Prepacks as a mechanism for resolving financial distress: The evidence

Pub Date : 2023-04-24 DOI:10.1111/jacf.12540
John J. McConnell, Ronald C. Lease, Elizabeth Tashjian
{"title":"Prepacks as a mechanism for resolving financial distress: The evidence","authors":"John J. McConnell,&nbsp;Ronald C. Lease,&nbsp;Elizabeth Tashjian","doi":"10.1111/jacf.12540","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>Prepacked bankruptcies, or “prepacks,” are considered a hybrid form of distressed restructuring because they share certain characteristics with both of the widely used alternatives for reorganizing distressed companies—out-of-court restructurings (OCRs) and traditional Chapter 11 reorganizations. Prepacks are similar to OCRs in that creditors and the debtor agree to the major terms of the reorganization outside of the court. Prepacks are similar to traditional Chapter 11 filings in that the reorganization occurs under court supervision, confirmation of the plan requires approval by two-thirds in amount and one-half in number by each class of claimholder, and all claimholders must exchange their old securities in accordance with the terms of the plan. In a prepack, the Chapter 11 bankruptcy petition and a plan of reorganization are filed simultaneously with the court.</p><p>In a 1991 article in this journal, John McConnell and Henri Servaes laid out a number of hypotheses as to why distressed firms might use prepackaged bankruptcies to reorganize.1 At the time of their article, however, prepacks were still relatively uncommon and these authors were limited to an “anecdotal” discussion of four cases to make their points. With the passage of time and the growth in the number of prepacks, we have been able to assemble data for a substantial sample of prepacks.</p><p>Our study of prepacks complements a growing literature on the outcomes of various forms of distressed reorganization. A significant concern in this literature is whether the various reorganization procedures are efficient. Inefficient reorganization procedures can result in excessively high direct costs or sub-optimal financing and investment decisions by firms. The most efficient organization procedure is the one that creates the greatest value for the firm, net of all costs. Although efficiency cannot be observed directly, we provide evidence on a number of indirect measures of efficiency—for instance, the time required to reorganize, the cost of reorganizing, and the recovery rates by creditors.</p><p>Where the data are available, we compare prepacks to OCRs and traditional Chapter 11s. We find that on most dimensions considered, prepacks lie between the two alternative means of reorganizing financially distressed firms. For example, prepacks have higher costs of reorganizing (as a fraction of assets) than OCRs, but lower costs than conventional bankruptcies. These findings buttress the idea that prepacks are a hybrid form of reorganization that contain some aspects of both OCRs and traditional Chapter 11s.</p><p>Our sample consists of 49 financially distressed firms that filed prepacks over the period 1986 through June 1993. Crystal Oil, which filed a prepack in 1986, is widely regarded as the first prepack of a large firm. Following Crystal Oil, the next two prepacks in our sample occurred in 1989 with combined assets of $1.7 billion. In the years thereafter, four took place in 1990 with combined assets of $3.6 billion, 13 in 1991 with assets of $5.2 billion, 17 in 1992 with assets of $11.2 billion, and 12 took place through the first six months of 1993 (the cutoff point of our study) with total assets exceeding $5.5 billion. In 1993, moreover, 12 (or over 50%) of the 22 publicly traded firms with assets exceeding $100 million that filed for Chapter 11 filed a prepack (using our definition of the term). In 1994, 11 of 29 (or 38% of) such firms filed a prepack.2</p><p>Our sample includes two types of prepacks—“pre-voted” and “post-voted” prepacks.3 In a pre-voted prepack, claimholders vote on the plan of reorganization before the Chapter 11 bankruptcy petition is filed with the court. The bankruptcy petition and the voting results are then filed along with a plan of reorganization. Absent improper disclosure or voting irregularities, the pre-filing vote is binding upon all claimholders. In a post-voted prepack, the bankruptcy petition and the plan of reorganization are filed simultaneously, but prior to a formal vote by claimholders. A vote is then conducted under the jurisdiction of the court. In our sample of prepacks, 32 are pre-voted and 17 are post-voted. All 49 of these firms eventually reorganized and emerged from Chapter 11.</p><p>As might be anticipated, pre-voted prepacks require less time in Chapter 11 than post-voted prepacks. It turns out that pre-voted and post-voted prepacks differ in other ways as well. In particular, pre-voted prepacks involve larger firms, involve a longer time for pre-filing negotiations, incur lower proportional fees, provide a higher recovery rate for creditors, have greater dollar percentage deviations from absolute priority, and provide for lower post-reorganization equity ownership for creditors.</p><p>We now turn to our proxy measures of reorganization efficiency. To put our investigation in context, we compare measures for our proxies for efficiency with similar statistics generated for OCRs and traditional Chapter 11 reorganizations as reported in other studies.4</p><p>All else equal, an efficient reorganization process will require a shorter time, have a lower cost, and will result in higher recovery rates than a less efficient reorganization process. Furthermore, an efficient process should result in low deviations from priority. With the exception of deviations from priority, the statistics in the tables suggest that OCRs are the most efficient form of reorganization, followed by prepacks, while traditional Chapter 11s are the least efficient form of distressed restructuring. Since prepack firms engage in extended pre-filing negotiations, why do these firms not merely reorganize out of court rather than file a prepack? McConnell and Servaes suggest three possible reasons. Two of these reasons relate to solving the holdout and free-rider problems that can arise in OCRs.11 Our sample provides some evidence on these points.</p><p>For an OCR to be successful, significant debt relief must be achieved. Most OCRs specify that 90% or 95% of creditors must participate in order for the plan be implemented. The level of support necessary for a bankruptcy plan to be confirmed is much lower and, if confirmed, 100% of creditors must participate. Furthermore, the court can “cram down” the plan on especially recalcitrant creditors. Thus, the cramdown provision under Chapter 11 can resolve even the most severe holdout problem where either one powerful creditor or a group of creditors blocks a reorganization plan that has broad support among the remaining creditors.12 Although the cram-down provision has been invoked relatively often for equity-holders in Chapter 11 bankruptcies, the provision has seldom been used for creditors. However, for two firms in our sample of 49 prepacks, the reorganization plan was crammed down on creditors, as well.13 The case of E-II Holdings, Inc. illustrates how the cram-down provision of the Bankruptcy Code can be used to solve severe holdout problems.</p><p>E-II was spun off in a 1987 leveraged buyout of Beatrice Companies. In 1991, E-II announced that it would stop paying interest on its bonds. After extended negotiations with an unofficial creditors’ committee, a plan of reorganization was proposed that provided debtholders a substantial equity stake in the firm. However, there was a major disagreement between senior and junior debtholders about the valuation of the firm. Senior debtholders favored a relatively conservative estimate of post-emergence value, which provided them a larger share of the firm's equity. Junior debtholders favored a higher valuation of the firm, which would reduce the proportion of equity required to pay senior debtholders in full.</p><p>During the restructuring discussions, two investors who specialize in trading securities in financially distressed firms (“vulture” investors) took substantial positions in E-II's two debt issues. Carl Icahn acquired 31% of the junior issue and Leon Black's Apollo Advisors acquired 24% of the senior debt issue and 27% of the junior debt issue. Thus, either Icahn or Black could effectively block any out-of-court reorganization.</p><p>In June 1992, E-II announced that an agreement in principle on a plan of reorganization had been reached with the creditors’ committee and filed its plan of reorganization. Although 90.5% in number of the voting junior debtholders subsequently supported the plan, clearing the 50% hurdle, only 59.5% in dollar amount cast favorable votes, thus falling short of the two-thirds requirement. Later E-II submitted a second plan wherein the estimated value of the firm was increased, thereby improving the apparent recovery rate for junior debtholders. The plan also gave senior debtholders the right to receive payment in equity rather than debt, thus giving them an option to maintain control of the firm. But, Icahn did not support the second plan because it did not give him a controlling equity position; therefore, the plan again failed to achieve the required level of support for confirmation. In the confirmation hearing, however, the court crammed down the firm's plan of reorganization on the dissenting junior debtholders, thereby circumventing the junior debtholders who had held out against the second plan.</p><p>Because all security holders must participate in any exchange of securities in Chapter 11, a bankruptcy reorganization can help to solve the free-rider problem that can arise in an OCR. Creditors have an incentive not to exchange their old securities for new ones with less favorable terms and, thereby, to “freeride” on the concessions granted by other creditors even though the exchange would benefit all creditors collectively. Because <i>all</i> creditors must exchange securities in a Chapter 11 reorganization, bankruptcy can resolve the free-rider problem by removing the incentive to free-ride on the concessions of others.</p><p>Our sample offers some insights into the way in which prepacks may provide a low-cost mechanism for solving the free-rider problem. In nine of the prepacks in our sample, the firm simultaneously mailed to creditors both a solicitation for an out-of-court exchange offer and a ballot for a prepackaged reorganization. The terms of the out-of-court restructuring and the prepack were identical. In each case, the firm indicated that the reorganization would be completed out of court if the exchange offer received sufficient participation. Because each of these firms ended up in our prepack sample, the OCR attempt obviously failed. In each of the four cases where we could obtain data, at least one class of claimholders gave a higher level of support for the prepackaged plan than for the proposed exchange offer. Apparently, the claimholders were more willing to participate in the prepack, which ensured 100% participation by claimholders, than in the identical exchange offer, which did not guarantee 100% participation.</p><p>Consider the specific case of Gaylord Container. Gaylord Acquisition Corp., subsequently Gaylord Container Corp., was formed in 1986 to acquire assets in the paper industry. Gaylord made numerous acquisitions between 1986 and 1989. In 1990 Moody's lowered its rating on the firm's debt, citing higher-than-expected operating costs and high debt levels. Gaylord suspended interest payments on its subordinated notes in 1991. In 1992, following negotiations with creditors, Gaylord filed a registration statement with the SEC for an exchange offer with a back-up plan for a prepack should the exchange offer fail. The firm determined that to restructure successfully, 95% (in amount) of the subordinated debtholders must tender in the exchange offer. When the solicitation period expired, only 89% of the subordinated debt was tendered; but, at the same time, holders of 97% of this debt consented to the prepack. The firm's CEO concluded, “Clearly, holders of the subordinated debt opted for the prepackaged plan alternative that binds 100% of the bondholders and, therefore, treats all holders equally.”14</p><p>In sum, prepacks appear to provide a means of resolving the free-rider problem in reorganizations of financially distressed firms.15</p><p>But if these results suggest that prepacks are a “cheap” substitute for traditional Chapter 11 filings, there are also good reasons to believe that prepacks are not an option for many of the firms that end up in Chapter 11. For example, a large percentage of the firms that chose a traditional Chapter 11 reorganization may simply have lacked the financial resources necessary to continue operations throughout the relatively long pre-filing negotiation period (18 months, on average) typical of a prepack.</p><p>Alternatively, our findings could also be used to support the case that prepacks are substitutes for OCRs in that prepacks offer an inexpensive solution to holdout and free-rider problems. This reading of the evidence would suggest that, before the rise of prepacks, if the costs of a traditional Chapter 11 were sufficiently greater than the costs of an OCR, even hesitant creditors may have been coerced into an out-of-court restructuring. But, insofar as a prepack now offers a low-cost mechanism for pressuring all creditors to participate, the firm may elect a prepack rather than an OCR.</p><p>Our best guess is that both arguments have some validity. That is, we believe that some firms that would have chosen an OCR in the past now choose to reorganize by means of a prepack, while other firms that would have opted for a traditional Chapter 11 also choose to reorganize with a prepack. Lending support to this view are our findings that pre-voted prepacks have outcomes much closer to those of OCRs while post-voted prepacks look more like traditional Chapter 11s.</p><p>In this sense, the advent of prepacks can be viewed as providing yet another option for financially distressed firms. Indeed, our findings can be interpreted as suggesting that prepacks themselves add to a range of possible solutions to financial distress that stretches between OCRs at one extreme and traditional Chapter 11s at the other. In each case, the solution reflects the working out of a process in which creditors and debtors are free to choose the method of reorganization that provides the greatest benefit at the lowest cost given their particular circumstances. It is our hope that the data provided here will be of use to debtors and creditors confronted with these choices.</p>","PeriodicalId":0,"journal":{"name":"","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-04-24","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/jacf.12540","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jacf.12540","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

Prepacked bankruptcies, or “prepacks,” are considered a hybrid form of distressed restructuring because they share certain characteristics with both of the widely used alternatives for reorganizing distressed companies—out-of-court restructurings (OCRs) and traditional Chapter 11 reorganizations. Prepacks are similar to OCRs in that creditors and the debtor agree to the major terms of the reorganization outside of the court. Prepacks are similar to traditional Chapter 11 filings in that the reorganization occurs under court supervision, confirmation of the plan requires approval by two-thirds in amount and one-half in number by each class of claimholder, and all claimholders must exchange their old securities in accordance with the terms of the plan. In a prepack, the Chapter 11 bankruptcy petition and a plan of reorganization are filed simultaneously with the court.

In a 1991 article in this journal, John McConnell and Henri Servaes laid out a number of hypotheses as to why distressed firms might use prepackaged bankruptcies to reorganize.1 At the time of their article, however, prepacks were still relatively uncommon and these authors were limited to an “anecdotal” discussion of four cases to make their points. With the passage of time and the growth in the number of prepacks, we have been able to assemble data for a substantial sample of prepacks.

Our study of prepacks complements a growing literature on the outcomes of various forms of distressed reorganization. A significant concern in this literature is whether the various reorganization procedures are efficient. Inefficient reorganization procedures can result in excessively high direct costs or sub-optimal financing and investment decisions by firms. The most efficient organization procedure is the one that creates the greatest value for the firm, net of all costs. Although efficiency cannot be observed directly, we provide evidence on a number of indirect measures of efficiency—for instance, the time required to reorganize, the cost of reorganizing, and the recovery rates by creditors.

Where the data are available, we compare prepacks to OCRs and traditional Chapter 11s. We find that on most dimensions considered, prepacks lie between the two alternative means of reorganizing financially distressed firms. For example, prepacks have higher costs of reorganizing (as a fraction of assets) than OCRs, but lower costs than conventional bankruptcies. These findings buttress the idea that prepacks are a hybrid form of reorganization that contain some aspects of both OCRs and traditional Chapter 11s.

Our sample consists of 49 financially distressed firms that filed prepacks over the period 1986 through June 1993. Crystal Oil, which filed a prepack in 1986, is widely regarded as the first prepack of a large firm. Following Crystal Oil, the next two prepacks in our sample occurred in 1989 with combined assets of $1.7 billion. In the years thereafter, four took place in 1990 with combined assets of $3.6 billion, 13 in 1991 with assets of $5.2 billion, 17 in 1992 with assets of $11.2 billion, and 12 took place through the first six months of 1993 (the cutoff point of our study) with total assets exceeding $5.5 billion. In 1993, moreover, 12 (or over 50%) of the 22 publicly traded firms with assets exceeding $100 million that filed for Chapter 11 filed a prepack (using our definition of the term). In 1994, 11 of 29 (or 38% of) such firms filed a prepack.2

Our sample includes two types of prepacks—“pre-voted” and “post-voted” prepacks.3 In a pre-voted prepack, claimholders vote on the plan of reorganization before the Chapter 11 bankruptcy petition is filed with the court. The bankruptcy petition and the voting results are then filed along with a plan of reorganization. Absent improper disclosure or voting irregularities, the pre-filing vote is binding upon all claimholders. In a post-voted prepack, the bankruptcy petition and the plan of reorganization are filed simultaneously, but prior to a formal vote by claimholders. A vote is then conducted under the jurisdiction of the court. In our sample of prepacks, 32 are pre-voted and 17 are post-voted. All 49 of these firms eventually reorganized and emerged from Chapter 11.

As might be anticipated, pre-voted prepacks require less time in Chapter 11 than post-voted prepacks. It turns out that pre-voted and post-voted prepacks differ in other ways as well. In particular, pre-voted prepacks involve larger firms, involve a longer time for pre-filing negotiations, incur lower proportional fees, provide a higher recovery rate for creditors, have greater dollar percentage deviations from absolute priority, and provide for lower post-reorganization equity ownership for creditors.

We now turn to our proxy measures of reorganization efficiency. To put our investigation in context, we compare measures for our proxies for efficiency with similar statistics generated for OCRs and traditional Chapter 11 reorganizations as reported in other studies.4

All else equal, an efficient reorganization process will require a shorter time, have a lower cost, and will result in higher recovery rates than a less efficient reorganization process. Furthermore, an efficient process should result in low deviations from priority. With the exception of deviations from priority, the statistics in the tables suggest that OCRs are the most efficient form of reorganization, followed by prepacks, while traditional Chapter 11s are the least efficient form of distressed restructuring. Since prepack firms engage in extended pre-filing negotiations, why do these firms not merely reorganize out of court rather than file a prepack? McConnell and Servaes suggest three possible reasons. Two of these reasons relate to solving the holdout and free-rider problems that can arise in OCRs.11 Our sample provides some evidence on these points.

For an OCR to be successful, significant debt relief must be achieved. Most OCRs specify that 90% or 95% of creditors must participate in order for the plan be implemented. The level of support necessary for a bankruptcy plan to be confirmed is much lower and, if confirmed, 100% of creditors must participate. Furthermore, the court can “cram down” the plan on especially recalcitrant creditors. Thus, the cramdown provision under Chapter 11 can resolve even the most severe holdout problem where either one powerful creditor or a group of creditors blocks a reorganization plan that has broad support among the remaining creditors.12 Although the cram-down provision has been invoked relatively often for equity-holders in Chapter 11 bankruptcies, the provision has seldom been used for creditors. However, for two firms in our sample of 49 prepacks, the reorganization plan was crammed down on creditors, as well.13 The case of E-II Holdings, Inc. illustrates how the cram-down provision of the Bankruptcy Code can be used to solve severe holdout problems.

E-II was spun off in a 1987 leveraged buyout of Beatrice Companies. In 1991, E-II announced that it would stop paying interest on its bonds. After extended negotiations with an unofficial creditors’ committee, a plan of reorganization was proposed that provided debtholders a substantial equity stake in the firm. However, there was a major disagreement between senior and junior debtholders about the valuation of the firm. Senior debtholders favored a relatively conservative estimate of post-emergence value, which provided them a larger share of the firm's equity. Junior debtholders favored a higher valuation of the firm, which would reduce the proportion of equity required to pay senior debtholders in full.

During the restructuring discussions, two investors who specialize in trading securities in financially distressed firms (“vulture” investors) took substantial positions in E-II's two debt issues. Carl Icahn acquired 31% of the junior issue and Leon Black's Apollo Advisors acquired 24% of the senior debt issue and 27% of the junior debt issue. Thus, either Icahn or Black could effectively block any out-of-court reorganization.

In June 1992, E-II announced that an agreement in principle on a plan of reorganization had been reached with the creditors’ committee and filed its plan of reorganization. Although 90.5% in number of the voting junior debtholders subsequently supported the plan, clearing the 50% hurdle, only 59.5% in dollar amount cast favorable votes, thus falling short of the two-thirds requirement. Later E-II submitted a second plan wherein the estimated value of the firm was increased, thereby improving the apparent recovery rate for junior debtholders. The plan also gave senior debtholders the right to receive payment in equity rather than debt, thus giving them an option to maintain control of the firm. But, Icahn did not support the second plan because it did not give him a controlling equity position; therefore, the plan again failed to achieve the required level of support for confirmation. In the confirmation hearing, however, the court crammed down the firm's plan of reorganization on the dissenting junior debtholders, thereby circumventing the junior debtholders who had held out against the second plan.

Because all security holders must participate in any exchange of securities in Chapter 11, a bankruptcy reorganization can help to solve the free-rider problem that can arise in an OCR. Creditors have an incentive not to exchange their old securities for new ones with less favorable terms and, thereby, to “freeride” on the concessions granted by other creditors even though the exchange would benefit all creditors collectively. Because all creditors must exchange securities in a Chapter 11 reorganization, bankruptcy can resolve the free-rider problem by removing the incentive to free-ride on the concessions of others.

Our sample offers some insights into the way in which prepacks may provide a low-cost mechanism for solving the free-rider problem. In nine of the prepacks in our sample, the firm simultaneously mailed to creditors both a solicitation for an out-of-court exchange offer and a ballot for a prepackaged reorganization. The terms of the out-of-court restructuring and the prepack were identical. In each case, the firm indicated that the reorganization would be completed out of court if the exchange offer received sufficient participation. Because each of these firms ended up in our prepack sample, the OCR attempt obviously failed. In each of the four cases where we could obtain data, at least one class of claimholders gave a higher level of support for the prepackaged plan than for the proposed exchange offer. Apparently, the claimholders were more willing to participate in the prepack, which ensured 100% participation by claimholders, than in the identical exchange offer, which did not guarantee 100% participation.

Consider the specific case of Gaylord Container. Gaylord Acquisition Corp., subsequently Gaylord Container Corp., was formed in 1986 to acquire assets in the paper industry. Gaylord made numerous acquisitions between 1986 and 1989. In 1990 Moody's lowered its rating on the firm's debt, citing higher-than-expected operating costs and high debt levels. Gaylord suspended interest payments on its subordinated notes in 1991. In 1992, following negotiations with creditors, Gaylord filed a registration statement with the SEC for an exchange offer with a back-up plan for a prepack should the exchange offer fail. The firm determined that to restructure successfully, 95% (in amount) of the subordinated debtholders must tender in the exchange offer. When the solicitation period expired, only 89% of the subordinated debt was tendered; but, at the same time, holders of 97% of this debt consented to the prepack. The firm's CEO concluded, “Clearly, holders of the subordinated debt opted for the prepackaged plan alternative that binds 100% of the bondholders and, therefore, treats all holders equally.”14

In sum, prepacks appear to provide a means of resolving the free-rider problem in reorganizations of financially distressed firms.15

But if these results suggest that prepacks are a “cheap” substitute for traditional Chapter 11 filings, there are also good reasons to believe that prepacks are not an option for many of the firms that end up in Chapter 11. For example, a large percentage of the firms that chose a traditional Chapter 11 reorganization may simply have lacked the financial resources necessary to continue operations throughout the relatively long pre-filing negotiation period (18 months, on average) typical of a prepack.

Alternatively, our findings could also be used to support the case that prepacks are substitutes for OCRs in that prepacks offer an inexpensive solution to holdout and free-rider problems. This reading of the evidence would suggest that, before the rise of prepacks, if the costs of a traditional Chapter 11 were sufficiently greater than the costs of an OCR, even hesitant creditors may have been coerced into an out-of-court restructuring. But, insofar as a prepack now offers a low-cost mechanism for pressuring all creditors to participate, the firm may elect a prepack rather than an OCR.

Our best guess is that both arguments have some validity. That is, we believe that some firms that would have chosen an OCR in the past now choose to reorganize by means of a prepack, while other firms that would have opted for a traditional Chapter 11 also choose to reorganize with a prepack. Lending support to this view are our findings that pre-voted prepacks have outcomes much closer to those of OCRs while post-voted prepacks look more like traditional Chapter 11s.

In this sense, the advent of prepacks can be viewed as providing yet another option for financially distressed firms. Indeed, our findings can be interpreted as suggesting that prepacks themselves add to a range of possible solutions to financial distress that stretches between OCRs at one extreme and traditional Chapter 11s at the other. In each case, the solution reflects the working out of a process in which creditors and debtors are free to choose the method of reorganization that provides the greatest benefit at the lowest cost given their particular circumstances. It is our hope that the data provided here will be of use to debtors and creditors confronted with these choices.

分享
查看原文
预付款作为解决财务困境的机制:证据
预打包破产或“预打包”被认为是不良重组的一种混合形式,因为它们与广泛使用的重组不良公司的替代方案——庭外重组(OCR)和传统的第11章重组——都有某些特征。预扣与OCR类似,债权人和债务人在法院外同意重组的主要条款。预扣与传统的第11章备案类似,因为重组是在法院监督下进行的,对计划的确认需要每类索赔人三分之二的金额和一半的数量的批准,所有索赔人必须根据计划条款交换他们的旧证券。在一个预先包装中,第11章破产申请和重组计划同时提交给法院。约翰·麦康奈尔(John McConnell)和亨利·塞尔维斯(Henri Servaes。随着时间的推移和预包装数量的增长,我们已经能够收集大量预包装样本的数据。我们对预包装的研究补充了越来越多的关于各种形式的不良重组结果的文献。本文献中的一个重要问题是各种重组程序是否有效。低效的重组程序可能导致公司的直接成本过高或融资和投资决策不理想。最有效的组织程序是为公司创造最大价值的程序,扣除所有成本。虽然效率不能直接观察,但我们提供了一些间接衡量效率的证据,例如重组所需的时间、重组成本和债权人的回收率。在数据可用的情况下,我们将预包装与OCR和传统的第11章进行比较。我们发现,在考虑的大多数方面,预包装介于重组陷入财务困境的公司的两种替代方法之间。例如,预打包的重组成本(作为资产的一部分)高于OCR,但低于传统破产的成本。这些发现支持了这样一种观点,即预包装是一种混合形式的重组,包含了OCR和传统第11章的某些方面。我们的样本包括1986年至1993年6月期间提交预包装的49家财务困境公司。Crystal Oil于1986年申请了预包装,被广泛认为是大型公司的第一个预包装。继Crystal Oil之后,我们样本中的下两个预包装发生在1989年,总资产为17亿美元。在此后的几年里,1990年发生了四次,总资产为36亿美元,1991年发生了13次,资产为52亿美元,1992年发生了17次,资产112亿美元,1993年前六个月(我们研究的截止点)发生了12次,总资产超过55亿美元。此外,在1993年,22家资产超过1亿美元的上市公司中,有12家(或超过50%)申请了第11章的预包装(使用我们对该术语的定义)。1994年,29家(或38%)此类公司中有11家提交了预投票。2我们的样本包括两种预投票类型——“预投票”和“后投票”预投票。3在预投票预投票中,索赔人在向法院提交第11章破产申请之前对重组计划进行投票。破产申请和投票结果随后与重组计划一起提交。在没有不当披露或投票违规的情况下,提交前的投票对所有索赔人都有约束力。在投票后的预包装中,破产申请和重组计划同时提交,但在索赔人正式投票之前。然后在法院的管辖下进行投票。在我们的预投票样本中,32个是预投票的,17个是后投票的。所有49家公司最终都进行了重组,并脱离了第11章。不出所料,与投票后的预包装相比,投票前的预包装在第11章中所需的时间更少。事实证明,投票前和投票后的预包装在其他方面也有所不同。特别是,预先投票的预打包涉及较大的公司,涉及较长的备案前谈判时间,产生较低的比例费用,为债权人提供较高的回收率,与绝对优先权的美元百分比偏差较大,并为债权人提供较低的重组后股权所有权。现在我们来谈谈重组效率的代理指标。 为了将我们的调查放在上下文中,我们将我们的效率指标与其他研究中报告的OCR和传统的第11章重组产生的类似统计数据进行了比较。4除此之外,与效率较低的重组过程相比,高效的重组过程需要更短的时间、更低的成本,并将导致更高的回收率。此外,一个有效的过程应该导致与优先权的偏离程度较低。除了偏离优先级之外,表中的统计数据表明,OCR是最有效的重组形式,其次是预打包,而传统的第11章是最低效的不良重组形式。既然预包装公司参与延长的预包装谈判,为什么这些公司不只是庭外重组,而不是提交预包装?McConnell和Servaes提出了三个可能的原因。其中两个原因与解决OCRs中可能出现的拒绝和搭便车问题有关。11我们的样本提供了一些关于这些问题的证据。为了OCR的成功,必须实现重大的债务减免。大多数OCR规定,90%或95%的债权人必须参与才能实施该计划。破产计划得到确认所需的支持水平要低得多,如果得到确认,必须有100%的债权人参与。此外,法院可以将该计划“强加”给特别顽固的债权人。因此,即使是最严重的拒不执行问题,即一个强大的债权人或一群债权人阻止了在其余债权人中得到广泛支持的重组计划,第11章下的强制执行条款也可以解决。12尽管在第11章破产案中,股权持有人相对经常援引强制执行条款,该条款很少用于债权人。然而,在我们的49个预包装样本中,有两家公司的重组计划也被压在了债权人身上。13 E-II Holdings,股份有限公司的案例说明了如何利用破产法中的紧急条款来解决严重的拖延问题。E-II是在1987年对碧翠丝公司的杠杆收购中分拆出来的。1991年,E-II宣布将停止支付债券利息。在与非官方债权人委员会进行了长期谈判后,提出了一项重组计划,为债权人提供了该公司的大量股权。然而,高级和初级债券持有人对该公司的估值存在重大分歧。资深债券持有人倾向于对上市后价值进行相对保守的估计,这为他们提供了更大的公司股权份额。初级债券持有人倾向于对公司进行更高的估值,这将降低全额支付高级债券持有人所需的股权比例。在重组讨论期间,两名专门从事金融危机公司证券交易的投资者(“秃鹫”投资者)在E-II的两次债务发行中持有大量头寸。Carl Icahn收购了初级债券31%的股份,Leon Black的Apollo Advisors收购了高级债券24%的股份和初级债券27%的股份。因此,伊坎或布莱克都可以有效地阻止任何庭外重组。1992年6月,E-II宣布已与债权人委员会就重组计划达成原则性协议,并提交了重组计划。尽管90.5%的有投票权的初级债券持有人随后支持该计划,扫清了50%的障碍,但只有59.5%的美元持有人投了赞成票,因此达不到三分之二的要求。后来,E-II提交了第二份计划,其中增加了公司的估计价值,从而提高了初级债券持有人的表观回收率。该计划还赋予高级债券持有人以股权而非债务形式获得付款的权利,从而使他们可以选择保持对公司的控制。但是,伊坎不支持第二个计划,因为它没有给他一个控制股权的地位;因此,该计划再次未能达到确认所需的支持水平。然而,在确认听证会上,法院将公司的重组计划强加给了持异议的初级债券持有人,从而绕过了坚持反对第二个计划的初级债券持有人。因为所有证券持有人都必须参与第11章中的任何证券交易,破产重组可以帮助解决OCR中可能出现的搭便车问题。债权人有动机不把他们的旧证券换成条件不太优惠的新证券,从而“搭便车”获得其他债权人给予的优惠,即使这种交换将使所有债权人集体受益。 因为在第11章重组中,所有债权人都必须交换证券,破产可以通过消除搭便车的动机来解决搭便车问题。我们的样本提供了一些关于预包装可以为解决搭便车问题提供低成本机制的见解。在我们样本中的九个预包装中,该公司同时向债权人邮寄了一份庭外交换要约的征求书和一份预包装重组的投票。庭外重组和预包装的条款是相同的。在每一个案例中,该公司都表示,如果交换要约得到足够的参与,重组将在庭外完成。因为这些公司中的每一家最终都出现在我们的预包装样本中,OCR尝试显然失败了。在我们可以获得数据的四种情况中,至少有一类索赔人对预先包装的计划的支持程度高于对拟议交换要约的支持程度。显然,与不能保证100%参与的相同交换要约相比,索赔人更愿意参与确保索赔人100%参与的预包装。考虑一下盖洛德集装箱的具体情况。盖洛德收购公司,后来的盖洛德集装箱公司,成立于1986年,旨在收购造纸行业的资产。盖洛德在1986年至1989年间进行了多次收购。1990年,穆迪降低了对该公司债务的评级,理由是运营成本高于预期,债务水平高。盖洛德于1991年暂停支付其次级债券的利息。1992年,在与债权人谈判后,盖洛德向美国证券交易委员会提交了一份交换要约的注册声明,并在交换要约失败时提供了一份备用计划。该公司决定,要成功重组,95%(金额)的次级债券持有人必须在交换要约中投标。招标期届满时,只有89%的次级债务被招标;但与此同时,持有该笔债务97%的持有人同意了预打包。该公司首席执行官总结道:“很明显,次级债务持有人选择了对100%债券持有人具有约束力的预先打包计划替代方案,因此对所有持有人一视同仁。”14总之,预包装似乎为解决陷入财务困境的公司重组中的搭便车问题提供了一种手段。15但如果这些结果表明预包装是传统的第11章备案的“廉价”替代品,那么也有充分的理由相信,对于许多最终进入第11章的公司来说,预包装不是一种选择。例如,选择传统的第11章重组的公司中,很大一部分可能只是缺乏在相对较长的备案前谈判期(平均18个月)内继续运营所需的财政资源,这是典型的预包装。或者,我们的研究结果也可以用来支持预包装是OCR的替代品的情况,因为预包装为拒绝和搭便车问题提供了一种廉价的解决方案。对证据的解读表明,在预包装兴起之前,如果传统的第11章的成本远远高于OCR的成本,即使是犹豫不决的债权人也可能被迫进行庭外重组。但是,就预包装现在提供了一种低成本的机制来迫使所有债权人参与而言,公司可能会选择预包装而不是OCR。我们的最佳猜测是,这两种论点都有一定的有效性。也就是说,我们认为,一些过去会选择OCR的公司现在选择通过预包装的方式进行重组,而其他选择传统第11章的公司也选择用预包装进行重组。我们的研究结果支持了这一观点,即投票前的预包装的结果与OCR的结果更接近,而投票后的预包装看起来更像传统的第11章。从这个意义上说,预包装的出现可以被视为为为陷入财务困境的公司提供了另一种选择。事实上,我们的研究结果可以被解释为,预包装本身增加了一系列可能的财务困境解决方案,这些财务困境既有OCR的极端,也有传统的第11章的极端。在每种情况下,解决办法都反映了一个程序的制定,在这个程序中,债权人和债务人可以自由选择在其特定情况下以最低成本提供最大利益的重组方法。我们希望,这里提供的数据将对面临这些选择的债务人和债权人有用。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信