Comment on “Income and Wealth Inequality in Asia and the Pacific: Trends, Causes, and Policy Remedies”

IF 4.5 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS
Li Gan
{"title":"Comment on “Income and Wealth Inequality in Asia and the Pacific: Trends, Causes, and Policy Remedies”","authors":"Li Gan","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12409","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>I agree with Zhuang (<span>2022</span>) in his summary assessments of the negative effects of income inequality. Zhuang (<span>2022</span>) includes a section on the inequality in China, so I would like to focus my comments on this section, and particularly on the working-age households in China.</p><p>Most of the inequality measures cited in Zhang's paper and in other studies are from OECD or World Bank calculations. China's measures come from the National Bureau of Statistics (NBS). Unfortunately, it is difficult to decompose NBS' measures since the micro-level data used by the NBS are not publicly available.</p><p>Fortunately, there are several large-scale academic household surveys that are available – one of them is the China Household Income Project, led by Zhuang's coauthor on other occasions, Shi Li from Zhejiang University. My analysis here is partially based on another survey, the China Household Finance Survey, that I am the lead investigator for.</p><p>Zhuang (<span>2022</span>) discusses income inequality decade-wise since the 1980s. I would like to list the biennial changes of income inequality since 2010. Table 1 lists the P90/P50 ratios between 2010–2018. According to Table 1, inequality decreased slightly, from 3.65 to 3.28, between 2010 and 2018. However, working-age households did not see much change in these ratios, while families with retired people (at least one person in the family is older than 60) see a significant drop in inequality, from 5.09 to 3.21.</p><p>To understand the reason for this, we compare government transfers to the elderly in the form of pension payments, and government transfers to working-age households. The former includes payments to retirees covered by both the Basic Employee Pension Insurance and the Resident Pension Insurance. The latter includes payments from all social assistance programs, such as unemployment benefits and <i>Dibao</i> payments.</p><p>According to the official statistics, the percentage of pension payments to gross domestic product (GDP) more than doubled from 2.1% in 2010 to 5.4%, in 2019. Meanwhile, the percentage of social assistance to GDP decreased from 0.97% to 0.80%. The increase of social pension payments to GDP is a combination of rising benefits and rising numbers of retirees. The per capita pension payment was RMB 8144 in 2012, and RMB 18,958 in 2020 with an annual growth rate of 11.1%. Meanwhile, nominal per capita GDP only grew 7.74% annually. This is because of the differences in social spending, and the reduction in income inequality among elderly in China while income inequality among working-age families is stagnant.</p><p>Figure 1 indicates China's social spending relative to other countries. The left panel plots total pension payments as a percentage of GDP, relative to its GDP per capita. This panel shows that China's pension payments are on par with the projected world average indicated by a regression line. However, the right panel of Figure 1 plots the social spending on working-age households relative to its GDP per capita, and we observe that China's figure is far below the projected world average.</p><p>Figure 1 shows that China is aggressively transferring money to the elderly, but not to working-age households. I believe this is largely due to a (mis)understanding of the consequences of the social welfare system. Official documents show that Chinese government is deeply suspicious of “welfarism.” President Xi recently instructed the government in “preventing ‘welfarism’ trap” as one of the key elements in reaching the “common prosperity” (Xi, August 21, 2021, “Qiushi”). Similar statements have repeatedly appeared in many government documents.</p><p>However, a large literature has convincingly shown that the “welfare dependent” essentially does not exist if the amount of transfers is not too large. In Banerjee <i>et al</i>. (<span>2017</span>), social assistance in developing countries did not generate disincentives to work since the amount of transfers is only about 10% of consumption. The first Covid-related government program in the US, The CARES Act, raised the unemployment benefit to be 47% higher than the labor income for a median worker. Petroksy-Nadeau and Valletta (<span>2021</span>) find that even such benefits did not generate incentives for people to quit their jobs. This is because the Covid-related unemployment benefits lasted only a few months. Therefore, the present value of the benefit is not large enough to generate disincentives to work.</p><p>Yet the literature has documented that transfers to the working-age poor could be effective in stimulating consumption (Gan <i>et al</i>., <span>2018</span>). Social transfers are also beneficial for households' human capital accumulation (García &amp; Saavedra, <span>2017</span>). Both effects are critical for China's economy now and in the future.</p><p>In conclusion, the key to reducing income inequality in China is to substantially increase transfers to the working-age poor. However, doing so requires demystifying the widely held belief of “welfarism” among government officials.</p>","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":"18 1","pages":"42-44"},"PeriodicalIF":4.5000,"publicationDate":"2022-09-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12409","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Asian Economic Policy Review","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/aepr.12409","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

I agree with Zhuang (2022) in his summary assessments of the negative effects of income inequality. Zhuang (2022) includes a section on the inequality in China, so I would like to focus my comments on this section, and particularly on the working-age households in China.

Most of the inequality measures cited in Zhang's paper and in other studies are from OECD or World Bank calculations. China's measures come from the National Bureau of Statistics (NBS). Unfortunately, it is difficult to decompose NBS' measures since the micro-level data used by the NBS are not publicly available.

Fortunately, there are several large-scale academic household surveys that are available – one of them is the China Household Income Project, led by Zhuang's coauthor on other occasions, Shi Li from Zhejiang University. My analysis here is partially based on another survey, the China Household Finance Survey, that I am the lead investigator for.

Zhuang (2022) discusses income inequality decade-wise since the 1980s. I would like to list the biennial changes of income inequality since 2010. Table 1 lists the P90/P50 ratios between 2010–2018. According to Table 1, inequality decreased slightly, from 3.65 to 3.28, between 2010 and 2018. However, working-age households did not see much change in these ratios, while families with retired people (at least one person in the family is older than 60) see a significant drop in inequality, from 5.09 to 3.21.

To understand the reason for this, we compare government transfers to the elderly in the form of pension payments, and government transfers to working-age households. The former includes payments to retirees covered by both the Basic Employee Pension Insurance and the Resident Pension Insurance. The latter includes payments from all social assistance programs, such as unemployment benefits and Dibao payments.

According to the official statistics, the percentage of pension payments to gross domestic product (GDP) more than doubled from 2.1% in 2010 to 5.4%, in 2019. Meanwhile, the percentage of social assistance to GDP decreased from 0.97% to 0.80%. The increase of social pension payments to GDP is a combination of rising benefits and rising numbers of retirees. The per capita pension payment was RMB 8144 in 2012, and RMB 18,958 in 2020 with an annual growth rate of 11.1%. Meanwhile, nominal per capita GDP only grew 7.74% annually. This is because of the differences in social spending, and the reduction in income inequality among elderly in China while income inequality among working-age families is stagnant.

Figure 1 indicates China's social spending relative to other countries. The left panel plots total pension payments as a percentage of GDP, relative to its GDP per capita. This panel shows that China's pension payments are on par with the projected world average indicated by a regression line. However, the right panel of Figure 1 plots the social spending on working-age households relative to its GDP per capita, and we observe that China's figure is far below the projected world average.

Figure 1 shows that China is aggressively transferring money to the elderly, but not to working-age households. I believe this is largely due to a (mis)understanding of the consequences of the social welfare system. Official documents show that Chinese government is deeply suspicious of “welfarism.” President Xi recently instructed the government in “preventing ‘welfarism’ trap” as one of the key elements in reaching the “common prosperity” (Xi, August 21, 2021, “Qiushi”). Similar statements have repeatedly appeared in many government documents.

However, a large literature has convincingly shown that the “welfare dependent” essentially does not exist if the amount of transfers is not too large. In Banerjee et al. (2017), social assistance in developing countries did not generate disincentives to work since the amount of transfers is only about 10% of consumption. The first Covid-related government program in the US, The CARES Act, raised the unemployment benefit to be 47% higher than the labor income for a median worker. Petroksy-Nadeau and Valletta (2021) find that even such benefits did not generate incentives for people to quit their jobs. This is because the Covid-related unemployment benefits lasted only a few months. Therefore, the present value of the benefit is not large enough to generate disincentives to work.

Yet the literature has documented that transfers to the working-age poor could be effective in stimulating consumption (Gan et al., 2018). Social transfers are also beneficial for households' human capital accumulation (García & Saavedra, 2017). Both effects are critical for China's economy now and in the future.

In conclusion, the key to reducing income inequality in China is to substantially increase transfers to the working-age poor. However, doing so requires demystifying the widely held belief of “welfarism” among government officials.

Abstract Image

评“亚太地区收入和财富不平等:趋势、原因和政策补救”
我同意庄(2022)对收入不平等负面影响的总结评估。庄(2022)有一节是关于中国的不平等,所以我想把我的评论集中在这一节上,特别是中国的劳动年龄家庭。张的论文和其他研究中引用的大多数不平等指标都来自经合组织或世界银行的计算。中国的数据来自国家统计局。不幸的是,由于国家统计局使用的微观数据尚未公开,因此很难分解国家统计局的衡量标准。幸运的是,有几项大规模的学术家庭调查可用,其中之一是由庄的合著者、浙江大学的施力领导的中国家庭收入项目。我在这里的分析部分基于另一项调查,中国家庭金融调查,我是该调查的首席调查员。庄(2022)讨论了自20世纪80年代以来的收入不平等问题。我想列出自2010年以来收入不平等的两年变化情况。表1列出了2010-2018年间的P90/P50比率。根据表1,2010年至2018年间,不平等现象略有下降,从3.65降至3.28。然而,工作年龄家庭的这些比例没有太大变化,而有退休人员的家庭(家庭中至少有一人年龄超过60岁)的不平等现象显著下降,从5.09下降到3.21。为了理解原因,我们比较了政府以养老金支付的形式向老年人转移的资金和政府向工作年龄家庭转移的资金。前者包括支付给退休人员的基本职工养老保险和居民养老保险。后者包括所有社会援助项目的付款,如失业救济金和迪宝付款。根据官方统计数据,养老金支付占国内生产总值的比例从2010年的2.1%增加到2019年的5.4%,翻了一番多。与此同时,社会救助占GDP的比例从0.97%下降到0.80%。社会养老金支付占GDP的增加是福利增加和退休人数增加的综合作用。2012年,人均养老金支付额为8144元,2020年为18958元,年增长率为11.1%,而名义人均GDP年增长率仅为7.74%。这是因为社会支出的差异,以及中国老年人收入不平等的减少,而劳动年龄家庭的收入不平等却停滞不前。图1显示了中国相对于其他国家的社会支出。左侧面板将养老金支付总额绘制为GDP相对于人均GDP的百分比。该面板显示,中国的养老金支付与回归线所示的预计世界平均水平持平。然而,图1的右侧面板绘制了劳动年龄家庭的社会支出与其人均GDP的关系图,我们观察到中国的数字远低于预计的世界平均水平。图1显示,中国正在积极向老年人转移资金,但没有向劳动年龄家庭转移。我认为这主要是由于对社会福利制度后果的(错误)理解。官方文件显示,中国政府对“福利主义”深表怀疑。Xi主席最近指示政府“防止‘福利主义’陷阱”,将其作为实现“共同富裕”的关键要素之一(Xi,2021年8月21日,《求是》)。类似的声明多次出现在许多政府文件中。然而,大量文献令人信服地表明,如果转移金额不太大,“依赖福利的”基本上就不存在。在Banerjee等人(2017)中,发展中国家的社会援助并没有抑制工作,因为转移金额仅占消费的10%左右。美国第一个与新冠肺炎相关的政府计划《关怀法案》将失业救济金提高到比中等工人的劳动收入高47%。Petroksy Nadeau和Valletta(2021)发现,即使是这样的福利也不会激励人们辞职。这是因为与新冠肺炎相关的失业救济金只持续了几个月。因此,福利的现值不足以抑制工作。然而,文献证明,向工作年龄的穷人转移可以有效刺激消费(Gan et al.,2018)。社会转移也有利于家庭的人力资本积累(García&;Saavedra,2017)。这两种影响对中国经济现在和未来都至关重要。总之,减少中国收入不平等的关键是大幅增加对劳动年龄贫困人口的转移支付。然而,这样做需要揭开政府官员中普遍存在的“福利主义”的神秘面纱。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
CiteScore
12.90
自引率
2.60%
发文量
39
期刊介绍: The goal of the Asian Economic Policy Review is to become an intellectual voice on the current issues of international economics and economic policy, based on comprehensive and in-depth analyses, with a primary focus on Asia. Emphasis is placed on identifying key issues at the time - spanning international trade, international finance, the environment, energy, the integration of regional economies and other issues - in order to furnish ideas and proposals to contribute positively to the policy debate in the region.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信