed periodical such as a newspaper earns revenue by selling both advertising and subscriptions to the paper itself. Success depends on a platform’s ability to maintain the appropriate balance between participation on one side and the other. For example, if Uber, a two-sided platform offering transportation services, sets too high a fare it will have enough drivers but too few passengers. If the price is too low, it will have too many passengers in relation to available drivers. Administering antitrust under the rule of reason depends on careful fact finding. Under antitrust’s per se rule, once a practice is proven little evidence of anticompetitive effects is relevant. By contrast, the rule of reason requires a searching factual examination of a record, enabling the court to understand the effects of the defendant’s activities. This obliges appellate courts to review the record, and the Supreme Court’s AmEx opinion should be tested against this requirement. The Court ignored specific district court fact findings to the effect that AmEx’s anti-steering rule imposed higher costs on everyone, including customers who purchased with cash. The Court also concluded that AmEx’s anti-steering rule combatted free riding, because otherwise competing card issuers could profit from AmEx’s business model. That might be true if one could obtain AmEx’s perks merely by owning the card, but here one received the perks only for transactions actually made with the card, so there was no free riding. More generally, the Court’s analysis assumed that costs on one side of a two-sided platform are offset by gains on the other side. In some situations, such as the Uber example above, that may be true. But in the AmEx case both sides of the platform were harmed by the anti-steering rule. Both customers and merchants lost an opportunity to bargain around Amex’s higher fees. In addition, competing platforms were also worse off because whey were denied the opportunity to offer a lower cost substitute transaction. Competition always exists at the margin. One cannot evaluate the competitive effects of a particular restraint by considering whether the overall costs of a defendant’s business practices exceed the benefits. The AmEx challengers were not trying to tear down AmEx’s entire business, but only to enjoin its anti-steering rule. That requires assessing the marginal costs and benefits of the anti-steering rule. The record was clear that at the margin each merchant affected by the steering rule was worse off, and each cardholder was worse off as well. The Court’s assumption about offsetting cost and benefits also led it to conclude that in a qualifying two-sided platform, both sides should be included in the market definition. The two sides are, of course, complements in production, not substitutes. This holding is thus in conflict with an idea that is central to antitrust analysis, which is that relevant markets consists of a “collusive group,” or substitutes. Further, the Court exacerbated this problem by holding that in a case involving a vertical restraint a relevant market must be defined, even if market power is based on direct effects. That conclusion, which was never briefed or argued and never cited any of the economic literature on the question, flies in the face of decades of progress toward more accurate methodologies for assessing power. Further, it turns into a question of law something that is clearly an issue of fact – namely whether the defendant has sufficient power to produce an anticompetitive restraint. The Court did limit the scope of its holding to situations involving a simultaneous one-to-one transaction across the two sides of the platform. That would include credit card networks as well as other direct transactional networks such as Uber. However, it would exclude situations where there is not a simultaneous one-to-one relationship between transactions on the two sides, such as Netflix or music streaming services, periodicals or search engines partially supported by advertising, or most exchanges on sports networks. Neither would it include situations where the relationship between the transactions on the two sides is actuarial, such as health insurance networks.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信