Vanderbilt university roundtable on the capital structure puzzle

Pub Date : 2023-04-26 DOI:10.1111/jacf.12539
Stewart Myers, John McConnell, Alice Peterson, Dennis Soter, Joel Stern
{"title":"Vanderbilt university roundtable on the capital structure puzzle","authors":"Stewart Myers,&nbsp;John McConnell,&nbsp;Alice Peterson,&nbsp;Dennis Soter,&nbsp;Joel Stern","doi":"10.1111/jacf.12539","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>April 2, 1998         Nashville, Tennessee</p><p>JOEL STERN: Good afternoon. I'm Joel Stern, managing partner of Stern Stewart &amp; Co., and, on behalf of our hosts here at Vanderbilt's Owen Graduate School of Management, I want to welcome you all to this discussion of corporate capital structure. Before getting into our subject matter, let me take a moment to thank Hans Stoll for organizing this conference on “Financial Markets and the Corporation.” I also want to take this opportunity to salute Professor Martin Weingartner—in whose honor this conference is being held—at the conclusion of a long and productive career. Marty's contributions to the field of corporate finance are many and considerable; and, though he may be stepping down from his formal position, we expect to continue to hear from him for many more years.</p><p>The subject of today's meeting is corporate capital structure: Does capital structure matter? And, if so, how and why does it matter? Although these questions have been seriously debated in the academic finance profession for almost 40 years, we seem to be no closer to a definitive answer than we were in 1958, when Merton Miller and Franco Modigliani published their article presenting the first of their two famous “irrelevance” propositions.</p><p>Following the M&amp;M propositions, academic researchers in the 1960s and 1970s turned their attention to various market “imperfections” that might make firm value depend on capital structure and dividend policy. The main suspects were (1) a tax code that encourages debt by making interest payments, but not dividends, tax deductible, and (2) expected costs of financial distress, including corporate underinvestment, that can become important as you increase the amount of debt in the capital structure. Toward the end of the 1970s, there was also discussion of “signaling” effects—for example, the tendency for the stock market to respond negatively to announcements of new stock issues.</p><p>A defining moment in the academic capital structure debate came in 1984, when Professor Stewart Myers devoted his Presidential address to the American Finance Association to something he called “The Capital Structure Puzzle.” The puzzle was this: Most academic discussions of capital structure were based on the assumption that companies make financing decisions that are guided by a <i>target capital structure</i>—a proportion of debt to equity that management aims to achieve, if not at all times, then at least as a long-run average. But the empirical evidence suggested otherwise. Rather than adhering to targets, Professor Myers observed, most large U.S. public companies behaved as if they were following a financial “pecking order.” They were funding investment with retained earnings rather than external financing if possible; and if external funding was necessary, they issued debt first and equity only as a last resort.</p><p>Since then, the capital structure debate has raged on. Harvard professor Michael Jensen entered it in the mid-1980s, pointing to the success of LBOs and citing the beneficial effect of debt financing on management's tendency to overinvest in industries with excess capital and capacity. And, as if to oblige Professor Jensen, the market continued to supply large numbers of LBOs and other highly leveraged transactions throughout the rest of the decade. Then, in the early 1990s, we saw an almost complete halt to leveraged deals. But today, of course, leverage is back. A new wave of LBOs has shattered most of the old records, and junk-bond issuance is at all-time highs.</p><p>So, if capital structure is irrelevant, then what's going on here? And do the successes of the LBO movement have anything to say to the managements of our largest public companies? Such effects seemed to confirm the existence of large “information costs” that might also influence corporate financing choices in predictable ways.</p><p>With us here to discuss these issues, and to help us shed some light on this capital structure puzzle, is a small, but distinguished group of academics and practitioners. And let me introduce them briefly:</p><p>STEWART MYERS, whose name I have already mentioned several times, is the Billard Professor of Corporate Finance at one of my favorite schools, the MIT Sloan School of Management. Stew has done research over the years in issues dealing with capital structure, valuation, and regulation. He has also been an adviser to a large number of corporations and financial institutions. And let me mention that, for us at Stern Stewart, the name Stewart Myers has a special significance. As most people here are well aware, Stew is the co-author, with Dick Brealey of the London Business School, of <i>Principles of Corporate Finance</i>, the leading textbook in corporate finance. Every person who gets hired at Stern Stewart is required to have read that volume by the time he or she walks in the door.</p><p>ALICE PETERSON is Vice President and Treasurer of Sears, Roebuck and Co. As we all know, Sears has made dramatic improvements in operating performance and achieved large increases in shareholder value over the past few years. Alice joined Sears in 1989 as Director of Corporate Finance, 4 years before being made Vice President and Treasurer in 1993. Prior to coming to Sears, she held corporate finance and treasury positions at Kraft and at Pepsico. She earned her MBA here at Vanderbilt in 1981, and she serves on the boards of two New York Stock Exchange companies.</p><p>JOHN McCONNELL is the Emanuel T. Weiler Professor of Finance at Purdue University. John has made extensive contributions to the field of corporate finance, especially in the analysis of innovative securities. I still remember an article on income bonds that John contributed to our old <i>Chase Financial Quarterly</i>, the original predecessor of our <i>Journal of Applied Corporate Finance</i>. And, in an issue of the <i>JACF</i> about 5 or 6 years ago, John coauthored (with Eduardo Schwartz) a fascinating account of the origins of LYONS, the very successful puttable, convertible securities pioneered by Merrill Lynch. Given John's ability to tell stories, none of us is surprised that he manages to win teaching awards at Purdue year after year.</p><p>Last is DENNIS SOTER, my colleague and fellow partner at Stern Stewart. After graduating from the University of Rochester's Simon School of Business in 1972, Dennis joined me at the Chase Manhattan Bank. Then, in 1979, we parted ways. Dennis became Vice President in charge of corporate development at Brown Foreman, where he helped transform the firm from the maker of Jack Daniels (and other mild intoxicants) into a diversified consumer goods firm. Then he went to Ernst &amp; Whinney, where he was the national practice director of M&amp;A. Next, he joined Citizens Utilities and helped them to become something of an unregulated company as well as a regulated company.</p><p>Several years ago, we were very fortunate in persuading each other that we should be together again. And Dennis now runs our corporate finance advisory activity and also oversees implementations of EVA in middle market-sized companies. In the past 2 years, as I'm sure Dennis will tell us, he served as financial adviser in three highly successful leveraged recapitalizations. Each of these three deals involved borrowing substantial amounts of new debt to buy back shares—and two involved major changes major changes in dividend policy as well.</p><p>STERN: So, now that we know who the panelists are, let me turn the floor over to Professor Stewart Myers. You might not remember this, Stew, but in 1983 you were kind enough to publish an article in our <i>Midland Corporate Finance Journal</i> entitled “The Search for Optimal Capital Structure.”</p><p>And it was not only a marvelous piece, but it was the lead article in the very first issue—Volume 1 Number 1—of that journal. Then, about 10 years passed, and you wrote a second article for us that was called “Still Searching for Optimal Capital Structure.”</p><p>And that was also a wonderful piece—one that I use (along with the first one) in the courses I teach at Columbia and Carnegie Mellon.</p><p>My question for you is: What is your current thinking on the capital structure debate? And what are you going to call your next article?</p><p>STEWART MYERS: The next one is going to be called “<i>Stop</i> Searching for Optimal Capital Structure.” Let me take a minute or two to tell you why. Optimal capital structure is obviously something I've been concerned and struggling with ever since I arrived at the doctoral program at Stanford. I've been frustrated over the years by our inability to come up with any simple answer. But I am lately coming to a different view. Maybe it will start the discussion off.</p><p>When we talk about optimal capital structure, we are thinking of the percentages of different securities on the right-hand side of the balance sheet. We tend to think in terms of the mix of debt and equity, at least to start, and then go on to consider other securities as well. We look at preferred stock, for example, and at hybrid securities like convertible debt.</p><p>At what level do we understand how these financing choices affect firm value? At a tactical level, I think we understand it very well. For example, if you ask either academics or practitioners to analyze a financial innovation like the tax-deductible preferreds that John McConnell just finished telling us about, we do that pretty well. We understand how those things work, why they're designed the way they are, and what you need to do to get them sold. So, at this tactical level, we can be fairly satisfied with our understanding of capital structure.</p><p>Where we tend to fall down in terms of neat or simple theories is in understanding the role of capital structure at what I will call the “strategic” level—that is, when you're trying to explain the debt ratios of companies on average or over long periods of time. We do have some useful insights about capital structure, and we know what <i>ought</i> to matter. But it's very difficult to put these insights together into a simple theory that predicts what managers are going to do—or tells us what they should be doing.</p><p>Why aren't we cracking the problem? I think we are starting in the wrong place. We shouldn't be starting with the percentages of different kinds of financing on the right-hand side of the balance sheet. We should not be starting with capital structure, but with <i>financial</i> structure. By financial structure I mean the allocation of ownership and control, which includes the division of the risk and returns of the enterprise—and particularly of its intangible assets—between the insiders in the firm and the outsiders.</p><p>What's really going on in the public corporation is a <i>coinvestment</i> by insiders, who bring their human capital to it, and by financial investors. These two groups share the <i>intangible</i> assets of the organization. And, in order to make that shared investment work, you've got to figure out issues of ownership and control, incentives, risk-sharing, and so forth. You've got to start by making sure you get all of those things right. That's what I call financial structure.</p><p>Financial structure is not the same thing as a financing mix. Let me offer a simple example. Take a high-tech venture capital startup and compare it to Microsoft. Even though their debt ratios are likely to be identical—that is, zero—I think we'd all agree that they are not the same thing from a financial point of view. The same comparison could be made between a publicly held management consulting company and the usual private management consulting firm. Though their balance sheets might look exactly the same, I would say they're very different. In particular, I would predict that if you take a small consulting company public, it's almost sure to crater. The assets go home every night, and it's going to be very difficult to have the right incentives to keep key people in the company while at the same time satisfying outside investors.</p><p>So, if Stern Stewart ever goes public, Joel, I'm going to wait 6 months and then sell you short.</p><p>STERN: I actually had a dream that somebody was going to do that to us—but I had no idea, Stew, that it was going to be you! I must confess that such thoughts have passed through my mind. But, if we were to take such a course (which we have no plan to do), we would design the new firm so as to protect outside investors not so much from the possibility that the assets go home at night, but that they might move to the island of Maui, permanently.</p><p>Incidentally, this is not an unreasonable issue because Booz-Allen did that once. You may not be aware of it, but in the 1970s Booz-Allen went public at a price in the mid-teens. The shares went as high as about $20 and then dropped to about $2—and they stayed between $2 and $6 for quite a while. The reason I know about it is that I served on the board of directors of a company with the Vice Chairman of Booz-Allen. And every time the possibility of going public was raised for this privately held company, he would say: “It's the wrong thing to do.” And he would drag us through this horrible experience once more.</p><p>But Booz-Allen made a fundamental mistake—one that, if corrected, might have changed the outcome. They didn't differentiate between outsider shares and insider shares. If the insiders own shares that only gradually convert to outsider shares, the insiders aren't going anywhere. They could also have issued stock options to the employees with values tied to the value of the insider shares. With insider shares and options, it would take a long time for people to take out the wealth that they were building up in the firm.</p><p>How do you feel about that idea, Stew?</p><p>MYERS: I think you're just making my point. First of all, I don't think that it makes sense to take a small consulting company public. But if you did, you'd have to pay attention to financial structure—to issues like who owns what, who gets to make what decisions, what are the goals and performance measures, and how are people rewarded for meeting them.</p><p>STERN: So, your concept of financial structure is essentially the same as what some people are calling corporate governance or organizational structure—it's the assignment of decision rights, monitoring, performance measures, incentives, and all of that?</p><p>MYERS: Financial structure is my shorthand—just two words—for all of that sort of stuff. My point is that these issues of financial structure are the first-order concerns of most corporations. Management has to get them right.</p><p>Now, that's not the same as saying that managers have to do all these things consciously. Sometimes they get it right because they do what other corporations have done and survived.</p><p>Once an industrial corporation goes public, it's ordinarily a mid-cap firm with a financial structure well in place. In a sense, it has solved 80% of its problem—that is, as long as it keeps operating efficiently. Having solved that problem, I don't think most corporations worry a great deal about their debt-equity ratio. Obviously, they worry if it gets too high and they worry if it gets too low. But there's a big middle range where it doesn't seem to matter very much. I think that's why we're having a hard time pinning down exactly what the debt-equity ratio is or should be. It's a “second order” thing compared to the choice of financial structure.</p><p>STERN: Well, people have pointed out that the tax-deductibility of interest expense makes debt a way of adding considerable value. And because of the value added by those tax shields, one could argue that aggressive use of debt may turn out to be the best defense against an unfriendly takeover. Doesn't that argument seem to imply that capital structure could at least <i>become</i> a first-order concern?</p><p>MYERS: By raising the issue of hostile takeovers, I think you are mixing up the investment decision with the financing decision. I would like to keep them separate, at least as a starting point. Most takeover targets become targets not because they don't have enough debt, but because of bad investment decisions and poor operating performance. The primary cause of the wave of LBOs in the 1980s was not corporate failure to exploit the tax advantage of debt. Most of the LBOs—and I'm oversimplifying a little—were “diet deals.” They involved taking over mature companies with too much cash and too few investment opportunities and putting them on a diet. So, although there were tax savings, the transactions themselves were not tax-driven.</p><p>DENNIS SOTER: Most of the companies that we have worked with over the years do spend a lot of time thinking about capital structure. Now, it's true that they typically do not think about it the way academics do—that is, in terms of a <i>market</i> debt-to-equity ratio. Most of them define their objectives in terms of bond ratings or book leverage. But they do have loosely defined financial strategies and some idea of what constitutes an appropriate mix of debt and equity in their capital structure.</p><p>I'd like to ask Professor Myers a question: You used the term “optimal capital structure.” Would you define that for us?</p><p>MYERS: In its simplest terms, optimal capital structure is the optimal percentage of debt on the balance sheet.</p><p>SOTER: But optimal from what standpoint?</p><p>MYERS: Maximizing the market value of the company. I'm not saying that's the wrong question, or an irrelevant or an uninteresting question. It's a very interesting question. But I think by focusing too narrowly on that, you miss these other things which I put under the rubric of financial structure—things which I tend to think are more important to corporate managers, and so more powerful in explaining the corporate behavior we see.</p><p>STERN: I think you're right, at least in the sense that I regularly see behavior that doesn't appear to me to be value-maximizing. For example, in a roundtable discussion we ran a few years ago, one of the participants was an owner of a publicly traded company where he and his family owned about 37% of the equity. And I asked him why his debt ratio was so low. I said to him, “You're volunteering to pay an awful lot in taxes that you could avoid. Why don't you raise your debt ratio to the point where most of your pre-tax operating income is tax-sheltered?”</p><p>You see, the amount of taxes he was paying was quite sizeable; it was some $12–$15 million a year that was literally going out the door that could have been saved just by changing the capital structure. Why do companies do that, Stew?</p><p>MYERS: Tell me what he said first.</p><p>STERN: He looked at me somewhat quizzically, and he said, “Well, don't you <i>have</i> to pay taxes?”</p><p>MYERS: You're absolutely right. If you look at taxes alone, and you calculate the present value of the taxes that could be saved by greater use of debt, it seems like a big number. It's hard to explain why corporations don't seem to work very hard to take advantage of the tax shelter afforded by debt. I can't really explain why companies aren't taking advantage of those savings.</p><p>I also agree with Dennis that corporations will say that they have target debt ratios. But the fact is they don't work very hard to get there. If a company is very profitable and doesn't have a need for external funds, it's probably going to work down to a low debt ratio. If it's short of funds, it's going to work up to a high debt ratio. These companies are not treating their debt ratio targets as if they were first-order goals.</p><p>SOTER: Let me offer one possible clue to this capital structure puzzle by asking a question: Is it in the personal interests of the chief executive officer and the chief financial officer to employ leverage aggressively? Are they motivated through incentives, either through stock ownership or otherwise, to have an aggressive debt policy?</p><p>I submit that very few CFOs of the largest U.S. public companies have enough equity ownership to even consider undertaking a leveraged recapitalization. If it's successful, he or she looks good for the moment. But if it's doesn't work, he'll never get another job in corporate America as a chief financial officer. So there is a great deal of personal risk for corporate management for which there may be little compensating reward. Without a significant ownership interest, who wouldn't prefer to have a single-A bond rating and sleep well at night?</p><p>STERN: Unless they were subjected to an unfriendly takeover—in which case they would lose their jobs for sure.</p><p>SOTER: Joel, you're citing an extreme example, one where there's so much unused debt capacity that a company invites a hostile bid. In my experience, there are many other companies that, although not takeover candidates, still have enough excess debt capacity that their shareholders would benefit from a leveraged recapitalization.</p><p>JOHN McCONNELL: When I started my career many years ago, I taught a course on corporate capital structure, thinking that I knew something about it. Then, for a period of a few years, I quit teaching capital structure because I concluded I knew absolutely nothing. More recently, I've started teaching a course that I call capital structure, but which really amounts to a course in corporate governance. And, so, I think I've been undergoing an evolution in thinking that is quite similar to the one Stew has just described.</p><p>And like you, Dennis, as Stew was defining optimal capital structure and describing the capital structure puzzle, I too was thinking about management incentives. Most of us, I suspect, would agree with the general proposition that there is a tax shield associated with debt financing. There would certainly be some disagreement about how valuable that tax shield is: Does it amount to a full 34 cents on the dollar of debt financing, or does that number fall to only 15 or 20 cents when you consider the taxes paid by debt holders? But, regardless of which end of this range you choose, most people in this room would probably agree that the value of such savings can be substantial. And thus most of us here would also likely agree that, for whatever reason, many public corporations are not using enough debt—not using the value-maximizing level of debt.</p><p>But let me also respond to Dennis by saying that stock ownership may not be a complete answer to the question. I'm on the board of directors of a bank with about $600 million in assets, and there is great latitude as to the minimum capital ratio that the bank can have. The owners of the bank, however, insist for some reason upon keeping their capital ratio high. In so doing, they forgo not only possible tax benefits, but also the deposit insurance “funding arbitrage.”</p><p>Like the company Joel was describing earlier, 47% of the stock of this particular bank is owned by a single family of investors. And if one thinks only in terms of their ownership incentives, it would seem that that particular ownership structure would be one that would have sufficiently strong incentives to induce managers to have a high leverage ratio. But instead, they have low leverage and considerable excess capital.</p><p>And this case, by the way, is by no means an anomaly; it is quite representative of U.S. public corporations with heavy insider ownership. The studies that have looked at the relationship between insider stock ownership and leverage ratios show that, beyond a certain point, companies with very large insider ownership tend to have lower-than-average leverage ratios. Like other academic studies in which the relationship between ownership concentration and stock value is shown to be a bell-shaped curve, these studies of leverage and insider ownership suggest that insiders can actually own too much stock in their own firm.</p><p>STERN: I was thinking along the same lines, John, when we were doing some work with the Coca-Cola Company. The CEO of Coke had a very large percentage of his own personal net worth tied up in the equity of the company. He was the third or fourth largest shareholder. And it occurred to me that the concentration of the CEO's wealth in Coke stock, and thus in an undiversified portfolio, could be a major factor in keeping the company from having a high debt ratio. That is, given his personal portfolio, it may have been rational for him to keep the financial risk of the company to a minimum.</p><p>What this suggests to me is that, in cases with very large inside owners, we may need to devise a compensation scheme that helps overcome the owners’ risk aversion so as to align their risk-reward tradeoff with that of well-diversified shareholders.</p><p>McCONNELL: What about the use of nonvoting stock? That would allow insiders to raise capital for investment opportunities without reducing their control over decision-making. For example, the CEO of Coca-Cola could have had the company issue nonvoting stock, and then concentrated his own holdings in the voting stock. Is something like that what you have in mind?</p><p>STERN: No, that wouldn't be a solution to the problem I'm thinking about. The concern I have is that because the CEO's holdings represent such a large percentage of his own personal net worth, he was much more risk averse than institutional investors with well diversified portfolios. And this risk aversion may well have caused him to use less than the amount of leverage that would have optimal from the perspective of his institutional owners.</p><p>McCONNELL: One possible solution to this problem—not for Coke, but at least in the case of small, closely held companies—would be for the CEO to sell a large fraction of his equity, thus allowing him to diversify his portfolio and allowing outsiders to have greater control over the firm. This could end up significantly increasing the value of the firm, at least in countries like the U.S. with its strong legal protections for small investors and well-functioning corporate control market.</p><p>STERN: But, to return to our subject, we really don't have an explanation why public companies have low debt ratios—or at least low enough that they end up paying millions of dollars more in taxes than seems necessary. Since we have with us a senior executive from one of America's largest public companies, why don't we turn to her? Alice, what's your explanation of all this? And how do you think about corporate financial policy at Sears?</p><p>ALICE PETERSON: Let me start by reinforcing Stewart Myers's point that capital structure is a relatively small part of a much larger, value-creating equation. At Sears, as in most companies, creating shareholder value is the main governing objective. Behind our mantra to make Sears a compelling place to shop, work, and invest, we use an EVA-type metric to track performance in the “invest” category.</p><p>In order to create value for investors, companies need a business model to guide them in generating excess returns. Business models vary widely from company to company, even within the same industry. Such a business model incorporates overall objectives, organization, strategies, and financial goals. It occurs to me that Stewart Myers's broad definition of capital structure runs through our entire business model.</p><p>We call our overall financial metric Shareholder Value Added. It is simply operating profits less the cost of all the capital it takes to create those profits. When we break down capital costs into the amount of capital times the cost of capital, we focus significantly more managerial effort on the amount of capital—and our approach is operationally focused. In other words, we want to attack the root need for the capital—and, for us, that's inventory and stores and fixturing. I often say that, of our 350,000 associates at Sears, nearly all of us have a daily impact on the amount of capital, but only a handful decide how to fund the capital needs.</p><p>So, we spend disproportionately more time talking about how to get more profit using less assets. For the few of us who do focus on the righthand side of the balance sheet, there is considerable effort aimed at achieving the lowest long-term cost of capital by managing the capital structure.</p><p>How does a company decide its optimal mix of debt and equity? At Sears we start by asking how much financial flexibility we want to pay for. That leads to a discussion in which we determine our target debt rating, which in turn translates into a target capital structure. With every strategic plan we're gauging the extent of free cash flow, the appropriate level of capital expenditures, and whether and to what extent we should be buying back stock. I can tell you we have dug seriously into the capital structure question several times over the last 5 years as we have IPO'd and spun off various business units and not only for the businesses leaving the portfolio, but for those remaining, too.</p><p>So, what are these financial flexibility considerations? They include growth prospects and whether a company is inclined to grow organically or by acquisitions. They also include the need to position the company to weather extreme economic cycles and exogenous risks. Other considerations are ownership structure and stock positioning, as well as dividend policy, and our ability to manage overall enterprise risk.</p><p>One consideration that doesn't show up on most companies’ list, but which is very important for Sears, is its ongoing debt-financing needs. Sears is different from its retail competitors by virtue of our successful credit business. Our $28 billion consumer receivables portfolio is the largest proprietary retail credit portfolio by a wide margin (the next largest is J.C. Penney at $5 billion). The $25+ billion in debt financing required to fund this profitable credit business is a key consideration in determining our target debt rating. We have targeted a ‘Single-A’ long-term debt rating to optimize our overall cost of capital. We think a “Double-A” rating is entirely too expensive, but feel that “Triple-B” greatly limits our flexibility. Importantly, impacts from a downgrade would disproportionately affect Sears versus our retail and service competition.</p><p>To give you a sense of how we incorporate this shareholder value discipline into our daily lives, the way we approach target-setting for the enterprise-wide capital structure is by solving for the capital structure that optimizes our market value. We take into consideration historical performance, economic scenarios, business and industry prospects, risk of bankruptcy, and capital constraints. Coming at it from the other side, we also focus on our individual businesses’ cost of capital. Our individual businesses include very different formats: full-line stores, Homelife furniture stores, Sears Hardware stores, our services business, and our credit card business, to name just a few. These businesses represent different levels of risk, and so warrant different hurdle rates.</p><p>We address the individual businesses’ cost of capital in two ways: First, we take a rating agency view of the business. We ask ourselves, “What are the business's prospects for cashflow, and what are the associated risks?” We also assess the business's competitive position and develop an industry outlook. Second, we approach the same business's cost of capital by looking at its competitors and other benchmarks. We ask: “What is their capital structure, and their cost of capital? And are there tax issues?” We want to know whether our financial “DNA” is a help or a hindrance to competing effectively. We look at on versus off-book capital. We do analytics, we compare managements, and we look at “the story” behind each business. Needless to say, it's important that the cost of capital and the capital structure for all our component businesses add up to the enterprise-wide picture. By pursuing this simultaneous top-down and bottom-up approach, we find we are getting at all the issues that allow us to get more debt in our capital structure for the same amount of financial flexibility.</p><p>STERN: Well, to return to my earlier question, are there many public companies that are passing up opportunities to add significant value by raising their debt ratios? Or are we missing something important here?</p><p>McCONNELL: Well, Joel, I think we've already heard the best answer we're going to get. Our incentive structures are not very effective in overcoming managers’ risk aversion; there just isn't enough reward for success to justify the personal risks to management.</p><p>STERN: But if the incentive structures are not effective, then why don't we see more unfriendly takeovers to make sure that they are aligned properly?</p><p>PETERSON: Well, let me remind you both of your earlier comments. You both told stories in which owners with a long-term commitment to an institution were reluctant to jeopardize the future of that institution by taking on too much debt, or operating with insufficient capital. There are costs—significant potential costs—to operating a business with too much leverage, or too little equity.</p><p>When I think about what gets written up about public companies—more so by fixed income analysts and rating agencies than by equity analysts—capital structure is very much talked about. It becomes the issue—and for equity as well as fixed income analysts—when a heavy debt load significantly reduces a company's flexibility. And if for no other reason than this, companies are very aware of it. I know that we focus very much on our competitors’ capital structures. We often consider what their balance sheets permit them to do in the way of competitive strikes. To listen to the academics here, we'd believe that corporations don't proactively engineer their capital structure. And to listen to Joel and Dennis, we'd believe few companies in America have enough debt. I think both notions are unfounded.</p><p>So, I must confess that this idea that public companies are systematically underleveraged is Greek to me. Within our current business model, our company is not underleveraged today. We were clearly <i>over</i>leveraged 5 years ago.</p><p>SOTER: I want to respond to this issue of financial flexibility, and I want to do so by elaborating on my earlier statement about management's reluctance to make aggressive use of leverage. There's more to my explanation than just risk aversion. And it comes down to this: Corporate managers don't like to have their strategies subjected to the scrutiny of markets. They like to be able to draw down bank lines and write a check. All things equal, they would prefer not to have to act like an LBO firm in which every deal is funded on a one-off basis.</p><p>I would take issue with Alice's argument that most public companies are not underleveraged. I do not think that a “Single-A” rating is likely to be a value-maximizing capital structure for most companies. We have looked at about 25 different industries; and, with few exceptions, our analysis suggests that the optimal, value-maximizing capital structure is below investment grade.</p><p>McCONNELL: How do you know that, though?</p><p>SOTER: Without going into details, our method involves an assessment of the trade-off between realizing the tax benefits of debt financing versus the increased probability of financial distress and its associated costs.</p><p>PETERSON: Well, that's all well and good. But how would I get $25 billion on an ongoing basis with a sub-investment-grade rating?</p><p>SOTER: You could issue subordinated debt.</p><p>PETERSON: Dennis, the entire high-yield debt market in recent years was only $40 billion. And costs can be considerably above investment-grade debt costs.</p><p>SOTER: I agree that the costs of the debt will go up. As we all know, the cost of debt is always going to go up as you use more of it. But I'm looking at debt as a substitute for higher-cost equity. And the question I'm trying to answer is this: How much debt can you issue until your debt and equity become so risky that your weighted average cost of capital begins to go up. In other words, at what level do you minimize capital costs?</p><p>What I am suggesting is that most public companies would actually reduce their weighted average cost of capital and increase their overall value by using debt to the point where their debt rating falls below investment grade—not far below investment grade, but below investment grade.</p><p>PETERSON: Yes, but that would significantly reduce the financial flexibility of the company, and potentially destroy more value than it creates. Your financing strategy might work for companies without the scope and aspirations of, say, the company I work for. But when you want to grow, either internally or by acquisition, and when you have a $25 billion financing requirement, you're going to want the financial flexibility that comes with an investment-grade rating. And when your business strategy depends on maintaining strong relationships with your suppliers and other constituencies, that sub-investment-grade rating could jeopardize your entire business model.</p><p>SOTER: I'm not sure companies need as much financial flexibility as they think they do. Let me give you an example. About a year ago, SPX Corporation, a New York Stock Exchange company (and also our client), announced a leveraged recapitalization. At the time, SPX had one issue of subordinated notes outstanding rated “Single-B.” The “corporate” credit rating assigned the company by Standard &amp; Poor's was “BB-.” As part of the recapitalization, the company borrowed about $100 million to buy back 18% of its outstanding common stock in a Dutch auction. Within about 8 weeks of the announcement of the Dutch auction, the stock price had run from $43.50 right through the tender range of $48–$56, and settled at around $70. And, now that about 12 months have passed, it's currently trading at around $78.</p><p>Now, what about this issue of financial flexibility? First of all, SPX basically funded the entire transaction by completely eliminating the modest dividend that the company had been paying on its common stock. In fact, the cash flow savings from eliminating the dividend were actually larger than the after-tax cost of servicing the additional debt.</p><p>And, to take this issue of financial flexibility one step further, let me point out that SPX is now attempting to take over a company almost four times its size. Clearly, they're not going to be able to finance that transaction with bank lines. They're going to have to finance it in the marketplace. But, given their recent track record, it seems unlikely they will have any trouble financing the deal.</p><p>And that brings me back to the point that I was trying to make earlier—namely, that most managements don't like to be subjected to the scrutiny of the marketplace. What the story of SPX makes clear is that, provided you are willing to submit to the market test, you may not need much financial flexibility. As we were all taught in business school, you can raise capital on a project-by-project basis provided the market thinks the investments are promising. And the run-up in SPX's stock price—from about $75 to $78—since the announcement of the transaction suggests that the market has already accepted the deal.</p><p>But I can assure you that before SPX decided to undertake its leveraged recap 1 year ago, management was very concerned about financial risk and flexibility. And one of our biggest challenges in this case was convincing them of the limited significance, if not complete irrelevance, of bond ratings in the process of creating value.</p><p>HANS STOLL: Well, Dennis, I'm not as convinced as you seem to be that companies can always go to the capital markets when they have profitable opportunities. There are real problems arising from the so-called information asymmetry between management and investors—a possibility that could make financial flexibility quite valuable in some circumstances. If your company is fully levered, and your earnings have turned down for reasons beyond your control, you may be forced to pass up some profitable investments. Convincing the capital markets to provide funds in such cases could be very costly.</p><p>Alice, is that one major reason why companies want financial flexibility?</p><p>PETERSON: Well, that's part of the explanation. But it goes further than the here and now. Every company is different, and some of the middle market companies that Dennis deals with might very appropriately have the perspective that he has described. At Sears, we are very conscious of having been in business for 110 years, and we're planning to be around for at least another 110 years. And when you think about what you need to do to ensure that that happens, you come to appreciate that financial conservatism allows you to live through all kinds of economic cycles and competitive changes that could affect your company.</p><p>Much of our sense of the company comes from the knowledge of its accomplishments, from our sense of being part of a team that has done big things. We started Allstate from scratch in 1931, and we started the Discover Card from scratch in the late 1980s. The treasurer of a company must understand the capital resources (and their costs) needed to carry out the strategic plan and to support the business model. And that requires a degree of financing flexibility that is not available to firms with the highly leveraged balance sheets that Dennis has described.</p><p>MYERS: I'm with Alice on this one. I don't deny that there are situations in which the medicine of debt and restructuring is very apt and is very successful. But there are other situations where you don't want the company to go on a “diet,” or not at least on a “crash diet.” And, in such cases, you certainly don't want to let your thinking be driven by a second-order concern like taxes.</p><p>The first consideration should always be the investment opportunities, the business opportunities. The second consideration is the financial structure of the business. The third concern—and it's a distant third in my view—is the percentage mix of debt and equity on the balance sheet.</p><p>When you do get to the issue of the percentages on the balance sheet, taxes are only one of four or five things we know are potentially important. For this reason, I think it's sort of back-asswards to start off with taxes and say that's the primary concern, even though we can agree that it is one important element.</p><p>My second observation, Alice, if I were to put your speech in academic lingo…</p><p>PETERSON: By all means.</p><p>MYERS: …would go something like this: Economic theory is making a big mistake in treating all the employees of the corporation as <i>temporary</i> workers. As I suggested earlier, to succeed a corporation requires a <i>coinvestment</i> of financial capital from the outside and human capital that is built up inside the business. You need the human capital to make the business work in the long run. And it's not necessarily inefficient for people who have most of their human capital tied up in the business to be conservative in protecting it. Where human capital is fungible and people move all around—say, in the case of swaps traders—companies can afford to be much more aggressive in taking financial risks. And the employees won't care. But, in cases where there's lots of human capital really locked up in an organization—cases, for example, where somebody spends his or her whole career at a company—it's understandable that they would want to protect that investment.</p><p>STERN: Well, Stew, I'd like to make a suggestion to you. I think that what you're saying is almost certainly true— especially given the existing distribution between fixed and variable pay that exists in most public companies. If you take a look at people in middle management and below, their variable- pay component is typically a very modest amount. But, when you put them on an EVA incentive system— one where there are no caps on their awards and there is a bonus bank system to ensure that their payments are based on sustained improvements in performance—their behavior changes … almost overnight.</p><p>In some cases, they become in favor of a more aggressive capital structure because that reduces their cost of capital and increases their EVA. In addition to the case of SPX, which Dennis just mentioned, other companies such as Equifax and Briggs and Stratton have done leveraged recapitalizations <i>after</i> first going on an EVA program. I would also suggest that, after going on EVA, companies in so-called mature industries often begin acting as if their industries were not as mature as management seemed to think they were. That is, companies whose rates of return were well below their cost of capital for a long time suddenly became superior performers.</p><p>MYERS: That's great, Joel. But, once again, you are making my point. What you're saying is that by going in and changing financial structure—which includes the system of incentives inside the business—you can get the people who contribute human capital to the organization to take additional risks because they're given a reward.</p><p>STERN: Yes, that's right.</p><p>MYERS: My point, though, is that there's an investment in human capital that, from an efficiency point of view, you will want to protect much of the time. Now, you don't want to protect it when it's ceased to be productive—and that happens in many large bureaucratic organizations. But, by and large, it is economically efficient that when you ask people to make an investment of human capital in your firm, you do not then do things—like raising the leverage ratio too high—that would needlessly put that investment at risk.</p><p>STERN: Forgive me, Stew, but I still have a problem with this. Let's assume we do all of the things in the sequence that you propose, and that the issues of capital structure and taxes are the last things on the list. And let's assume that we get the 20 incentives right, and that we carry them down deep into the company.</p><p>Now, having done those things, we once again come to this issue about whether debt is not significantly less expensive than equity. And, as you suggest, Stew, in many cases we may come to the conclusion that the company cannot support much leverage, whether because the debt would endanger the strategic plan or put the human capital investment at undue risk. My argument is this: Even under these circumstances, I still suspect that there are a good many companies where lots of talented, energetic people would be more than willing to put their human capital at risk for the right payoffs.</p><p>After all, this is essentially what KKR does when they go into a company. They say to operating management, “If you're willing to take some additional risk, and subject yourself to very challenging performance standards, we can make it very rewarding for you.” As we now know from the research, the same operating managers have shown themselves capable of doubling their companies’ operating cash flow in a period of 3 years or less when you change the incentive system. And this is basically what we're trying to accomplish with EVA, but without the risk to human capital imposed by high leverage.</p><p>In a conference we held a number of weeks ago for our EVA clients, Michael Jensen and I got into an intellectual fist-fight on a favorite subject of his. Both Mike and my partner, Bennett Stewart, are fond of talking about the effectiveness of high debt ratios in discouraging managers from doing foolish things with shareholder resources. The basic idea is that debt exerts a discipline on management that can be valuable in companies with too much cash and few profitable investment opportunities.</p><p>As we have argued in a series of articles, our EVA-based incentive compensation is also designed to deal with this corporate “free cash flow” problem. And, because our system can be taken well down into the corporate structure—that is, into the individual business units and below—I would argue that EVA might even be <i>more cost-effective</i> than debt financing in discouraging the corporate waste of capital.</p><p>So, to the extent that we have succeeded in designing and implementing a measurement and reward system that motivates managers to make the most efficient use of capital—and I recognize that this is the critical assumption—then why would it be necessary to resort to debt to accomplish the same goal? That is, assuming debt creates a valuable discipline for management in certain cases, why wouldn't the “localized” incentives provided by an EVA plan be expected to do an even better job? After all, as you have pointed out, Stew, too much debt could kill all corporate investment, good as well as bad. An EVA system encourages managers to fight for just those projects that promise to earn their cost of capital.</p><p>SOTER: Let me take a crack at that one, Joel. At the risk of being asked to leave the partnership, let me tell you the following story. In 1992 we were helping Equifax, the nation's largest provider of consumer financial information, to adopt EVA incentives. At the same time, we were asked to advise the company on what turned out to be a rather aggressive leveraged recapitalization.</p><p>As the chief financial officer told me, “Look, anything can happen. There is no contractual obligation on the part of the board to continue to have EVA incentives here in this company. But the contractual obligations associated with debt are real, and the consequences of failing to meet them are far more weighty to the company and to the stockholders than canceling an EVA plan.”</p><p>As this statement suggests, there is an important difference between the contractual nature of the company having to service debt versus the obligations under EVA incentives. And the company's willingness to bind itself in this way sends a strong signal to investors. It demonstrates to the marketplace that agency problems are being addressed inside the company, and it can be very effective in eliminating at least the perception, if not the reality, of corporate reinvestment risk.</p><p>STERN: I have two responses, Dennis. First of all, I accept your resignation. The second is, if you take a look at recent announcements of public companies of just their intent to go on an EVA plan, the market response has been noticeably positive. In some cases, we have seen share values change by as much as 25% within a week's time.</p><p>Last week I took part in a conference at Stanford law school, and on the panel sitting next to me was George Roberts of KKR. I went through a rather lengthy discussion of the content, the design structure, and the outcomes of EVA plans. And when George was asked to comment on it, he said: “That sounds like a better idea than the one we've got. Why would you want to use leverage unless you really have to? The discipline of debt is a very blunt instrument to accomplish what you are saying you can do unit by unit throughout the organization.”</p><p>You see, we can even design the incentive system to encourage teamwork among the different business units while preserving rewards for individual performance. We could say to an operating head, “Seventy percent of the annual reward will be based on the performance of your unit, and 30% will be based on the performance of all the other units.” This way, if good ideas are developed in one part of the organization that could help other parts, they will quickly move from unit to unit.</p><p>So, what I am really suggesting, then, is that EVA can provide a solution to this human capital problem that Stew has mentioned as a reason for avoiding high leverage. We can take managers and employees with large investments in human capital and make them rationally less risk averse by making them partners in creating sustainable improvements in value. This way, managers and the existing shareholders can end up the big winner, and not somebody like KKR that comes in from the outside.</p><p>HANS STOLL: Up to this point, we have discussed capital structure policy as if it were designed primarily to reduce taxes and agency costs while also holding down expected costs of financial distress. But we have said very little about information costs. As Joel mentioned earlier, in 1984 Stew Myers presented a theory of capital structure called the “pecking order” theory, which relies heavily on information costs to explain corporate behavior. And I was wondering, Stew, if you could share with us your current thinking on the role of information costs in corporate financing decisions?</p><p>MYERS: The pecking order starts out with the prediction that companies will issue debt instead of equity most of the time because of information problems. If the information problems are important, then you're going to see the debt ratio vary across time according to companies’ needs for funds. Companies with a balance of payments deficit with respect to the outside world will be increasing their debt ratios while those that have a surplus will be paying down debt and reducing leverage.</p><p>I like to put it just that baldly, not because I think it's the complete answer, but because I want to get away from academics’ “nesting instinct.” The tendency of academics is to begin by observing that there are four or five things that could affect capital structure. Therefore, they say, let's find ten proxies for these four or five factors and run a regression. But, because each proxy has some connection to two or three of the underlying variables, you end up not being able to interpret the regression. Or you interpret it the way you like to interpret it, but not against an alternative theory.</p><p>Lakshmi Shyam-Sunder and I have a paper coming out shortly in the <i>Journal of Financial Economics</i> where we show that, for a sample of relatively mature and established public companies, the pecking order works great. We get R<sup>2</sup>s up around 0.80 in a time series. We also show that if it were true that companies were really trying to move to a target capital structure based on a tradeoff of taxes and cost of financial distress, you could reject the pecking order. Therefore, our test has power. At the same time, we show that if the companies were actually following the pecking order, it would look like they were seeking out some debt-equity target.</p><p>So if you want to start with one description of how large, established companies behave, why not start with the one that has a very high R<sup>2</sup> and for which we can show statistical power?</p><p>SOTER: Is the pecking order theory consistent with value-maximizing behavior?</p><p>MYERS: Yes.</p><p>SOTER: But as I understand it, one of the premises of the pecking order theory is that dividends are sticky. And, for that reason alone, I have trouble seeing how that policy can be consistent with value-maximizing behavior.</p><p>MYERS: Are we talking about dividend policy now?</p><p>SOTER: I don't see how you can separate the two. In my experience, they are interdependent decisions— or at least we encourage management to view them that way.</p><p>MYERS: Why do dividends matter aside from taxes?</p><p>SOTER: If they don't matter aside from taxes, then my first thought would be: Why don't we cut back on dividends before we even seek or consider seeking external financing? This is what we did in the case of SPX that I just mentioned.</p><p>MYERS: I don't have a complete answer to that, and I think that's one of the biggest unsolved problems in academic finance. We don't have a good theory of dividend policy. We have no theory of dividend policy that goes back to any kind of fundamentals. And so I admit the pecking order takes the stickiness of dividends as a fact. It doesn't try to explain it. I don't think anybody can explain it.</p><p>SOTER: Let me give you one other example of how a dividend cut can be used to facilitate an increase in leverage. A year ago, we advised IPALCO Enterprises, the parent company of Indianapolis Power and Light, in becoming the first utility ever to undertake a leveraged recapitalization. IPALCO started off with a “AA” bond rating and a 42% debt-to-capital ratio. The company borrowed more than $400 million and used the proceeds to buy back its common stock. In the process, the company's debt-to-capital ratio went from 42% to 69%. But the increase in debt was financed in effect with an almost 33% cut in the dividend, from $1.48 per share to $1 per share. In fact, the annual savings from the dividend cut of about $41 million exceeded the increase in the <i>after-tax</i> interest expense by about $25 million. That is, IPALCO's after-tax cash flows actually increased by $25 million even as the leverage ratio increased from 42% to 69%. And both of the rating agencies the day after the announcement reaffirmed the company's “AA-”/ “AA” bond ratings, which further suggests that leverage ratios, at least in traditional book accounting terms, just don't matter.</p><p>IPALCO's operating cash flows have also increased since that time, and the stock market seems to have liked what's happened. In 1997, the company's stock provided a total shareholder return of 58.5%, putting it among the top three electric utilities last year.</p><p>McCONNELL: I want to just stop and take stock for a moment, and to make sure that, if there is a debate here, we all understand what the debate is about. If I understand Stew's observation, it is that capital structure may matter but it doesn't seem to matter very much, at least from a manager's perspective. Managers don't spend a lot of time worrying about it. Is that a reasonable characterization?</p><p>MYERS: That's right, at least for large, established companies within a wide middle range of debt ratios.</p><p>McCONNELL: What Dennis is arguing, if I understand it, is that capital structure definitely matters, and he has given us several case illustrations. One problem with the use of cases, of course, is that you hear only about the ones that work—which is not to say, Dennis, that all of yours didn't work; I'm sure they did.</p><p>Ron Masulis has done a classic study of the stock market's response to exchange offers. And that study shows very clearly—and for a large sample of companies, not just one or two interesting cases—that when companies announce that they are issuing new debt to retire stock, their stock price increases. And the study also shows the converse: when stock is issued to retire debt, stock prices decline. Now, the question is: Why does that happen? How should we interpret the market's reaction?</p><p>Some people have argued that there is a signaling effect at work here. That is, most companies tend to do leverage-increasing recaps only when they expect earnings—or, more precisely, operating cash flows—to increase in the future. To the extent investors understand this, they raise stock prices in anticipation of higher future operating earnings. This may in fact explain the market's reaction to the leveraged recaps that Dennis described.</p><p>And the opposite story is likely to explain the market's negative response to leverage-reducing recaps. If you look closely at Ron's data, what you find is that 90% of the companies that do leverage-reducing recaps are actually in some degree of financial distress. So, what we may be picking up from the announcement of an equity increasing swap is a signal that we're in real trouble, guys.</p><p>My question, Dennis, is this: Are these leveraged recaps valuable in and of themselves—say, for their tax savings and for some beneficial incentive effect? Or are they simply functioning as signals of management's confidence in future earnings?</p><p>SOTER: You are certainly right to warn that I could be dealing with a biased sample, and I realize that anecdotal evidence does not constitute proof. But let me respond to your question by telling you a little more about IPALCO.</p><p>McCONNELL: Go ahead. I've been at Purdue for 20 years now, and it's close to my heart.</p><p>SOTER: Since it's a utility, Indianapolis Power and Light probably goes well beyond what most unregulated companies provide in terms of disclosure. In fact, for all practical purposes, they share with the investment community a 5-year plan. Utility analysts are famous for forecasting earnings per share within one penny each quarter because management is spoon-feeding them all the information. So, I don't think there was much room for signaling associated with their new financial strategy.</p><p>On the other hand, I think you can argue that there was a lot signaling in the cases of SPX and Briggs and Stratton. In the case of Briggs and Stratton, the stock price went from $42.75 to $48 during the week of the announcement. And, as I mentioned earlier, SPX's stock price started at $43.50, ran right through the price range for the Dutch auction (of $48 to $56) and settled at close to $70.</p><p>But let me also make the following observation: If signaling is the explanation, there are almost certain to be a number of other, real effects behind the signal. For example, both SPX and Briggs and Stratton had been EVA companies for some time before making announcing their recaps. And, since investors had already achieved a degree of confidence in these two management teams, this signal of future improvements coming on top of recent past achievements could be especially convincing.</p><p>And, to show you what I mean by real improvements, let me now go back to the case of IPALCO. About 7 months after IPALCO completed its recap, I had lunch with the chief financial officer, John Brehm. In describing some of the events that had happened internally since the recap, he said, “It's been extraordinary. Through 8 months of 1997, we have been right on budget with respect to reported earnings per share, but we are $40 million ahead on cash flow since the recap.” He said that the recap had really focused people on generating cash flow. They are running the business differently, even though it has not yet been reflected in reported earnings. (And I must confess that even I was a little surprised; I didn't think anything would have focused the attention of utility managers.)</p><p>So, I think there are several things at work here. Yes, there is some signaling. But you have to ask: What's being signaled—or why is management more confident about future operating cash flow? Well, a big part of the answer is that managers now have stronger incentives to produce operating cash flow, and debt helps increase cash flow by sheltering corporate taxes. And, on top of all this, the substitution of stock buybacks for cash dividends has the effect of increasing after-tax rates of return to stockholders by distributing cash in a more tax-efficient way.</p><p>MYERS: There is a signal in the utility business, by the way. If I were a utility investor, my worry would be that the utility would take all this cash flow that's coming into its pockets and burn it somewhere. And the leveraged recap acts as a signal, in your case, that they are not going to do that.</p><p>PETERSON: I agree that, just as there's nothing like the prospect of the guillotine to concentrate the mind, leverage can have wonderful effects in certain circumstances. But I also believe that we can create incentives inside companies that produce the LBO mindset and the behavior that goes with it without piling on leverage. In other words, I think we have to think about how we get the <i>behavior</i> we want, and I think there are a lot of ways to do it.</p><p>The foolproof way, as Joel has pointed out, is to lever up and require managers to own lots of stock. There is nothing like having that debt service staring them in the face every day. So I agree with that point.</p><p>STERN: Alice, what is the feeling about dividend policy at Sears? Could Sears cut its dividend by a third, or even to zero, and borrow a lot more and thereby increase its value?</p><p>PETERSON: We haven't increased our dividend for more than 10 years. In fact, we have effectively cut it by virtue of the spinoffs that we've done. When we spun off Dean Witter Discover, we reduced our total dividend payments; and when we spun off Allstate, we reduced it again.</p><p>But that, of course, is not the same thing as cutting it to zero. And that is an action with very serious consequences. Sears is one of the most actively traded stocks in the United States. And, when you have a stock that is as actively traded and as broadly held as ours, if you decide to eliminate your dividend you must be prepared to deal with a very dramatic shift in your stockholder base. I'm not saying that it couldn't be done. But it would take a great deal of preparation, and it would have to be communicated very, very carefully to the investment community. And it's not something that we plan to do any time in the near future.</p><p>In other words, positioning your company for the stock market is an extremely critical part of the whole circle of activities and decisions that turn on how much flexibility you want as a company. As in the case of leverage, you need to set your dividend policy in such a way that it supports your business model, your ability to carry out your strategic plan.</p><p>SOTER: I'm not as convinced that dividend policy needs to be established with a concern for the needs of the current stockholder base. In 1994, we advised the board of FPL Group, the parent company of Florida Power &amp; Light, in its decision to commit what in the minds of many was financial <i>hara-kiri</i>. FPL was the first profitable utility, to my knowledge, to voluntarily cut its dividend. The dividend was cut nearly one-third, from a quarterly payout of 62 cents to 42 cents per share; and in its place the board authorized management to repurchase up to 10 million shares of common stock in the open market. If ever there was a test of the so-called “clientele effect,” this was it. I recall a director at the board meeting that preceded the final decision to make the cut asking the question, “What's the likely impact on our stock price?” I responded— conservatively I hoped—that the market price would drop up to 25%, and would not fully recover for as long as 2 or 3 months.</p><p>Sure enough, the stock dropped 15% on the day of the announcement. But within 3 weeks the price had fully recovered. What's more, the dividend cut itself caused 15 brokerage houses to put a “buy” on the stock. And the stock attracted lots of new institutional investors, even as it lost many others. During the 12 months following the dividend action, FPL's stockholders realized a total return of 23.8%, more than double the S&amp;P Electric Index. So, there was a significant change in the investor clientele, in the composition of the stockholder base.</p><p>And this also tends to happens with leveraged recapitalizations. When we advised Equifax in 1992 in a very aggressive leveraged recapitalization, there was also a significant change in the investor make-up of the company. These two experiences lead me to believe that one stockholder clientele is indeed as good as another.</p><p>MYERS: Your case is interesting, Dennis, but I'm not sure it has much to say 24 to a company like Sears. Suppose Sears cuts its dividend to zero, but without taking a leveraged recap. All it's going to do is to tell shareholders, “Don't worry, we'll use the money we would have used for the dividend to buy back shares over time?”</p><p>SOTER: That's exactly what Florida Power &amp; Light did. They did not do a leveraged recapitalization, but they did announce that they would be using part of the cash savings to buy back their shares in the open market. So, it's a nice, almost laboratory-controlled, example of where we cut cash dividends and substituted a policy of open market repurchases.</p><p>PETERSON: Our payout ratio is in the 20%–25% range, which is a little bit lower than that of our peer group. Another consideration—although not necessarily the most important factor— is that our shareholders are often our customers. These so-called “retail” investors tend to want dividends.</p><p>MYERS: I tend to agree with Alice's position. And I would think even the most zealous market-efficiency types should not have trouble with it. The “perfect markets” view of finance would say that, aside from temporary signaling effects, it doesn't really matter very much whether you pay dividends or buy back shares. And so, if somebody says, “Why pay dividends?,” the standard answer is, “Why not? There are clienteles out there that want dividends, and consumers are sovereign.”</p><p>So, if somebody was going to pay dividends in this world, why wouldn't Sears be likely to satisfy that demand? I don't see anything wrong with that argument. The only possible objection I can see would be taxes again. But I don't think anybody has proved that high dividend yields lead to a higher cost of capital because of taxes.</p><p>STERN: Let me ask you a question, then, Stew. If what you're saying is true, then why don't some companies have two classes of shares, one that would pay a high dividend and one would pay a low dividend? This way, the shareholders could buy whichever mix of those shares they wanted so as to write their own dividend policy. If dividends were so terribly important that there was an optimal dividend policy for investors, then you would expect that there would be more than one class of share available to investors so that they could manufacture their own dividend policy.</p><p>MYERS: You didn't hear what I said. I said that dividend policy is not important, aside from the short-run signals that are given. It doesn't matter whether cash is paid out via dividends or share repurchases. (The total amount of cash paid out does matter, of course.)</p><p>But there are people out there who, for whatever reasons, want some dividends. Somebody has got to give it to them. It doesn't cost Sears very much to give it to them. They are natural provider of that service. Why not? If somebody else wants to repurchase shares, good for them. I just don't care.</p><p>SOTER: What if I were to suggest that here, too, we can have our cake and eat it, too. Before joining Stern Stewart, as Joel mentioned, I worked for Citizens Utilities. The founder of Citizens Utilities was Richard Rosenthal, and some of you may be aware of this case because, back in the ’70s, John Long at the University of Rochester wrote a paper about the company's highly unusual dividend policy.</p><p>For many years, Citizens had two classes of common stock, one that paid a cash dividend, and one that paid a common stock dividend of an equivalent amount. Richard had gotten this grandfathered originally in 1956 and, through successive tax acts, that waiver had been extended. But, in 1990 as the Bush tax act was coming up, we saw that we were going to lose the exemption. So we had two options: We could eliminate the stock dividend and change it to a cash dividend, or we could convert the cash dividend class to a stock dividend, and so eliminate cash dividends altogether.</p><p>We chose the second course. We obviously weren't going to start paying cash dividends on the stock dividend class. To soften the blow for the stockholders who wanted cash, we created the “stock dividend sale plan.” We said, in effect, “We're going to give all stockholders stock dividends, but those stockholders who want to receive cash income can make an election that effectively enables them to convert those dividends into cash.” You see, the company couldn't just buy back their shares because the IRS would have viewed that as a sham, and the cash would have been taxed as ordinary income. So, instead we simply made arrangements with an investment bank and our transfer agent to aggregate those shares that stockholders elected to cash in to maintain their income stream—and those shares were sold, with no commission costs (except the bid-ask spreads), to provide stockholders with the same cash income. Our shareholders were taxed on that income at a capital gains tax rate, and only on the difference between the sales price and their basis.</p><p>So, we achieved a significant reduction in taxes for the stockholders who elected to continue to receive income.</p><p>MYERS: It's good financial engineering. But, again, I think it's a second order effect, just as Miller &amp; Modigliani taught us.</p><p>STERN: Well, I think that's a good note on which to bring this to a close, and I want to thank you all very much for your participation. We expected this to be an exciting program, and I think we got our fair rate of return.</p>","PeriodicalId":0,"journal":{"name":"","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":0.0,"publicationDate":"2023-04-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/jacf.12539","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jacf.12539","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

April 2, 1998         Nashville, Tennessee

JOEL STERN: Good afternoon. I'm Joel Stern, managing partner of Stern Stewart & Co., and, on behalf of our hosts here at Vanderbilt's Owen Graduate School of Management, I want to welcome you all to this discussion of corporate capital structure. Before getting into our subject matter, let me take a moment to thank Hans Stoll for organizing this conference on “Financial Markets and the Corporation.” I also want to take this opportunity to salute Professor Martin Weingartner—in whose honor this conference is being held—at the conclusion of a long and productive career. Marty's contributions to the field of corporate finance are many and considerable; and, though he may be stepping down from his formal position, we expect to continue to hear from him for many more years.

The subject of today's meeting is corporate capital structure: Does capital structure matter? And, if so, how and why does it matter? Although these questions have been seriously debated in the academic finance profession for almost 40 years, we seem to be no closer to a definitive answer than we were in 1958, when Merton Miller and Franco Modigliani published their article presenting the first of their two famous “irrelevance” propositions.

Following the M&M propositions, academic researchers in the 1960s and 1970s turned their attention to various market “imperfections” that might make firm value depend on capital structure and dividend policy. The main suspects were (1) a tax code that encourages debt by making interest payments, but not dividends, tax deductible, and (2) expected costs of financial distress, including corporate underinvestment, that can become important as you increase the amount of debt in the capital structure. Toward the end of the 1970s, there was also discussion of “signaling” effects—for example, the tendency for the stock market to respond negatively to announcements of new stock issues.

A defining moment in the academic capital structure debate came in 1984, when Professor Stewart Myers devoted his Presidential address to the American Finance Association to something he called “The Capital Structure Puzzle.” The puzzle was this: Most academic discussions of capital structure were based on the assumption that companies make financing decisions that are guided by a target capital structure—a proportion of debt to equity that management aims to achieve, if not at all times, then at least as a long-run average. But the empirical evidence suggested otherwise. Rather than adhering to targets, Professor Myers observed, most large U.S. public companies behaved as if they were following a financial “pecking order.” They were funding investment with retained earnings rather than external financing if possible; and if external funding was necessary, they issued debt first and equity only as a last resort.

Since then, the capital structure debate has raged on. Harvard professor Michael Jensen entered it in the mid-1980s, pointing to the success of LBOs and citing the beneficial effect of debt financing on management's tendency to overinvest in industries with excess capital and capacity. And, as if to oblige Professor Jensen, the market continued to supply large numbers of LBOs and other highly leveraged transactions throughout the rest of the decade. Then, in the early 1990s, we saw an almost complete halt to leveraged deals. But today, of course, leverage is back. A new wave of LBOs has shattered most of the old records, and junk-bond issuance is at all-time highs.

So, if capital structure is irrelevant, then what's going on here? And do the successes of the LBO movement have anything to say to the managements of our largest public companies? Such effects seemed to confirm the existence of large “information costs” that might also influence corporate financing choices in predictable ways.

With us here to discuss these issues, and to help us shed some light on this capital structure puzzle, is a small, but distinguished group of academics and practitioners. And let me introduce them briefly:

STEWART MYERS, whose name I have already mentioned several times, is the Billard Professor of Corporate Finance at one of my favorite schools, the MIT Sloan School of Management. Stew has done research over the years in issues dealing with capital structure, valuation, and regulation. He has also been an adviser to a large number of corporations and financial institutions. And let me mention that, for us at Stern Stewart, the name Stewart Myers has a special significance. As most people here are well aware, Stew is the co-author, with Dick Brealey of the London Business School, of Principles of Corporate Finance, the leading textbook in corporate finance. Every person who gets hired at Stern Stewart is required to have read that volume by the time he or she walks in the door.

ALICE PETERSON is Vice President and Treasurer of Sears, Roebuck and Co. As we all know, Sears has made dramatic improvements in operating performance and achieved large increases in shareholder value over the past few years. Alice joined Sears in 1989 as Director of Corporate Finance, 4 years before being made Vice President and Treasurer in 1993. Prior to coming to Sears, she held corporate finance and treasury positions at Kraft and at Pepsico. She earned her MBA here at Vanderbilt in 1981, and she serves on the boards of two New York Stock Exchange companies.

JOHN McCONNELL is the Emanuel T. Weiler Professor of Finance at Purdue University. John has made extensive contributions to the field of corporate finance, especially in the analysis of innovative securities. I still remember an article on income bonds that John contributed to our old Chase Financial Quarterly, the original predecessor of our Journal of Applied Corporate Finance. And, in an issue of the JACF about 5 or 6 years ago, John coauthored (with Eduardo Schwartz) a fascinating account of the origins of LYONS, the very successful puttable, convertible securities pioneered by Merrill Lynch. Given John's ability to tell stories, none of us is surprised that he manages to win teaching awards at Purdue year after year.

Last is DENNIS SOTER, my colleague and fellow partner at Stern Stewart. After graduating from the University of Rochester's Simon School of Business in 1972, Dennis joined me at the Chase Manhattan Bank. Then, in 1979, we parted ways. Dennis became Vice President in charge of corporate development at Brown Foreman, where he helped transform the firm from the maker of Jack Daniels (and other mild intoxicants) into a diversified consumer goods firm. Then he went to Ernst & Whinney, where he was the national practice director of M&A. Next, he joined Citizens Utilities and helped them to become something of an unregulated company as well as a regulated company.

Several years ago, we were very fortunate in persuading each other that we should be together again. And Dennis now runs our corporate finance advisory activity and also oversees implementations of EVA in middle market-sized companies. In the past 2 years, as I'm sure Dennis will tell us, he served as financial adviser in three highly successful leveraged recapitalizations. Each of these three deals involved borrowing substantial amounts of new debt to buy back shares—and two involved major changes major changes in dividend policy as well.

STERN: So, now that we know who the panelists are, let me turn the floor over to Professor Stewart Myers. You might not remember this, Stew, but in 1983 you were kind enough to publish an article in our Midland Corporate Finance Journal entitled “The Search for Optimal Capital Structure.”

And it was not only a marvelous piece, but it was the lead article in the very first issue—Volume 1 Number 1—of that journal. Then, about 10 years passed, and you wrote a second article for us that was called “Still Searching for Optimal Capital Structure.”

And that was also a wonderful piece—one that I use (along with the first one) in the courses I teach at Columbia and Carnegie Mellon.

My question for you is: What is your current thinking on the capital structure debate? And what are you going to call your next article?

STEWART MYERS: The next one is going to be called “Stop Searching for Optimal Capital Structure.” Let me take a minute or two to tell you why. Optimal capital structure is obviously something I've been concerned and struggling with ever since I arrived at the doctoral program at Stanford. I've been frustrated over the years by our inability to come up with any simple answer. But I am lately coming to a different view. Maybe it will start the discussion off.

When we talk about optimal capital structure, we are thinking of the percentages of different securities on the right-hand side of the balance sheet. We tend to think in terms of the mix of debt and equity, at least to start, and then go on to consider other securities as well. We look at preferred stock, for example, and at hybrid securities like convertible debt.

At what level do we understand how these financing choices affect firm value? At a tactical level, I think we understand it very well. For example, if you ask either academics or practitioners to analyze a financial innovation like the tax-deductible preferreds that John McConnell just finished telling us about, we do that pretty well. We understand how those things work, why they're designed the way they are, and what you need to do to get them sold. So, at this tactical level, we can be fairly satisfied with our understanding of capital structure.

Where we tend to fall down in terms of neat or simple theories is in understanding the role of capital structure at what I will call the “strategic” level—that is, when you're trying to explain the debt ratios of companies on average or over long periods of time. We do have some useful insights about capital structure, and we know what ought to matter. But it's very difficult to put these insights together into a simple theory that predicts what managers are going to do—or tells us what they should be doing.

Why aren't we cracking the problem? I think we are starting in the wrong place. We shouldn't be starting with the percentages of different kinds of financing on the right-hand side of the balance sheet. We should not be starting with capital structure, but with financial structure. By financial structure I mean the allocation of ownership and control, which includes the division of the risk and returns of the enterprise—and particularly of its intangible assets—between the insiders in the firm and the outsiders.

What's really going on in the public corporation is a coinvestment by insiders, who bring their human capital to it, and by financial investors. These two groups share the intangible assets of the organization. And, in order to make that shared investment work, you've got to figure out issues of ownership and control, incentives, risk-sharing, and so forth. You've got to start by making sure you get all of those things right. That's what I call financial structure.

Financial structure is not the same thing as a financing mix. Let me offer a simple example. Take a high-tech venture capital startup and compare it to Microsoft. Even though their debt ratios are likely to be identical—that is, zero—I think we'd all agree that they are not the same thing from a financial point of view. The same comparison could be made between a publicly held management consulting company and the usual private management consulting firm. Though their balance sheets might look exactly the same, I would say they're very different. In particular, I would predict that if you take a small consulting company public, it's almost sure to crater. The assets go home every night, and it's going to be very difficult to have the right incentives to keep key people in the company while at the same time satisfying outside investors.

So, if Stern Stewart ever goes public, Joel, I'm going to wait 6 months and then sell you short.

STERN: I actually had a dream that somebody was going to do that to us—but I had no idea, Stew, that it was going to be you! I must confess that such thoughts have passed through my mind. But, if we were to take such a course (which we have no plan to do), we would design the new firm so as to protect outside investors not so much from the possibility that the assets go home at night, but that they might move to the island of Maui, permanently.

Incidentally, this is not an unreasonable issue because Booz-Allen did that once. You may not be aware of it, but in the 1970s Booz-Allen went public at a price in the mid-teens. The shares went as high as about $20 and then dropped to about $2—and they stayed between $2 and $6 for quite a while. The reason I know about it is that I served on the board of directors of a company with the Vice Chairman of Booz-Allen. And every time the possibility of going public was raised for this privately held company, he would say: “It's the wrong thing to do.” And he would drag us through this horrible experience once more.

But Booz-Allen made a fundamental mistake—one that, if corrected, might have changed the outcome. They didn't differentiate between outsider shares and insider shares. If the insiders own shares that only gradually convert to outsider shares, the insiders aren't going anywhere. They could also have issued stock options to the employees with values tied to the value of the insider shares. With insider shares and options, it would take a long time for people to take out the wealth that they were building up in the firm.

How do you feel about that idea, Stew?

MYERS: I think you're just making my point. First of all, I don't think that it makes sense to take a small consulting company public. But if you did, you'd have to pay attention to financial structure—to issues like who owns what, who gets to make what decisions, what are the goals and performance measures, and how are people rewarded for meeting them.

STERN: So, your concept of financial structure is essentially the same as what some people are calling corporate governance or organizational structure—it's the assignment of decision rights, monitoring, performance measures, incentives, and all of that?

MYERS: Financial structure is my shorthand—just two words—for all of that sort of stuff. My point is that these issues of financial structure are the first-order concerns of most corporations. Management has to get them right.

Now, that's not the same as saying that managers have to do all these things consciously. Sometimes they get it right because they do what other corporations have done and survived.

Once an industrial corporation goes public, it's ordinarily a mid-cap firm with a financial structure well in place. In a sense, it has solved 80% of its problem—that is, as long as it keeps operating efficiently. Having solved that problem, I don't think most corporations worry a great deal about their debt-equity ratio. Obviously, they worry if it gets too high and they worry if it gets too low. But there's a big middle range where it doesn't seem to matter very much. I think that's why we're having a hard time pinning down exactly what the debt-equity ratio is or should be. It's a “second order” thing compared to the choice of financial structure.

STERN: Well, people have pointed out that the tax-deductibility of interest expense makes debt a way of adding considerable value. And because of the value added by those tax shields, one could argue that aggressive use of debt may turn out to be the best defense against an unfriendly takeover. Doesn't that argument seem to imply that capital structure could at least become a first-order concern?

MYERS: By raising the issue of hostile takeovers, I think you are mixing up the investment decision with the financing decision. I would like to keep them separate, at least as a starting point. Most takeover targets become targets not because they don't have enough debt, but because of bad investment decisions and poor operating performance. The primary cause of the wave of LBOs in the 1980s was not corporate failure to exploit the tax advantage of debt. Most of the LBOs—and I'm oversimplifying a little—were “diet deals.” They involved taking over mature companies with too much cash and too few investment opportunities and putting them on a diet. So, although there were tax savings, the transactions themselves were not tax-driven.

DENNIS SOTER: Most of the companies that we have worked with over the years do spend a lot of time thinking about capital structure. Now, it's true that they typically do not think about it the way academics do—that is, in terms of a market debt-to-equity ratio. Most of them define their objectives in terms of bond ratings or book leverage. But they do have loosely defined financial strategies and some idea of what constitutes an appropriate mix of debt and equity in their capital structure.

I'd like to ask Professor Myers a question: You used the term “optimal capital structure.” Would you define that for us?

MYERS: In its simplest terms, optimal capital structure is the optimal percentage of debt on the balance sheet.

SOTER: But optimal from what standpoint?

MYERS: Maximizing the market value of the company. I'm not saying that's the wrong question, or an irrelevant or an uninteresting question. It's a very interesting question. But I think by focusing too narrowly on that, you miss these other things which I put under the rubric of financial structure—things which I tend to think are more important to corporate managers, and so more powerful in explaining the corporate behavior we see.

STERN: I think you're right, at least in the sense that I regularly see behavior that doesn't appear to me to be value-maximizing. For example, in a roundtable discussion we ran a few years ago, one of the participants was an owner of a publicly traded company where he and his family owned about 37% of the equity. And I asked him why his debt ratio was so low. I said to him, “You're volunteering to pay an awful lot in taxes that you could avoid. Why don't you raise your debt ratio to the point where most of your pre-tax operating income is tax-sheltered?”

You see, the amount of taxes he was paying was quite sizeable; it was some $12–$15 million a year that was literally going out the door that could have been saved just by changing the capital structure. Why do companies do that, Stew?

MYERS: Tell me what he said first.

STERN: He looked at me somewhat quizzically, and he said, “Well, don't you have to pay taxes?”

MYERS: You're absolutely right. If you look at taxes alone, and you calculate the present value of the taxes that could be saved by greater use of debt, it seems like a big number. It's hard to explain why corporations don't seem to work very hard to take advantage of the tax shelter afforded by debt. I can't really explain why companies aren't taking advantage of those savings.

I also agree with Dennis that corporations will say that they have target debt ratios. But the fact is they don't work very hard to get there. If a company is very profitable and doesn't have a need for external funds, it's probably going to work down to a low debt ratio. If it's short of funds, it's going to work up to a high debt ratio. These companies are not treating their debt ratio targets as if they were first-order goals.

SOTER: Let me offer one possible clue to this capital structure puzzle by asking a question: Is it in the personal interests of the chief executive officer and the chief financial officer to employ leverage aggressively? Are they motivated through incentives, either through stock ownership or otherwise, to have an aggressive debt policy?

I submit that very few CFOs of the largest U.S. public companies have enough equity ownership to even consider undertaking a leveraged recapitalization. If it's successful, he or she looks good for the moment. But if it's doesn't work, he'll never get another job in corporate America as a chief financial officer. So there is a great deal of personal risk for corporate management for which there may be little compensating reward. Without a significant ownership interest, who wouldn't prefer to have a single-A bond rating and sleep well at night?

STERN: Unless they were subjected to an unfriendly takeover—in which case they would lose their jobs for sure.

SOTER: Joel, you're citing an extreme example, one where there's so much unused debt capacity that a company invites a hostile bid. In my experience, there are many other companies that, although not takeover candidates, still have enough excess debt capacity that their shareholders would benefit from a leveraged recapitalization.

JOHN McCONNELL: When I started my career many years ago, I taught a course on corporate capital structure, thinking that I knew something about it. Then, for a period of a few years, I quit teaching capital structure because I concluded I knew absolutely nothing. More recently, I've started teaching a course that I call capital structure, but which really amounts to a course in corporate governance. And, so, I think I've been undergoing an evolution in thinking that is quite similar to the one Stew has just described.

And like you, Dennis, as Stew was defining optimal capital structure and describing the capital structure puzzle, I too was thinking about management incentives. Most of us, I suspect, would agree with the general proposition that there is a tax shield associated with debt financing. There would certainly be some disagreement about how valuable that tax shield is: Does it amount to a full 34 cents on the dollar of debt financing, or does that number fall to only 15 or 20 cents when you consider the taxes paid by debt holders? But, regardless of which end of this range you choose, most people in this room would probably agree that the value of such savings can be substantial. And thus most of us here would also likely agree that, for whatever reason, many public corporations are not using enough debt—not using the value-maximizing level of debt.

But let me also respond to Dennis by saying that stock ownership may not be a complete answer to the question. I'm on the board of directors of a bank with about $600 million in assets, and there is great latitude as to the minimum capital ratio that the bank can have. The owners of the bank, however, insist for some reason upon keeping their capital ratio high. In so doing, they forgo not only possible tax benefits, but also the deposit insurance “funding arbitrage.”

Like the company Joel was describing earlier, 47% of the stock of this particular bank is owned by a single family of investors. And if one thinks only in terms of their ownership incentives, it would seem that that particular ownership structure would be one that would have sufficiently strong incentives to induce managers to have a high leverage ratio. But instead, they have low leverage and considerable excess capital.

And this case, by the way, is by no means an anomaly; it is quite representative of U.S. public corporations with heavy insider ownership. The studies that have looked at the relationship between insider stock ownership and leverage ratios show that, beyond a certain point, companies with very large insider ownership tend to have lower-than-average leverage ratios. Like other academic studies in which the relationship between ownership concentration and stock value is shown to be a bell-shaped curve, these studies of leverage and insider ownership suggest that insiders can actually own too much stock in their own firm.

STERN: I was thinking along the same lines, John, when we were doing some work with the Coca-Cola Company. The CEO of Coke had a very large percentage of his own personal net worth tied up in the equity of the company. He was the third or fourth largest shareholder. And it occurred to me that the concentration of the CEO's wealth in Coke stock, and thus in an undiversified portfolio, could be a major factor in keeping the company from having a high debt ratio. That is, given his personal portfolio, it may have been rational for him to keep the financial risk of the company to a minimum.

What this suggests to me is that, in cases with very large inside owners, we may need to devise a compensation scheme that helps overcome the owners’ risk aversion so as to align their risk-reward tradeoff with that of well-diversified shareholders.

McCONNELL: What about the use of nonvoting stock? That would allow insiders to raise capital for investment opportunities without reducing their control over decision-making. For example, the CEO of Coca-Cola could have had the company issue nonvoting stock, and then concentrated his own holdings in the voting stock. Is something like that what you have in mind?

STERN: No, that wouldn't be a solution to the problem I'm thinking about. The concern I have is that because the CEO's holdings represent such a large percentage of his own personal net worth, he was much more risk averse than institutional investors with well diversified portfolios. And this risk aversion may well have caused him to use less than the amount of leverage that would have optimal from the perspective of his institutional owners.

McCONNELL: One possible solution to this problem—not for Coke, but at least in the case of small, closely held companies—would be for the CEO to sell a large fraction of his equity, thus allowing him to diversify his portfolio and allowing outsiders to have greater control over the firm. This could end up significantly increasing the value of the firm, at least in countries like the U.S. with its strong legal protections for small investors and well-functioning corporate control market.

STERN: But, to return to our subject, we really don't have an explanation why public companies have low debt ratios—or at least low enough that they end up paying millions of dollars more in taxes than seems necessary. Since we have with us a senior executive from one of America's largest public companies, why don't we turn to her? Alice, what's your explanation of all this? And how do you think about corporate financial policy at Sears?

ALICE PETERSON: Let me start by reinforcing Stewart Myers's point that capital structure is a relatively small part of a much larger, value-creating equation. At Sears, as in most companies, creating shareholder value is the main governing objective. Behind our mantra to make Sears a compelling place to shop, work, and invest, we use an EVA-type metric to track performance in the “invest” category.

In order to create value for investors, companies need a business model to guide them in generating excess returns. Business models vary widely from company to company, even within the same industry. Such a business model incorporates overall objectives, organization, strategies, and financial goals. It occurs to me that Stewart Myers's broad definition of capital structure runs through our entire business model.

We call our overall financial metric Shareholder Value Added. It is simply operating profits less the cost of all the capital it takes to create those profits. When we break down capital costs into the amount of capital times the cost of capital, we focus significantly more managerial effort on the amount of capital—and our approach is operationally focused. In other words, we want to attack the root need for the capital—and, for us, that's inventory and stores and fixturing. I often say that, of our 350,000 associates at Sears, nearly all of us have a daily impact on the amount of capital, but only a handful decide how to fund the capital needs.

So, we spend disproportionately more time talking about how to get more profit using less assets. For the few of us who do focus on the righthand side of the balance sheet, there is considerable effort aimed at achieving the lowest long-term cost of capital by managing the capital structure.

How does a company decide its optimal mix of debt and equity? At Sears we start by asking how much financial flexibility we want to pay for. That leads to a discussion in which we determine our target debt rating, which in turn translates into a target capital structure. With every strategic plan we're gauging the extent of free cash flow, the appropriate level of capital expenditures, and whether and to what extent we should be buying back stock. I can tell you we have dug seriously into the capital structure question several times over the last 5 years as we have IPO'd and spun off various business units and not only for the businesses leaving the portfolio, but for those remaining, too.

So, what are these financial flexibility considerations? They include growth prospects and whether a company is inclined to grow organically or by acquisitions. They also include the need to position the company to weather extreme economic cycles and exogenous risks. Other considerations are ownership structure and stock positioning, as well as dividend policy, and our ability to manage overall enterprise risk.

One consideration that doesn't show up on most companies’ list, but which is very important for Sears, is its ongoing debt-financing needs. Sears is different from its retail competitors by virtue of our successful credit business. Our $28 billion consumer receivables portfolio is the largest proprietary retail credit portfolio by a wide margin (the next largest is J.C. Penney at $5 billion). The $25+ billion in debt financing required to fund this profitable credit business is a key consideration in determining our target debt rating. We have targeted a ‘Single-A’ long-term debt rating to optimize our overall cost of capital. We think a “Double-A” rating is entirely too expensive, but feel that “Triple-B” greatly limits our flexibility. Importantly, impacts from a downgrade would disproportionately affect Sears versus our retail and service competition.

To give you a sense of how we incorporate this shareholder value discipline into our daily lives, the way we approach target-setting for the enterprise-wide capital structure is by solving for the capital structure that optimizes our market value. We take into consideration historical performance, economic scenarios, business and industry prospects, risk of bankruptcy, and capital constraints. Coming at it from the other side, we also focus on our individual businesses’ cost of capital. Our individual businesses include very different formats: full-line stores, Homelife furniture stores, Sears Hardware stores, our services business, and our credit card business, to name just a few. These businesses represent different levels of risk, and so warrant different hurdle rates.

We address the individual businesses’ cost of capital in two ways: First, we take a rating agency view of the business. We ask ourselves, “What are the business's prospects for cashflow, and what are the associated risks?” We also assess the business's competitive position and develop an industry outlook. Second, we approach the same business's cost of capital by looking at its competitors and other benchmarks. We ask: “What is their capital structure, and their cost of capital? And are there tax issues?” We want to know whether our financial “DNA” is a help or a hindrance to competing effectively. We look at on versus off-book capital. We do analytics, we compare managements, and we look at “the story” behind each business. Needless to say, it's important that the cost of capital and the capital structure for all our component businesses add up to the enterprise-wide picture. By pursuing this simultaneous top-down and bottom-up approach, we find we are getting at all the issues that allow us to get more debt in our capital structure for the same amount of financial flexibility.

STERN: Well, to return to my earlier question, are there many public companies that are passing up opportunities to add significant value by raising their debt ratios? Or are we missing something important here?

McCONNELL: Well, Joel, I think we've already heard the best answer we're going to get. Our incentive structures are not very effective in overcoming managers’ risk aversion; there just isn't enough reward for success to justify the personal risks to management.

STERN: But if the incentive structures are not effective, then why don't we see more unfriendly takeovers to make sure that they are aligned properly?

PETERSON: Well, let me remind you both of your earlier comments. You both told stories in which owners with a long-term commitment to an institution were reluctant to jeopardize the future of that institution by taking on too much debt, or operating with insufficient capital. There are costs—significant potential costs—to operating a business with too much leverage, or too little equity.

When I think about what gets written up about public companies—more so by fixed income analysts and rating agencies than by equity analysts—capital structure is very much talked about. It becomes the issue—and for equity as well as fixed income analysts—when a heavy debt load significantly reduces a company's flexibility. And if for no other reason than this, companies are very aware of it. I know that we focus very much on our competitors’ capital structures. We often consider what their balance sheets permit them to do in the way of competitive strikes. To listen to the academics here, we'd believe that corporations don't proactively engineer their capital structure. And to listen to Joel and Dennis, we'd believe few companies in America have enough debt. I think both notions are unfounded.

So, I must confess that this idea that public companies are systematically underleveraged is Greek to me. Within our current business model, our company is not underleveraged today. We were clearly overleveraged 5 years ago.

SOTER: I want to respond to this issue of financial flexibility, and I want to do so by elaborating on my earlier statement about management's reluctance to make aggressive use of leverage. There's more to my explanation than just risk aversion. And it comes down to this: Corporate managers don't like to have their strategies subjected to the scrutiny of markets. They like to be able to draw down bank lines and write a check. All things equal, they would prefer not to have to act like an LBO firm in which every deal is funded on a one-off basis.

I would take issue with Alice's argument that most public companies are not underleveraged. I do not think that a “Single-A” rating is likely to be a value-maximizing capital structure for most companies. We have looked at about 25 different industries; and, with few exceptions, our analysis suggests that the optimal, value-maximizing capital structure is below investment grade.

McCONNELL: How do you know that, though?

SOTER: Without going into details, our method involves an assessment of the trade-off between realizing the tax benefits of debt financing versus the increased probability of financial distress and its associated costs.

PETERSON: Well, that's all well and good. But how would I get $25 billion on an ongoing basis with a sub-investment-grade rating?

SOTER: You could issue subordinated debt.

PETERSON: Dennis, the entire high-yield debt market in recent years was only $40 billion. And costs can be considerably above investment-grade debt costs.

SOTER: I agree that the costs of the debt will go up. As we all know, the cost of debt is always going to go up as you use more of it. But I'm looking at debt as a substitute for higher-cost equity. And the question I'm trying to answer is this: How much debt can you issue until your debt and equity become so risky that your weighted average cost of capital begins to go up. In other words, at what level do you minimize capital costs?

What I am suggesting is that most public companies would actually reduce their weighted average cost of capital and increase their overall value by using debt to the point where their debt rating falls below investment grade—not far below investment grade, but below investment grade.

PETERSON: Yes, but that would significantly reduce the financial flexibility of the company, and potentially destroy more value than it creates. Your financing strategy might work for companies without the scope and aspirations of, say, the company I work for. But when you want to grow, either internally or by acquisition, and when you have a $25 billion financing requirement, you're going to want the financial flexibility that comes with an investment-grade rating. And when your business strategy depends on maintaining strong relationships with your suppliers and other constituencies, that sub-investment-grade rating could jeopardize your entire business model.

SOTER: I'm not sure companies need as much financial flexibility as they think they do. Let me give you an example. About a year ago, SPX Corporation, a New York Stock Exchange company (and also our client), announced a leveraged recapitalization. At the time, SPX had one issue of subordinated notes outstanding rated “Single-B.” The “corporate” credit rating assigned the company by Standard & Poor's was “BB-.” As part of the recapitalization, the company borrowed about $100 million to buy back 18% of its outstanding common stock in a Dutch auction. Within about 8 weeks of the announcement of the Dutch auction, the stock price had run from $43.50 right through the tender range of $48–$56, and settled at around $70. And, now that about 12 months have passed, it's currently trading at around $78.

Now, what about this issue of financial flexibility? First of all, SPX basically funded the entire transaction by completely eliminating the modest dividend that the company had been paying on its common stock. In fact, the cash flow savings from eliminating the dividend were actually larger than the after-tax cost of servicing the additional debt.

And, to take this issue of financial flexibility one step further, let me point out that SPX is now attempting to take over a company almost four times its size. Clearly, they're not going to be able to finance that transaction with bank lines. They're going to have to finance it in the marketplace. But, given their recent track record, it seems unlikely they will have any trouble financing the deal.

And that brings me back to the point that I was trying to make earlier—namely, that most managements don't like to be subjected to the scrutiny of the marketplace. What the story of SPX makes clear is that, provided you are willing to submit to the market test, you may not need much financial flexibility. As we were all taught in business school, you can raise capital on a project-by-project basis provided the market thinks the investments are promising. And the run-up in SPX's stock price—from about $75 to $78—since the announcement of the transaction suggests that the market has already accepted the deal.

But I can assure you that before SPX decided to undertake its leveraged recap 1 year ago, management was very concerned about financial risk and flexibility. And one of our biggest challenges in this case was convincing them of the limited significance, if not complete irrelevance, of bond ratings in the process of creating value.

HANS STOLL: Well, Dennis, I'm not as convinced as you seem to be that companies can always go to the capital markets when they have profitable opportunities. There are real problems arising from the so-called information asymmetry between management and investors—a possibility that could make financial flexibility quite valuable in some circumstances. If your company is fully levered, and your earnings have turned down for reasons beyond your control, you may be forced to pass up some profitable investments. Convincing the capital markets to provide funds in such cases could be very costly.

Alice, is that one major reason why companies want financial flexibility?

PETERSON: Well, that's part of the explanation. But it goes further than the here and now. Every company is different, and some of the middle market companies that Dennis deals with might very appropriately have the perspective that he has described. At Sears, we are very conscious of having been in business for 110 years, and we're planning to be around for at least another 110 years. And when you think about what you need to do to ensure that that happens, you come to appreciate that financial conservatism allows you to live through all kinds of economic cycles and competitive changes that could affect your company.

Much of our sense of the company comes from the knowledge of its accomplishments, from our sense of being part of a team that has done big things. We started Allstate from scratch in 1931, and we started the Discover Card from scratch in the late 1980s. The treasurer of a company must understand the capital resources (and their costs) needed to carry out the strategic plan and to support the business model. And that requires a degree of financing flexibility that is not available to firms with the highly leveraged balance sheets that Dennis has described.

MYERS: I'm with Alice on this one. I don't deny that there are situations in which the medicine of debt and restructuring is very apt and is very successful. But there are other situations where you don't want the company to go on a “diet,” or not at least on a “crash diet.” And, in such cases, you certainly don't want to let your thinking be driven by a second-order concern like taxes.

The first consideration should always be the investment opportunities, the business opportunities. The second consideration is the financial structure of the business. The third concern—and it's a distant third in my view—is the percentage mix of debt and equity on the balance sheet.

When you do get to the issue of the percentages on the balance sheet, taxes are only one of four or five things we know are potentially important. For this reason, I think it's sort of back-asswards to start off with taxes and say that's the primary concern, even though we can agree that it is one important element.

My second observation, Alice, if I were to put your speech in academic lingo…

PETERSON: By all means.

MYERS: …would go something like this: Economic theory is making a big mistake in treating all the employees of the corporation as temporary workers. As I suggested earlier, to succeed a corporation requires a coinvestment of financial capital from the outside and human capital that is built up inside the business. You need the human capital to make the business work in the long run. And it's not necessarily inefficient for people who have most of their human capital tied up in the business to be conservative in protecting it. Where human capital is fungible and people move all around—say, in the case of swaps traders—companies can afford to be much more aggressive in taking financial risks. And the employees won't care. But, in cases where there's lots of human capital really locked up in an organization—cases, for example, where somebody spends his or her whole career at a company—it's understandable that they would want to protect that investment.

STERN: Well, Stew, I'd like to make a suggestion to you. I think that what you're saying is almost certainly true— especially given the existing distribution between fixed and variable pay that exists in most public companies. If you take a look at people in middle management and below, their variable- pay component is typically a very modest amount. But, when you put them on an EVA incentive system— one where there are no caps on their awards and there is a bonus bank system to ensure that their payments are based on sustained improvements in performance—their behavior changes … almost overnight.

In some cases, they become in favor of a more aggressive capital structure because that reduces their cost of capital and increases their EVA. In addition to the case of SPX, which Dennis just mentioned, other companies such as Equifax and Briggs and Stratton have done leveraged recapitalizations after first going on an EVA program. I would also suggest that, after going on EVA, companies in so-called mature industries often begin acting as if their industries were not as mature as management seemed to think they were. That is, companies whose rates of return were well below their cost of capital for a long time suddenly became superior performers.

MYERS: That's great, Joel. But, once again, you are making my point. What you're saying is that by going in and changing financial structure—which includes the system of incentives inside the business—you can get the people who contribute human capital to the organization to take additional risks because they're given a reward.

STERN: Yes, that's right.

MYERS: My point, though, is that there's an investment in human capital that, from an efficiency point of view, you will want to protect much of the time. Now, you don't want to protect it when it's ceased to be productive—and that happens in many large bureaucratic organizations. But, by and large, it is economically efficient that when you ask people to make an investment of human capital in your firm, you do not then do things—like raising the leverage ratio too high—that would needlessly put that investment at risk.

STERN: Forgive me, Stew, but I still have a problem with this. Let's assume we do all of the things in the sequence that you propose, and that the issues of capital structure and taxes are the last things on the list. And let's assume that we get the 20 incentives right, and that we carry them down deep into the company.

Now, having done those things, we once again come to this issue about whether debt is not significantly less expensive than equity. And, as you suggest, Stew, in many cases we may come to the conclusion that the company cannot support much leverage, whether because the debt would endanger the strategic plan or put the human capital investment at undue risk. My argument is this: Even under these circumstances, I still suspect that there are a good many companies where lots of talented, energetic people would be more than willing to put their human capital at risk for the right payoffs.

After all, this is essentially what KKR does when they go into a company. They say to operating management, “If you're willing to take some additional risk, and subject yourself to very challenging performance standards, we can make it very rewarding for you.” As we now know from the research, the same operating managers have shown themselves capable of doubling their companies’ operating cash flow in a period of 3 years or less when you change the incentive system. And this is basically what we're trying to accomplish with EVA, but without the risk to human capital imposed by high leverage.

In a conference we held a number of weeks ago for our EVA clients, Michael Jensen and I got into an intellectual fist-fight on a favorite subject of his. Both Mike and my partner, Bennett Stewart, are fond of talking about the effectiveness of high debt ratios in discouraging managers from doing foolish things with shareholder resources. The basic idea is that debt exerts a discipline on management that can be valuable in companies with too much cash and few profitable investment opportunities.

As we have argued in a series of articles, our EVA-based incentive compensation is also designed to deal with this corporate “free cash flow” problem. And, because our system can be taken well down into the corporate structure—that is, into the individual business units and below—I would argue that EVA might even be more cost-effective than debt financing in discouraging the corporate waste of capital.

So, to the extent that we have succeeded in designing and implementing a measurement and reward system that motivates managers to make the most efficient use of capital—and I recognize that this is the critical assumption—then why would it be necessary to resort to debt to accomplish the same goal? That is, assuming debt creates a valuable discipline for management in certain cases, why wouldn't the “localized” incentives provided by an EVA plan be expected to do an even better job? After all, as you have pointed out, Stew, too much debt could kill all corporate investment, good as well as bad. An EVA system encourages managers to fight for just those projects that promise to earn their cost of capital.

SOTER: Let me take a crack at that one, Joel. At the risk of being asked to leave the partnership, let me tell you the following story. In 1992 we were helping Equifax, the nation's largest provider of consumer financial information, to adopt EVA incentives. At the same time, we were asked to advise the company on what turned out to be a rather aggressive leveraged recapitalization.

As the chief financial officer told me, “Look, anything can happen. There is no contractual obligation on the part of the board to continue to have EVA incentives here in this company. But the contractual obligations associated with debt are real, and the consequences of failing to meet them are far more weighty to the company and to the stockholders than canceling an EVA plan.”

As this statement suggests, there is an important difference between the contractual nature of the company having to service debt versus the obligations under EVA incentives. And the company's willingness to bind itself in this way sends a strong signal to investors. It demonstrates to the marketplace that agency problems are being addressed inside the company, and it can be very effective in eliminating at least the perception, if not the reality, of corporate reinvestment risk.

STERN: I have two responses, Dennis. First of all, I accept your resignation. The second is, if you take a look at recent announcements of public companies of just their intent to go on an EVA plan, the market response has been noticeably positive. In some cases, we have seen share values change by as much as 25% within a week's time.

Last week I took part in a conference at Stanford law school, and on the panel sitting next to me was George Roberts of KKR. I went through a rather lengthy discussion of the content, the design structure, and the outcomes of EVA plans. And when George was asked to comment on it, he said: “That sounds like a better idea than the one we've got. Why would you want to use leverage unless you really have to? The discipline of debt is a very blunt instrument to accomplish what you are saying you can do unit by unit throughout the organization.”

You see, we can even design the incentive system to encourage teamwork among the different business units while preserving rewards for individual performance. We could say to an operating head, “Seventy percent of the annual reward will be based on the performance of your unit, and 30% will be based on the performance of all the other units.” This way, if good ideas are developed in one part of the organization that could help other parts, they will quickly move from unit to unit.

So, what I am really suggesting, then, is that EVA can provide a solution to this human capital problem that Stew has mentioned as a reason for avoiding high leverage. We can take managers and employees with large investments in human capital and make them rationally less risk averse by making them partners in creating sustainable improvements in value. This way, managers and the existing shareholders can end up the big winner, and not somebody like KKR that comes in from the outside.

HANS STOLL: Up to this point, we have discussed capital structure policy as if it were designed primarily to reduce taxes and agency costs while also holding down expected costs of financial distress. But we have said very little about information costs. As Joel mentioned earlier, in 1984 Stew Myers presented a theory of capital structure called the “pecking order” theory, which relies heavily on information costs to explain corporate behavior. And I was wondering, Stew, if you could share with us your current thinking on the role of information costs in corporate financing decisions?

MYERS: The pecking order starts out with the prediction that companies will issue debt instead of equity most of the time because of information problems. If the information problems are important, then you're going to see the debt ratio vary across time according to companies’ needs for funds. Companies with a balance of payments deficit with respect to the outside world will be increasing their debt ratios while those that have a surplus will be paying down debt and reducing leverage.

I like to put it just that baldly, not because I think it's the complete answer, but because I want to get away from academics’ “nesting instinct.” The tendency of academics is to begin by observing that there are four or five things that could affect capital structure. Therefore, they say, let's find ten proxies for these four or five factors and run a regression. But, because each proxy has some connection to two or three of the underlying variables, you end up not being able to interpret the regression. Or you interpret it the way you like to interpret it, but not against an alternative theory.

Lakshmi Shyam-Sunder and I have a paper coming out shortly in the Journal of Financial Economics where we show that, for a sample of relatively mature and established public companies, the pecking order works great. We get R2s up around 0.80 in a time series. We also show that if it were true that companies were really trying to move to a target capital structure based on a tradeoff of taxes and cost of financial distress, you could reject the pecking order. Therefore, our test has power. At the same time, we show that if the companies were actually following the pecking order, it would look like they were seeking out some debt-equity target.

So if you want to start with one description of how large, established companies behave, why not start with the one that has a very high R2 and for which we can show statistical power?

SOTER: Is the pecking order theory consistent with value-maximizing behavior?

MYERS: Yes.

SOTER: But as I understand it, one of the premises of the pecking order theory is that dividends are sticky. And, for that reason alone, I have trouble seeing how that policy can be consistent with value-maximizing behavior.

MYERS: Are we talking about dividend policy now?

SOTER: I don't see how you can separate the two. In my experience, they are interdependent decisions— or at least we encourage management to view them that way.

MYERS: Why do dividends matter aside from taxes?

SOTER: If they don't matter aside from taxes, then my first thought would be: Why don't we cut back on dividends before we even seek or consider seeking external financing? This is what we did in the case of SPX that I just mentioned.

MYERS: I don't have a complete answer to that, and I think that's one of the biggest unsolved problems in academic finance. We don't have a good theory of dividend policy. We have no theory of dividend policy that goes back to any kind of fundamentals. And so I admit the pecking order takes the stickiness of dividends as a fact. It doesn't try to explain it. I don't think anybody can explain it.

SOTER: Let me give you one other example of how a dividend cut can be used to facilitate an increase in leverage. A year ago, we advised IPALCO Enterprises, the parent company of Indianapolis Power and Light, in becoming the first utility ever to undertake a leveraged recapitalization. IPALCO started off with a “AA” bond rating and a 42% debt-to-capital ratio. The company borrowed more than $400 million and used the proceeds to buy back its common stock. In the process, the company's debt-to-capital ratio went from 42% to 69%. But the increase in debt was financed in effect with an almost 33% cut in the dividend, from $1.48 per share to $1 per share. In fact, the annual savings from the dividend cut of about $41 million exceeded the increase in the after-tax interest expense by about $25 million. That is, IPALCO's after-tax cash flows actually increased by $25 million even as the leverage ratio increased from 42% to 69%. And both of the rating agencies the day after the announcement reaffirmed the company's “AA-”/ “AA” bond ratings, which further suggests that leverage ratios, at least in traditional book accounting terms, just don't matter.

IPALCO's operating cash flows have also increased since that time, and the stock market seems to have liked what's happened. In 1997, the company's stock provided a total shareholder return of 58.5%, putting it among the top three electric utilities last year.

McCONNELL: I want to just stop and take stock for a moment, and to make sure that, if there is a debate here, we all understand what the debate is about. If I understand Stew's observation, it is that capital structure may matter but it doesn't seem to matter very much, at least from a manager's perspective. Managers don't spend a lot of time worrying about it. Is that a reasonable characterization?

MYERS: That's right, at least for large, established companies within a wide middle range of debt ratios.

McCONNELL: What Dennis is arguing, if I understand it, is that capital structure definitely matters, and he has given us several case illustrations. One problem with the use of cases, of course, is that you hear only about the ones that work—which is not to say, Dennis, that all of yours didn't work; I'm sure they did.

Ron Masulis has done a classic study of the stock market's response to exchange offers. And that study shows very clearly—and for a large sample of companies, not just one or two interesting cases—that when companies announce that they are issuing new debt to retire stock, their stock price increases. And the study also shows the converse: when stock is issued to retire debt, stock prices decline. Now, the question is: Why does that happen? How should we interpret the market's reaction?

Some people have argued that there is a signaling effect at work here. That is, most companies tend to do leverage-increasing recaps only when they expect earnings—or, more precisely, operating cash flows—to increase in the future. To the extent investors understand this, they raise stock prices in anticipation of higher future operating earnings. This may in fact explain the market's reaction to the leveraged recaps that Dennis described.

And the opposite story is likely to explain the market's negative response to leverage-reducing recaps. If you look closely at Ron's data, what you find is that 90% of the companies that do leverage-reducing recaps are actually in some degree of financial distress. So, what we may be picking up from the announcement of an equity increasing swap is a signal that we're in real trouble, guys.

My question, Dennis, is this: Are these leveraged recaps valuable in and of themselves—say, for their tax savings and for some beneficial incentive effect? Or are they simply functioning as signals of management's confidence in future earnings?

SOTER: You are certainly right to warn that I could be dealing with a biased sample, and I realize that anecdotal evidence does not constitute proof. But let me respond to your question by telling you a little more about IPALCO.

McCONNELL: Go ahead. I've been at Purdue for 20 years now, and it's close to my heart.

SOTER: Since it's a utility, Indianapolis Power and Light probably goes well beyond what most unregulated companies provide in terms of disclosure. In fact, for all practical purposes, they share with the investment community a 5-year plan. Utility analysts are famous for forecasting earnings per share within one penny each quarter because management is spoon-feeding them all the information. So, I don't think there was much room for signaling associated with their new financial strategy.

On the other hand, I think you can argue that there was a lot signaling in the cases of SPX and Briggs and Stratton. In the case of Briggs and Stratton, the stock price went from $42.75 to $48 during the week of the announcement. And, as I mentioned earlier, SPX's stock price started at $43.50, ran right through the price range for the Dutch auction (of $48 to $56) and settled at close to $70.

But let me also make the following observation: If signaling is the explanation, there are almost certain to be a number of other, real effects behind the signal. For example, both SPX and Briggs and Stratton had been EVA companies for some time before making announcing their recaps. And, since investors had already achieved a degree of confidence in these two management teams, this signal of future improvements coming on top of recent past achievements could be especially convincing.

And, to show you what I mean by real improvements, let me now go back to the case of IPALCO. About 7 months after IPALCO completed its recap, I had lunch with the chief financial officer, John Brehm. In describing some of the events that had happened internally since the recap, he said, “It's been extraordinary. Through 8 months of 1997, we have been right on budget with respect to reported earnings per share, but we are $40 million ahead on cash flow since the recap.” He said that the recap had really focused people on generating cash flow. They are running the business differently, even though it has not yet been reflected in reported earnings. (And I must confess that even I was a little surprised; I didn't think anything would have focused the attention of utility managers.)

So, I think there are several things at work here. Yes, there is some signaling. But you have to ask: What's being signaled—or why is management more confident about future operating cash flow? Well, a big part of the answer is that managers now have stronger incentives to produce operating cash flow, and debt helps increase cash flow by sheltering corporate taxes. And, on top of all this, the substitution of stock buybacks for cash dividends has the effect of increasing after-tax rates of return to stockholders by distributing cash in a more tax-efficient way.

MYERS: There is a signal in the utility business, by the way. If I were a utility investor, my worry would be that the utility would take all this cash flow that's coming into its pockets and burn it somewhere. And the leveraged recap acts as a signal, in your case, that they are not going to do that.

PETERSON: I agree that, just as there's nothing like the prospect of the guillotine to concentrate the mind, leverage can have wonderful effects in certain circumstances. But I also believe that we can create incentives inside companies that produce the LBO mindset and the behavior that goes with it without piling on leverage. In other words, I think we have to think about how we get the behavior we want, and I think there are a lot of ways to do it.

The foolproof way, as Joel has pointed out, is to lever up and require managers to own lots of stock. There is nothing like having that debt service staring them in the face every day. So I agree with that point.

STERN: Alice, what is the feeling about dividend policy at Sears? Could Sears cut its dividend by a third, or even to zero, and borrow a lot more and thereby increase its value?

PETERSON: We haven't increased our dividend for more than 10 years. In fact, we have effectively cut it by virtue of the spinoffs that we've done. When we spun off Dean Witter Discover, we reduced our total dividend payments; and when we spun off Allstate, we reduced it again.

But that, of course, is not the same thing as cutting it to zero. And that is an action with very serious consequences. Sears is one of the most actively traded stocks in the United States. And, when you have a stock that is as actively traded and as broadly held as ours, if you decide to eliminate your dividend you must be prepared to deal with a very dramatic shift in your stockholder base. I'm not saying that it couldn't be done. But it would take a great deal of preparation, and it would have to be communicated very, very carefully to the investment community. And it's not something that we plan to do any time in the near future.

In other words, positioning your company for the stock market is an extremely critical part of the whole circle of activities and decisions that turn on how much flexibility you want as a company. As in the case of leverage, you need to set your dividend policy in such a way that it supports your business model, your ability to carry out your strategic plan.

SOTER: I'm not as convinced that dividend policy needs to be established with a concern for the needs of the current stockholder base. In 1994, we advised the board of FPL Group, the parent company of Florida Power & Light, in its decision to commit what in the minds of many was financial hara-kiri. FPL was the first profitable utility, to my knowledge, to voluntarily cut its dividend. The dividend was cut nearly one-third, from a quarterly payout of 62 cents to 42 cents per share; and in its place the board authorized management to repurchase up to 10 million shares of common stock in the open market. If ever there was a test of the so-called “clientele effect,” this was it. I recall a director at the board meeting that preceded the final decision to make the cut asking the question, “What's the likely impact on our stock price?” I responded— conservatively I hoped—that the market price would drop up to 25%, and would not fully recover for as long as 2 or 3 months.

Sure enough, the stock dropped 15% on the day of the announcement. But within 3 weeks the price had fully recovered. What's more, the dividend cut itself caused 15 brokerage houses to put a “buy” on the stock. And the stock attracted lots of new institutional investors, even as it lost many others. During the 12 months following the dividend action, FPL's stockholders realized a total return of 23.8%, more than double the S&P Electric Index. So, there was a significant change in the investor clientele, in the composition of the stockholder base.

And this also tends to happens with leveraged recapitalizations. When we advised Equifax in 1992 in a very aggressive leveraged recapitalization, there was also a significant change in the investor make-up of the company. These two experiences lead me to believe that one stockholder clientele is indeed as good as another.

MYERS: Your case is interesting, Dennis, but I'm not sure it has much to say 24 to a company like Sears. Suppose Sears cuts its dividend to zero, but without taking a leveraged recap. All it's going to do is to tell shareholders, “Don't worry, we'll use the money we would have used for the dividend to buy back shares over time?”

SOTER: That's exactly what Florida Power & Light did. They did not do a leveraged recapitalization, but they did announce that they would be using part of the cash savings to buy back their shares in the open market. So, it's a nice, almost laboratory-controlled, example of where we cut cash dividends and substituted a policy of open market repurchases.

PETERSON: Our payout ratio is in the 20%–25% range, which is a little bit lower than that of our peer group. Another consideration—although not necessarily the most important factor— is that our shareholders are often our customers. These so-called “retail” investors tend to want dividends.

MYERS: I tend to agree with Alice's position. And I would think even the most zealous market-efficiency types should not have trouble with it. The “perfect markets” view of finance would say that, aside from temporary signaling effects, it doesn't really matter very much whether you pay dividends or buy back shares. And so, if somebody says, “Why pay dividends?,” the standard answer is, “Why not? There are clienteles out there that want dividends, and consumers are sovereign.”

So, if somebody was going to pay dividends in this world, why wouldn't Sears be likely to satisfy that demand? I don't see anything wrong with that argument. The only possible objection I can see would be taxes again. But I don't think anybody has proved that high dividend yields lead to a higher cost of capital because of taxes.

STERN: Let me ask you a question, then, Stew. If what you're saying is true, then why don't some companies have two classes of shares, one that would pay a high dividend and one would pay a low dividend? This way, the shareholders could buy whichever mix of those shares they wanted so as to write their own dividend policy. If dividends were so terribly important that there was an optimal dividend policy for investors, then you would expect that there would be more than one class of share available to investors so that they could manufacture their own dividend policy.

MYERS: You didn't hear what I said. I said that dividend policy is not important, aside from the short-run signals that are given. It doesn't matter whether cash is paid out via dividends or share repurchases. (The total amount of cash paid out does matter, of course.)

But there are people out there who, for whatever reasons, want some dividends. Somebody has got to give it to them. It doesn't cost Sears very much to give it to them. They are natural provider of that service. Why not? If somebody else wants to repurchase shares, good for them. I just don't care.

SOTER: What if I were to suggest that here, too, we can have our cake and eat it, too. Before joining Stern Stewart, as Joel mentioned, I worked for Citizens Utilities. The founder of Citizens Utilities was Richard Rosenthal, and some of you may be aware of this case because, back in the ’70s, John Long at the University of Rochester wrote a paper about the company's highly unusual dividend policy.

For many years, Citizens had two classes of common stock, one that paid a cash dividend, and one that paid a common stock dividend of an equivalent amount. Richard had gotten this grandfathered originally in 1956 and, through successive tax acts, that waiver had been extended. But, in 1990 as the Bush tax act was coming up, we saw that we were going to lose the exemption. So we had two options: We could eliminate the stock dividend and change it to a cash dividend, or we could convert the cash dividend class to a stock dividend, and so eliminate cash dividends altogether.

We chose the second course. We obviously weren't going to start paying cash dividends on the stock dividend class. To soften the blow for the stockholders who wanted cash, we created the “stock dividend sale plan.” We said, in effect, “We're going to give all stockholders stock dividends, but those stockholders who want to receive cash income can make an election that effectively enables them to convert those dividends into cash.” You see, the company couldn't just buy back their shares because the IRS would have viewed that as a sham, and the cash would have been taxed as ordinary income. So, instead we simply made arrangements with an investment bank and our transfer agent to aggregate those shares that stockholders elected to cash in to maintain their income stream—and those shares were sold, with no commission costs (except the bid-ask spreads), to provide stockholders with the same cash income. Our shareholders were taxed on that income at a capital gains tax rate, and only on the difference between the sales price and their basis.

So, we achieved a significant reduction in taxes for the stockholders who elected to continue to receive income.

MYERS: It's good financial engineering. But, again, I think it's a second order effect, just as Miller & Modigliani taught us.

STERN: Well, I think that's a good note on which to bring this to a close, and I want to thank you all very much for your participation. We expected this to be an exciting program, and I think we got our fair rate of return.

分享
查看原文
范德比尔特大学资本结构难题圆桌会议
1998年4月2日         田纳西州纳什维尔:下午好。我是Joel Stern,Stern Stewart&amp;我谨代表我们在范德比尔特大学欧文管理研究生院的东道主,欢迎大家参加这次关于公司资本结构的讨论。在开始讨论我们的主题之前,让我花点时间感谢Hans Stoll组织了这次关于“金融市场与公司”的会议。我也想借此机会向Martin Weingartner教授致敬,因为他结束了漫长而富有成效的职业生涯。Marty对公司金融领域的贡献是巨大的;而且,尽管他可能会辞去正式职务,但我们预计在未来几年里还会继续收到他的来信。今天会议的主题是公司资本结构:资本结构重要吗?如果是的话,它是如何以及为什么重要的?尽管金融学界对这些问题进行了近40年的认真辩论,但我们似乎并不比1958年更接近于一个明确的答案,当时默顿·米勒和弗兰科·莫迪利亚尼发表了他们的文章,提出了他们两个著名的“无关”命题中的第一个。继M&amp;M命题,20世纪60年代和70年代的学术研究人员将注意力转向了各种市场“不完美”,这些不完美可能使公司价值取决于资本结构和股息政策。主要的嫌疑是:(1)税法通过支付利息而不是股息来鼓励债务,可减税;(2)财务困境的预期成本,包括企业投资不足,随着资本结构中债务数量的增加,这些成本可能会变得很重要。在20世纪70年代末,人们还讨论了“信号”效应——例如,股票市场对新股发行的公告做出负面反应的趋势。1984年,斯图尔特·迈尔斯教授在美国金融协会发表了总统演讲,他称之为“资本结构难题”,这是学术资本结构辩论的一个决定性时刻。“难题在于:大多数关于资本结构的学术讨论都是基于这样一种假设,即公司在目标资本结构的指导下做出融资决策——管理层旨在实现的债务与股权的比例,如果不是一直实现的话,那么至少是长期平均水平。但经验证据表明情况并非如此。迈尔斯教授观察到,大多数美国大型上市公司并没有坚持目标,而是表现得像是在遵循财务“等级顺序”。如果可能的话,它们用留存收益而不是外部融资来资助投资;如果需要外部资金,他们会先发行债券,最后才发行股票。自那以后,资本结构的争论愈演愈烈。哈佛大学教授迈克尔·詹森在20世纪80年代中期加入了这场争论,他指出了杠杆收购的成功,并指出债务融资对管理层过度投资资本和产能过剩行业的倾向产生了有益影响。而且,似乎是为了满足詹森教授的要求,在接下来的十年里,市场继续提供大量杠杆收购和其他高杠杆交易。然后,在20世纪90年代初,我们看到杠杆交易几乎完全停止。但今天,当然,杠杆作用又回来了。新一波杠杆收购打破了大部分旧记录,垃圾债券发行创历史新高。那么,如果资本结构无关紧要,那么这里发生了什么?杠杆收购运动的成功对我们最大的上市公司的管理层有什么意义吗?这种影响似乎证实了巨大的“信息成本”的存在,这些成本也可能以可预测的方式影响公司的融资选择。我们在这里讨论这些问题,并帮助我们阐明这一资本结构难题,是一个由学者和从业者组成的小型但杰出的团体。让我简单介绍一下:STEWART MYERS,我已经多次提到他的名字,是我最喜欢的学校之一,麻省理工学院斯隆管理学院的Billard公司金融教授。Stew多年来一直在资本结构、估值和监管方面进行研究。他还担任过许多公司和金融机构的顾问。让我提一下,对我们斯特恩-斯图尔特来说,斯图尔特-迈尔斯这个名字有着特殊的意义。正如这里的大多数人都很清楚的那样,Stew与伦敦商学院的Dick Brealey合著了《企业金融原理》,这是企业金融领域的领先教科书。Stern Stewart的每一位员工都必须在进门时已经阅读了这本书。艾莉斯·彼得森是西尔斯公司的副总裁兼财务主管。 也就是说,长期以来回报率远低于资本成本的公司突然表现出色。迈尔斯:太好了,乔尔。但是,你又一次表明了我的观点。你所说的是,通过进入并改变财务结构——包括企业内部的激励体系——你可以让为组织贡献人力资本的人承担额外的风险,因为他们得到了奖励。斯特恩:是的,没错。迈尔斯:不过,我的观点是,从效率的角度来看,人力资本投资在很大程度上是需要保护的。现在,当它停止生产时,你不想保护它——这种情况发生在许多大型官僚组织中。但是,总的来说,当你要求人们对你的公司进行人力资本投资时,你不会做一些不必要地将投资置于风险之中的事情,比如将杠杆率提高得过高,这在经济上是有效的。史坦:原谅我,史坦,但我还是有问题。让我们假设我们按照你提出的顺序做所有的事情,资本结构和税收问题是清单上的最后一件事。让我们假设我们得到了正确的20项激励措施,并将其深入到公司中。现在,在做了这些事情之后,我们再次谈到债务是否比股权便宜得多的问题。而且,正如你所建议的,Stew,在许多情况下,我们可能会得出结论,公司无法支持太多的杠杆,无论是因为债务会危及战略计划,还是使人力资本投资面临不应有的风险。我的论点是:即使在这种情况下,我仍然怀疑,在很多公司里,很多有才华、有活力的人都非常愿意为了正确的回报而将人力资本置于风险之中。毕竟,KKR在进入一家公司时基本上就是这样做的。他们对运营管理层说:“如果你愿意承担一些额外的风险,并让自己遵守极具挑战性的绩效标准,我们可以让你获得非常大的回报。”正如我们现在从研究中了解到的那样,同样的运营经理已经表明,当你改变激励制度时,他们有能力在3年或更短的时间内将公司的运营现金流翻一番。这基本上就是我们试图通过EVA实现的,但没有高杠杆对人力资本造成的风险。几周前,在我们为长荣客户举行的一次会议上,Michael Jensen和我就他最喜欢的一个主题展开了一场智力上的较量。Mike和我的合伙人Bennett Stewart都喜欢谈论高负债率在阻止经理利用股东资源做傻事方面的有效性。其基本思想是,债务对管理施加了一种纪律,这种纪律在现金太多、盈利投资机会很少的公司中可能很有价值。正如我们在一系列文章中所说,我们基于EVA的激励薪酬也是为了解决企业的“自由现金流”问题。而且,因为我们的体系可以很好地纳入公司结构——也就是说,纳入各个业务部门及以下——我认为,在阻止公司资本浪费方面,EVA甚至可能比债务融资更具成本效益。因此,如果我们已经成功地设计和实施了一个衡量和奖励系统,激励管理者最有效地利用资本——我承认这是一个关键的假设——那么为什么有必要通过债务来实现同样的目标呢?也就是说,假设债务在某些情况下为管理创造了一个有价值的纪律,为什么EVA计划提供的“本地化”激励措施不会做得更好呢?毕竟,正如你所指出的,Stew,过多的债务可能会扼杀所有的企业投资,无论好坏。EVA体系鼓励管理者只为那些承诺赚取资本成本的项目而战。索尔特:让我来试试,乔尔。冒着被要求离开合伙企业的风险,让我告诉你以下故事。1992年,我们帮助美国最大的消费者金融信息提供商Equifax采用EVA激励措施。与此同时,我们被要求就一项相当激进的杠杆资本重组向该公司提供建议。正如首席财务官告诉我的那样,“看,任何事情都有可能发生。董事会没有合同义务在这家公司继续实施EVA激励措施。但与债务相关的合同义务是真实存在的,未能履行这些义务对公司和股东的影响远大于取消EVA计划。”。 索尔特:但据我所知,优先顺序理论的前提之一是股息是粘性的。仅出于这个原因,我很难理解该政策如何与价值最大化行为相一致。迈尔斯:我们现在在讨论股息政策吗?索特:我不知道你怎么能把两者分开。根据我的经验,它们是相互依存的决策——或者至少我们鼓励管理层这样看待它们。迈尔斯:为什么股息和税收无关?SOTER:如果除了税收之外,它们都无关紧要,那么我的第一个想法是:为什么我们不在寻求或考虑寻求外部融资之前削减股息?这就是我们在我刚才提到的SPX案例中所做的。迈尔斯:我还没有一个完整的答案,我认为这是学术金融领域尚未解决的最大问题之一。我们没有一个好的股息政策理论。我们没有任何股息政策理论可以追溯到任何一种基本面。因此,我承认,优先顺序将股息的粘性视为一个事实。它并没有试图解释这一点。我认为任何人都无法解释。注:让我再举一个例子,说明如何利用股息削减来促进杠杆率的提高。一年前,我们为印第安纳波利斯电力和照明公司的母公司IPALCO Enterprises提供咨询,使其成为有史以来第一家进行杠杆资本重组的公用事业公司。IPALCO最初的债券评级为“AA”,债务资本比率为42%。该公司借款超过4亿美元,并将所得用于回购其普通股。在此过程中,该公司的债务资本比率从42%上升到69%。但债务的增加实际上是通过股息削减近33%来实现的,从每股1.48美元降至每股1美元。事实上,每年从股息削减中节省的约4100万美元超过了税后利息支出的增加约2500万美元。也就是说,即使杠杆率从42%提高到69%,IPALCO的税后现金流实际上也增加了2500万美元。公告发布后的第二天,两家评级机构都重申了该公司的“AA-”/“AA”债券评级,这进一步表明,杠杆率,至少在传统的账面会计术语中,并不重要。自那时以来,IPALCO的经营现金流也有所增加,股市似乎对所发生的事情很满意。1997年,该公司的股票为股东提供了58.5%的总回报,使其跻身去年前三大电力公司之列。麦克康奈尔:我只想停下来评估一下,并确保,如果这里有辩论,我们都了解辩论的内容。如果我理解Stew的观察,那就是资本结构可能很重要,但至少从经理的角度来看,这似乎并不重要。经理们不会花很多时间担心它。这是一个合理的描述吗?迈尔斯:这是对的,至少对于负债率在中等范围内的大型老牌公司来说是这样。麦康奈尔:如果我理解的话,丹尼斯的论点是资本结构绝对重要,他给了我们几个案例说明。当然,使用案例的一个问题是,你只听到那些有效的案例——丹尼斯,这并不是说你的所有案例都不起作用;我确信他们做到了。罗恩·马苏利斯(Ron Masulis)对股票市场对交易所报价的反应进行了一项经典研究。这项研究非常清楚地表明,当公司宣布发行新债券以退役股票时,他们的股价会上涨,这对大量公司来说,而不仅仅是一两个有趣的案例。研究还表明了相反的情况:当发行股票以偿还债务时,股价会下跌。现在,问题是:为什么会发生这种情况?我们应该如何解读市场的反应?一些人认为,这是一种信号效应。也就是说,大多数公司倾向于只有当他们预计未来收益——或者更准确地说,经营现金流——会增加时,才进行杠杆增加重述。在投资者理解这一点的范围内,他们会提高股价,以期待未来更高的运营收益。事实上,这可能解释了市场对丹尼斯所描述的杠杆重述的反应。相反的情况可能解释了市场对杠杆率下降的负面反应。如果你仔细观察Ron的数据,你会发现90%的公司实际上都处于某种程度的财务困境中。所以,我们可能从宣布的股权增加互换中得到的是一个信号,我们真的有麻烦了,伙计们。 丹尼斯,我的问题是:这些杠杆式的重述本身有价值吗?比如说,对他们的税收节省和一些有益的激励作用?还是它们只是管理层对未来收益信心的信号?SOTER:你警告我可能处理的是一个有偏见的样本,这当然是正确的,我意识到轶事证据并不构成证据。但让我回答你的问题,告诉你更多关于IPALCO.McCONNELL的信息:继续吧。我在普渡大学已经20年了,它离我很近。SOTER:由于这是一家公用事业公司,印第安纳波利斯电力和照明公司在披露方面可能远远超出了大多数不受监管的公司的规定。事实上,出于所有实际目的,他们与投资界共享一个5年计划。公用事业分析师以预测每个季度每股收益在一便士以内而闻名,因为管理层正在向他们灌输所有信息。因此,我认为他们的新财务战略没有太大的信号空间。另一方面,我认为你可以说,在SPX、Briggs和Stratton的案件中有很多信号。就Briggs和Stratton而言,在宣布这一消息的那一周,股价从42.75美元涨到了48美元。而且,正如我之前提到的,SPX的股价从43.50美元开始,正好穿过荷兰拍卖的价格区间(48美元至56美元),最终接近70美元。但让我也观察一下:如果信号是解释,那么几乎可以肯定,信号背后还有许多其他真实的影响。例如,SPX、Briggs和Stratton在宣布其回顾之前都曾是EVA公司一段时间。而且,由于投资者已经对这两个管理团队产生了一定程度的信心,在过去取得的成就基础上,这种未来改进的信号可能特别令人信服。为了向您展示我所说的真正的改进,现在让我回到IPALCO的案例。IPALCO完成回顾大约7个月后,我与首席财务官John Brehm共进午餐。在描述自回顾以来内部发生的一些事件时,他说:“这太不寻常了。1997年的8个月里,我们在每股收益方面的预算是正确的,但自回顾以来,我们在现金流方面领先了4000万美元。”。他们正在以不同的方式经营业务,尽管这还没有反映在报告的收益中。(我必须承认,就连我自己也有点惊讶;我认为没有什么能引起公用事业经理的注意。)所以,我认为这里有几件事在起作用。是的,有一些信号。但你必须问:信号是什么——或者为什么管理层对未来的经营现金流更有信心?答案的很大一部分是,管理者现在有更强的动机来产生经营现金流,而债务通过庇护公司税来帮助增加现金流。除此之外,用股票回购代替现金股息,通过以更节税的方式分配现金,提高了股东的税后回报率。迈尔斯:顺便说一句,公用事业行业有一个信号。如果我是一名公用事业投资者,我担心的是公用事业会把所有流入口袋的现金流都烧到某个地方。在你的情况下,杠杆重述是一个信号,表明他们不会这么做。彼得森:我同意,就像没有什么能比得上断头台来集中注意力一样,杠杆在某些情况下也会产生奇妙的效果。但我也相信,我们可以在公司内部创造激励措施,在不增加杠杆的情况下产生杠杆收购的心态和行为。换言之,我认为我们必须考虑如何获得我们想要的行为,我认为有很多方法可以做到这一点。正如乔尔所指出的,万无一失的方法是提高杠杆率,要求经理拥有大量股票。没有什么能比得上每天都让他们面对债务偿还了。所以我同意这一点。斯特恩:爱丽丝,对西尔斯的股息政策有什么感觉?西尔斯能否将股息削减三分之一,甚至降至零,并借入更多资金,从而提高其价值?彼得森:我们已经10多年没有增加股息了。事实上,我们已经通过我们所做的衍生产品有效地减少了它。当我们剥离Dean Witter Discover时,我们减少了股息支付总额;当我们剥离Allstate时,我们又减少了它。当然,这与将其降至零不是一回事。这是一个后果非常严重的行动。西尔斯是美国交易最活跃的股票之一。 而且,当你的股票交易活跃,持有量和我们的股票一样大时,如果你决定取消股息,你必须准备好应对股东基础的巨大变化。我并不是说做不到。但这需要大量的准备,而且必须非常、非常仔细地与投资界沟通。这不是我们在不久的将来打算做的事情。换言之,在决定你作为一家公司的灵活性的整个活动和决策周期中,为你的公司定位是一个极其关键的部分。就像杠杆的情况一样,你需要制定股息政策,使其支持你的商业模式,支持你执行战略计划的能力。SOTER:我不认为股息政策的制定需要考虑到当前股东群体的需求。1994年,我们为佛罗里达电力公司的母公司FPL集团董事会提供咨询;光,在其作出的决定中,许多人认为这是财务上的自杀。据我所知,FPL是第一家自愿削减股息的盈利公用事业公司。股息削减了近三分之一,从每股62美分的季度派息降至42美分;取而代之的是,董事会授权管理层在公开市场上回购多达1000万股普通股。如果说有所谓的“客户效应”的测试,那就是它。我记得在做出最终决定之前的董事会会议上,一位董事问过这样一个问题:“对我们的股价可能会有什么影响?”我保守地回答——我希望——市场价格会下跌25%,在两三个月内不会完全恢复。果不其然,该股在公告发布当天下跌了15%。但在3周内,价格已经完全回升。更重要的是,股息削减本身导致15家经纪公司对该股进行了“买入”。该股吸引了许多新的机构投资者,尽管它失去了许多其他机构投资者。在股息行动后的12个月里,FPL的股东实现了23.8%的总回报,是标准普尔的两倍多;P电气指数。因此,投资者客户和股东基础的构成发生了重大变化。这种情况也往往发生在杠杆资本重组中。当我们在1992年为Equifax提供非常积极的杠杆资本重组建议时,该公司的投资者构成也发生了重大变化。这两次经历让我相信,一个股东的客户确实和另一个股东一样好。迈尔斯:丹尼斯,你的案子很有趣,但我不确定对西尔斯这样的公司有什么好说的。假设西尔斯将股息降至零,但不进行杠杆重组。它所要做的就是告诉股东,“别担心,随着时间的推移,我们会用股息来回购股票吗?”;光照了。他们没有进行杠杆资本重组,但他们确实宣布将使用部分现金储蓄在公开市场回购股票。因此,这是一个很好的、几乎由实验室控制的例子,我们削减了现金股息,并取代了公开市场回购政策。彼得森:我们的赔付率在20%-25%之间,这比我们同行的赔付率低一点。另一个考虑因素——尽管不一定是最重要的因素——是我们的股东往往是我们的客户。这些所谓的“散户”投资者往往想要分红。迈尔斯:我倾向于同意爱丽丝的立场。我认为,即使是最热衷于市场效率的人也不应该对此感到困扰。金融的“完美市场”观点会说,除了暂时的信号效应外,你是支付股息还是回购股票其实并不重要。因此,如果有人说,“为什么要支付股息?”标准答案是,“为什么不呢?有客户想要股息,而消费者是主权的。”那么,如果这个世界上有人要支付股息,西尔斯为什么不可能满足这一需求呢?我认为那个论点没有什么错。我能看到的唯一可能的反对意见是再次征税。但我认为没有人证明高股息收益率会因为税收而导致更高的资本成本。STERN:那么,让我问你一个问题,Stew。如果你说的是真的,那么为什么有些公司不拥有两类股票,一类支付高股息,另一类支付低股息?通过这种方式,股东可以购买他们想要的任何股票组合,从而制定自己的股息政策。 如果股息非常重要,以至于为投资者制定了最佳的股息政策,那么你会期望投资者可以获得不止一类股票,这样他们就可以制定自己的股息政策。迈尔斯:你没听到我说的。我说过,除了给出的短期信号外,股息政策并不重要。现金是通过股息还是股票回购来支付并不重要。(当然,支付的现金总额确实很重要。)但也有人出于任何原因想要一些股息。必须有人给他们。西尔斯把它送给他们并不花太多钱。他们是这种服务的自然提供者。为什么不呢?如果其他人想回购股票,对他们有好处。我就是不在乎。索特:如果我也在这里建议,我们也可以吃蛋糕。正如Joel所提到的,在加入Stern Stewart之前,我曾在Citizens Utilities工作。公民公用事业公司的创始人是Richard Rosenthal,你们中的一些人可能知道这个案例,因为早在70年代,罗切斯特大学的John Long就写了一篇关于该公司极不寻常的股息政策的论文。多年来,公民有两类普通股,一类支付现金股息,另一类支付同等金额的普通股股息。理查德最初于1956年获得了这一祖父身份,通过连续的税收法案,这一豁免得到了延长。但是,在1990年,随着布什税法的出台,我们看到我们将失去免税权。所以我们有两种选择:我们可以取消股票股息,将其改为现金股息,或者我们可以将现金股息类别转换为股票股息,从而完全取消现金股息。我们选择了第二道菜。我们显然不会开始在股票股息类别上支付现金股息。为了减轻对想要现金的股东的打击,我们制定了“股票股息出售计划”。实际上,我们说,“我们将向所有股东发放股票股息,但那些想要获得现金收入的股东可以进行选择,有效地将股息转换为现金。”,该公司不能仅仅回购他们的股票,因为美国国税局会认为这是一场骗局,现金将作为普通收入征税。因此,我们只是与一家投资银行和我们的转让代理人达成协议,将股东选择兑现的股票汇总起来,以维持其收入流——这些股票被出售,没有佣金成本(买卖价差除外),为股东提供相同的现金收入。我们的股东对这些收入按资本利得税税率征税,而且只按销售价格与其基础之间的差额征税。因此,我们为那些选择继续获得收入的股东大幅减税。迈尔斯:这是一个很好的金融工程。但是,我再次认为这是一个二阶效应,就像Miller&amp;莫迪利亚尼教过我们。斯特恩:好吧,我认为这是一个很好的结束语,我非常感谢大家的参与。我们预计这将是一个激动人心的项目,我认为我们得到了公平的回报率。 众所周知,西尔斯在过去几年中取得了显著的经营业绩改善,股东价值大幅增长。Alice于1989年加入西尔斯,担任公司财务总监,4年后于1993年出任副总裁兼财务主管。在加盟西尔斯之前,她曾在卡夫和百事可乐担任公司财务和财务职务。1981年,她在范德比尔特大学获得MBA学位,并在纽约证券交易所两家公司的董事会任职。约翰·麦克康奈尔是普渡大学的伊曼纽尔·T·威勒金融学教授。John在公司金融领域做出了广泛的贡献,尤其是在创新证券的分析方面。我还记得约翰在我们旧的《大通金融季刊》上发表的一篇关于收益债券的文章,这是我们《应用企业金融杂志》的前身。而且,在大约5、6年前的一期JACF中,John(与Eduardo Schwartz)合著了一篇关于LYONS起源的引人入胜的文章,LYONS是美林开创的一种非常成功的可推杆、可转换证券。考虑到约翰讲故事的能力,我们谁也不会对他年复一年地在普渡大学获得教学奖感到惊讶。最后是丹尼斯·索特,他是我的同事,也是斯特恩·斯图尔特的合伙人。1972年,丹尼斯从罗切斯特大学西蒙商学院毕业后,加入了我在大通曼哈顿银行的工作。然后,在1979年,我们分道扬镳。Dennis成为Brown Foreman负责企业发展的副总裁,在那里他帮助公司从Jack Daniels(和其他温和麻醉剂)的制造商转变为一家多元化的消费品公司。然后他去了安永会计师事务所;Whinney,在那里他是M&amp;A.接下来,他加入了公民公用事业公司,帮助他们成为一家不受监管的公司和一家受监管的企业。几年前,我们非常幸运地说服对方,我们应该再次在一起。Dennis现在负责我们的企业财务咨询活动,并监督EVA在中等市场规模公司的实施。我相信丹尼斯会告诉我们,在过去的两年里,他曾担任过三次非常成功的杠杆资本重组的财务顾问。这三笔交易中的每一笔都涉及借入大量新债务回购股票,其中两笔涉及股息政策的重大变化。斯特恩:既然我们知道了小组成员是谁,让我把发言权交给斯图尔特·迈尔斯教授。Stew,你可能不记得了,但在1983年,你好心地在我们的《米德兰企业金融杂志》上发表了一篇题为“寻找最佳资本结构”的文章。这不仅是一篇了不起的文章,而且是该杂志第一期(第一卷第1号)的主要文章。然后,大约10年过去了,你为我们写了第二篇文章,名为《仍在寻找最佳资本结构》。这也是一篇精彩的文章——我在哥伦比亚大学和卡内基梅隆大学教授的课程中使用了这篇文章(与第一篇文章一起)。我想问你的问题是:你目前对资本结构辩论的看法是什么?你的下一篇文章叫什么?STEWART MYERS:下一个将被称为“停止寻找最佳资本结构”。让我花一两分钟告诉你为什么。自从我进入斯坦福大学的博士项目以来,最优资本结构显然是我一直关心和努力的问题。这些年来,我们一直无法找到任何简单的答案,这让我很沮丧。但我最近有了不同的看法。当我们谈论最优资本结构时,我们想到的是资产负债表右侧不同证券的百分比。我们倾向于从债务和股权的组合来思考,至少一开始是这样,然后再考虑其他证券。例如,我们关注优先股,以及可转换债券等混合证券。我们在多大程度上理解这些融资选择如何影响公司价值?在战术层面上,我认为我们非常理解这一点。例如,如果你让学者或从业者分析一项金融创新,比如约翰·麦康奈尔刚刚告诉我们的免税优惠,我们做得很好。我们了解这些东西是如何工作的,为什么它们是这样设计的,以及你需要做什么才能把它们卖掉。因此,在这个战术层面上,我们可以对我们对资本结构的理解感到相当满意。我们倾向于用简洁或简单的理论来理解资本结构在我称之为“战略”层面的作用,也就是说,当你试图解释公司的平均或长期负债率时。我们确实对资本结构有一些有用的见解,我们知道什么应该是重要的。 但很难将这些见解整合成一个简单的理论来预测管理者将要做什么,或者告诉我们他们应该做什么。我们为什么不解决这个问题?我认为我们开始的地方不对。我们不应该从资产负债表右侧不同类型融资的百分比开始。我们不应该从资本结构开始,而应该从金融结构开始。我所说的财务结构是指所有权和控制权的分配,包括企业内部人和外部人对企业风险和回报的划分,尤其是无形资产的风险和回报。上市公司真正发生的事情是内部人士和金融投资者的共同投资,他们将人力资本带到公司中。这两个集团共享组织的无形资产。而且,为了使共享投资发挥作用,你必须弄清楚所有权和控制权、激励措施、风险分担等问题。你必须从确保你把所有这些事情都做好开始。这就是我所说的金融结构。金融结构与融资组合不是一回事。让我举一个简单的例子。以一家高科技风险投资初创公司为例,将其与微软进行比较。尽管他们的债务比率可能是相同的——也就是零——但我想我们都会同意,从财务角度来看,他们不是一回事。上市管理咨询公司和通常的私人管理咨询公司之间也可以进行同样的比较。尽管他们的资产负债表可能看起来完全一样,但我认为他们非常不同。特别是,我预测,如果你让一家小型咨询公司上市,它几乎肯定会崩溃。这些资产每天晚上都会回家,很难有合适的激励措施来留住公司的关键人员,同时满足外部投资者的需求。所以,如果Stern Stewart上市,Joel,我会等6个月,然后卖空你。STERN:我真的做了一个梦,梦见有人会对我们这样做——但我不知道,Stew,会是你!我必须承认,这样的想法已经在我脑海中闪过。但是,如果我们要走这样一条路(我们没有计划这样做),我们会设计新公司,以保护外部投资者,与其说是保护他们免受资产在晚上回家的可能性,不如说是他们可能会永久搬到毛伊岛。顺便说一句,这不是一个不合理的问题,因为博思艾伦曾经这样做过。你可能不知道,但在20世纪70年代,Booz Allen在十几岁的时候就以一定的价格上市了。股价曾高达20美元左右,随后跌至2美元左右,并在2美元至6美元之间徘徊了很长一段时间。我之所以知道这件事,是因为我曾在一家公司的董事会任职,当时我是博思艾伦的副董事长。每当这家私人控股公司上市的可能性被提出时,他都会说:“这是错误的做法。”他会再次把我们拖入这段可怕的经历。但布兹-艾伦犯了一个根本性的错误——如果纠正这个错误,可能会改变结果。他们没有区分外部股票和内部股票。如果内部人士持有的股票只是逐渐转化为外部人士的股票,那么内部人士不会去任何地方。他们还可以向员工发行股票期权,其价值与内幕股票的价值挂钩。有了内幕股票和期权,人们需要很长时间才能拿出他们在公司积累的财富。你觉得这个主意怎么样,Stew?迈尔斯:我想你只是在表达我的观点。首先,我认为把一家小型咨询公司上市是没有意义的。但如果你这样做了,你就必须关注财务结构——比如谁拥有什么,谁可以做出什么决定,目标和绩效指标是什么,以及人们如何因实现这些目标而获得奖励。斯特恩:所以,你对财务结构的概念与一些人所说的公司治理或组织结构本质上是一样的——它是决策权、监督、绩效指标、激励措施的分配,等等?迈尔斯:金融结构是我对所有这些东西的简写——只有两个词。我的观点是,这些财务结构问题是大多数公司最关心的问题。管理层必须把它们做好。现在,这并不等同于说管理者必须有意识地做所有这些事情。有时,他们做对了,因为他们做了其他公司已经做过的事情,并活了下来。一旦一家工业公司上市,它通常是一家财务结构良好的中型公司。从某种意义上说,它已经解决了80%的问题——也就是说,只要它保持高效运行。 在解决了这个问题之后,我认为大多数公司都不太担心他们的债务股本比率。很明显,他们担心如果它变得太高,他们担心它变得太低。但有一个很大的中间区间,它似乎并不重要。我认为这就是为什么我们很难确定债务权益比率到底是什么或应该是什么。与金融结构的选择相比,这是一个“二阶”问题。斯特恩:人们已经指出,利息支出的税收减免使债务成为一种增加可观价值的方式。由于这些税收保护带来的价值,有人可能会认为,积极使用债务可能是抵御不友好收购的最佳防御措施。这一论点难道不意味着资本结构至少可以成为一个首要问题吗?迈尔斯:通过提出敌意收购的问题,我认为你把投资决策和融资决策混为一谈。我想把它们分开,至少作为一个起点。大多数收购目标之所以成为目标,并不是因为他们没有足够的债务,而是因为糟糕的投资决策和糟糕的经营业绩。20世纪80年代杠杆收购浪潮的主要原因不是公司未能利用债务的税收优势。大多数杠杆收购——我有点过于简单化了——都是“减肥交易”。它们涉及收购现金太多、投资机会太少的成熟公司,并让它们节食。因此,尽管有税收节约,但交易本身并不是由税收驱动的。丹尼斯·索尔特:多年来与我们合作的大多数公司确实花了很多时间考虑资本结构。现在,确实他们通常不会像学者那样思考这个问题——也就是说,从市场债务与股本比率的角度来看。他们中的大多数人都以债券评级或账面杠杆率来定义自己的目标。但他们确实有松散的财务战略定义,以及在资本结构中什么是债务和股权的适当组合。我想问迈尔斯教授一个问题:你用了“最优资本结构”这个词。你能为我们定义一下吗?迈尔斯:最简单地说,最佳资本结构是债务在资产负债表上的最佳百分比。SOTER:但从什么角度来看是最佳的呢?迈尔斯:最大化公司的市场价值。我并不是说这是一个错误的问题,或者一个无关或无趣的问题。这是一个非常有趣的问题。但我认为,如果过于狭隘地关注这一点,你就会错过我将其放在财务结构标题下的其他事情——我倾向于认为这些事情对公司经理来说更重要,因此在解释我们所看到的公司行为方面更有力。斯特恩:我认为你是对的,至少在我经常看到的行为在我看来并不是价值最大化。例如,在几年前我们进行的一次圆桌讨论中,其中一位参与者是一家上市公司的所有者,他和他的家人拥有该公司约37%的股权。我问他为什么负债率这么低。我对他说:“你自愿缴纳大量可以避免的税款。你为什么不把你的债务比率提高到你税前大部分营业收入都得到税收保护的程度呢?”你看,他缴纳的税款相当可观;仅仅通过改变资本结构,每年就可以节省1200万至1500万美元。为什么公司会这么做,Stew?迈尔斯:先告诉我他说了什么。斯特恩:他有点疑惑地看着我,他说:“好吧,你不需要纳税吗?”迈尔斯:你说得对。如果你只看税收,并计算更多地使用债务可以节省的税收的现值,这似乎是一个很大的数字。很难解释为什么公司似乎不努力利用债务提供的税收优惠。我真的无法解释为什么公司没有利用这些储蓄。我也同意丹尼斯的观点,企业会说他们有目标债务比率。但事实上,他们并不是很努力地工作到那里。如果一家公司非常有利可图,而且不需要外部资金,那么它可能会降低负债率。如果它缺乏资金,就会导致高负债率。这些公司并没有将其债务比率目标视为一阶目标。SOTER:让我提出一个问题,为这个资本结构难题提供一个可能的线索:激进地使用杠杆是否符合首席执行官和首席财务官的个人利益?他们是否通过激励措施,无论是通过持股还是其他方式,来制定积极的债务政策?我认为,美国最大的几位首席财务官。 上市公司拥有足够的股权,甚至可以考虑进行杠杆资本重组。如果成功的话,他或她目前看起来不错。但如果不起作用,他将永远无法在美国企业界找到另一份首席财务官的工作。因此,公司管理层面临着巨大的个人风险,而补偿回报可能很少。如果没有重大的所有权权益,谁不愿意拥有一个a债券评级,晚上睡个好觉呢?斯特恩:除非他们受到不友好的收购——在这种情况下,他们肯定会失业。索尔特:乔尔,你引用了一个极端的例子,一家公司有太多未使用的债务能力,以至于邀请了一个恶意投标。根据我的经验,还有许多其他公司,虽然不是收购候选人,但仍有足够的超额债务能力,其股东将从杠杆资本重组中受益。约翰·麦克康奈尔:多年前,当我开始我的职业生涯时,我教了一门关于公司资本结构的课程,以为我对此有所了解。然后,在几年的时间里,我放弃了教授资本结构,因为我得出的结论是我一无所知。最近,我开始教授一门我称之为资本结构的课程,但它实际上相当于一门公司治理课程。所以,我认为我的思维一直在经历一种进化,这与Stew刚刚描述的非常相似。和你一样,丹尼斯,当Stew定义最优资本结构并描述资本结构难题时,我也在考虑管理激励。我怀疑,我们大多数人都会同意这样一个普遍的主张,即债务融资有税收保护。对于这种税收保护的价值,肯定会有一些分歧:它是债务融资的34美分,还是考虑到债务持有人缴纳的税款,这个数字会降到只有15或20美分?但是,无论你选择这个范围的哪一端,在座的大多数人可能都会同意,这种节省的价值是巨大的。因此,我们大多数人也可能同意,无论出于何种原因,许多上市公司都没有使用足够的债务——没有使用债务的价值最大化水平。但让我也回应丹尼斯说,股票所有权可能不是这个问题的完整答案。我是一家资产约6亿美元的银行的董事会成员,该银行的最低资本比率有很大的自由度。然而,该银行的所有者出于某种原因坚持保持高资本比率。这样一来,他们不仅放弃了可能的税收优惠,还放弃了存款保险“资金套利”。就像乔尔之前描述的公司一样,这家银行47%的股票由一个投资者家族所有。如果只考虑他们的所有权激励,那么这种特定的所有权结构似乎会有足够强大的激励,促使管理者拥有高杠杆率。但相反,它们的杠杆率很低,资本过剩。顺便说一句,这种情况绝非反常现象;它在拥有大量内部人士所有权的美国上市公司中颇具代表性。研究内部人持股与杠杆率之间关系的研究表明,超过一定程度,拥有大量内部人持股的公司的杠杆率往往低于平均水平。与其他学术研究一样,所有权集中度和股票价值之间的关系显示为钟形曲线,这些关于杠杆和内部人所有权的研究表明,内部人实际上可能在自己的公司中拥有过多的股票。斯特恩:约翰,当我们在可口可乐公司做一些工作时,我也有同样的想法。可口可乐的首席执行官将自己个人净资产的很大一部分与公司的股权挂钩。他是第三或第四大股东。我突然想到,首席执行官的财富集中在可口可乐的股票上,从而集中在一个单一的投资组合中,这可能是阻止该公司出现高负债率的一个主要因素。也就是说,考虑到他的个人投资组合,他将公司的财务风险降至最低可能是合理的。这对我来说意味着,在拥有大量内部所有者的情况下,我们可能需要制定一个补偿方案,帮助克服所有者的风险厌恶,从而使他们的风险回报权衡与多元化股东的风险回报平衡。麦康奈尔:那使用无投票权的股票呢?这将允许内部人士为投资机会筹集资金,而不会减少他们对决策的控制。 例如,可口可乐的首席执行官本可以让公司发行无投票权的股票,然后将自己持有的股份集中在有投票权的股份上。你心里想的是那样的事吗?斯特恩:不,那不能解决我正在考虑的问题。我担心的是,由于首席执行官的持股占他个人净资产的很大比例,他比投资组合多元化的机构投资者更厌恶风险。这种风险厌恶很可能导致他使用的杠杆数量低于从机构所有者角度来看的最佳杠杆数量。麦康奈尔:这个问题的一个可能的解决方案是,首席执行官出售其大部分股权,从而使其投资组合多样化,并允许外部人士对公司拥有更大的控制权,这对可口可乐来说不是这样,但至少对小型、紧密控股的公司来说是这样。这最终可能会大幅增加公司的价值,至少在美国这样对小投资者有强有力的法律保护和运作良好的公司控制市场的国家是如此。斯特恩:但是,回到我们的主题,我们真的无法解释为什么上市公司的负债率很低——或者至少低到足以让它们最终多缴纳数百万美元的税款。既然我们身边有一位来自美国最大上市公司之一的高管,我们为什么不去找她呢?爱丽丝,你对这一切有什么解释?你如何看待西尔斯的公司财务政策?艾莉斯·彼得森:让我首先强调斯图尔特·迈尔斯的观点,即资本结构是一个更大的价值创造等式中相对较小的部分。在西尔斯,和大多数公司一样,创造股东价值是主要的管理目标。在我们让西尔斯成为一个引人注目的购物、工作和投资场所的口号背后,我们使用EVA类型的指标来跟踪“投资”类别的业绩。为了为投资者创造价值,公司需要一种商业模式来引导他们产生超额回报。商业模式因公司而异,甚至在同一行业内也是如此。这种商业模式包含总体目标、组织、战略和财务目标。我突然想到,Stewart Myers对资本结构的宽泛定义贯穿了我们的整个商业模式。我们称我们的整体财务指标为股东增值。它只是运营利润减去创造这些利润所需的所有资本成本。当我们将资本成本分解为资本金额乘以资本成本时,我们会将更多的管理精力集中在资本金额上——我们的方法侧重于运营。换句话说,我们想解决对资本的根本需求——对我们来说,这就是库存、库存和固定设备。我经常说,在西尔斯的35万名员工中,几乎所有人每天都会对资本金额产生影响,但只有少数人决定如何为资本需求提供资金。因此,我们花了更多的时间讨论如何用更少的资产获得更多的利润。对于我们中少数关注资产负债表右侧的人来说,通过管理资本结构来实现最低的长期资本成本是相当大的努力。一家公司如何决定其债务和股权的最佳组合?在西尔斯,我们首先要问我们希望支付多大的财务灵活性。这就引出了一场讨论,我们在讨论中确定我们的目标债务评级,这反过来又转化为目标资本结构。对于每一项战略计划,我们都在衡量自由现金流的程度、资本支出的适当水平,以及我们是否应该回购股票以及回购的程度。我可以告诉你,在过去的5年里,我们已经多次认真研究资本结构问题,因为我们已经进行了首次公开募股,并剥离了各个业务部门,不仅针对离开投资组合的业务,也针对剩下的业务。那么,这些财务灵活性考虑因素是什么呢?它们包括增长前景,以及公司是否倾向于有机增长或通过收购实现增长。它们还包括为公司定位以抵御极端经济周期和外部风险的必要性。其他考虑因素包括股权结构和股票定位、股息政策以及我们管理整体企业风险的能力。一个没有出现在大多数公司名单上,但对西尔斯来说非常重要的考虑因素是其持续的债务融资需求。西尔斯与零售竞争对手的不同之处在于我们成功的信贷业务。我们280亿美元的消费者应收款投资组合是最大的自营零售信贷投资组合(其次是J.C.Penney,50亿美元)。为这项盈利的信贷业务提供资金所需的250多亿美元债务融资是确定我们目标债务评级的关键考虑因素。 我们将长期债务评级定为“单a级”,以优化我们的整体资本成本。我们认为“双a”评级太贵了,但认为“三B”大大限制了我们的灵活性。重要的是,与我们的零售和服务竞争相比,降级的影响将不成比例地影响西尔斯。为了让您了解我们如何将股东价值准则融入日常生活,我们为整个企业的资本结构设定目标的方法是通过解决优化我们市场价值的资本结构。我们考虑了历史业绩、经济情景、商业和行业前景、破产风险和资本限制。从另一方面来看,我们也关注个体企业的资本成本。我们的个体企业包括非常不同的形式:全线商店、家居家具商店、西尔斯五金商店、我们的服务业务和我们的信用卡业务,仅举几例。这些业务代表了不同的风险水平,因此保证了不同的门槛率。我们通过两种方式来解决个体企业的资本成本问题:首先,我们从评级机构的角度来看待企业。我们问自己,“企业的现金流前景如何,相关风险如何?”我们还评估企业的竞争地位,并制定行业展望。其次,我们通过考察其竞争对手和其他基准来衡量同一企业的资本成本。我们问:“他们的资本结构和资本成本是什么?是否存在税收问题?”我们想知道我们的财务“DNA”是帮助还是阻碍有效竞争。我们看账面资本与账面外资本。我们进行分析,我们比较管理层,我们观察每项业务背后的“故事”。不用说,重要的是,我们所有组成业务的资本成本和资本结构加在一起,构成整个企业的整体。通过追求这种自上而下和自下而上的同时进行的方法,我们发现我们正在解决所有问题,这些问题使我们能够在相同的财务灵活性下在资本结构中获得更多的债务。斯特恩:好吧,回到我之前的问题,是否有许多上市公司正在放弃通过提高债务比率来增加重大价值的机会?还是我们错过了一些重要的东西?麦康奈尔:乔尔,我想我们已经听到了最好的答案。我们的激励结构在克服管理者的风险厌恶方面不是很有效;成功没有足够的回报来证明管理层的个人风险是合理的。斯特恩:但如果激励结构不有效,那么我们为什么不看到更不友好的收购,以确保它们正确对齐?彼得森:好吧,让我提醒你们两个之前的评论。你们都讲述了这样的故事:对一家机构有长期承诺的所有者不愿意承担太多债务或在资本不足的情况下运营,从而危及该机构的未来。经营一家杠杆率过高或股本过少的企业会产生成本——巨大的潜在成本。当我想到关于上市公司的报道时——固定收益分析师和评级机构的报道比股票分析师的报道更多——资本结构经常被谈论。当沉重的债务负担大大降低了公司的灵活性时,这就成了一个问题,对股票和固定收益分析师来说也是如此。如果没有其他原因的话,公司非常清楚这一点。我知道我们非常关注竞争对手的资本结构。我们经常考虑他们的资产负债表允许他们以竞争性罢工的方式做什么。听听这里的学者们的意见,我们认为企业不会主动设计其资本结构。听Joel和Dennis的话,我们相信美国很少有公司有足够的债务。我认为这两种观点都是没有根据的。因此,我必须承认,上市公司系统性杠杆不足的想法对我来说是希腊式的。在我们目前的商业模式下,我们公司今天的杠杆率并不低。5年前,我们显然杠杆率过高。SOTER:我想回应财务灵活性的问题,我想详细阐述我之前关于管理层不愿积极利用杠杆的声明。我的解释不仅仅是规避风险。归根结底:公司经理不喜欢让他们的战略受到市场的审查。他们喜欢能够划下银行存款额度并开支票。在所有条件相同的情况下,他们不愿意表现得像一家杠杆收购公司,每笔交易都是一次性的。我不同意Alice的观点,即大多数上市公司都没有杠杆不足。我不认为“单a”评级可能是大多数公司价值最大化的资本结构。 管理层和投资者之间所谓的信息不对称确实存在问题——在某些情况下,这种可能性可能会使财务灵活性变得非常有价值。如果你的公司完全杠杆化,而你的收入由于你无法控制的原因而下降,你可能会被迫放弃一些有利可图的投资。在这种情况下,说服资本市场提供资金可能代价高昂。爱丽丝,这是公司想要财务灵活性的一个主要原因吗?彼得森:好吧,这是解释的一部分。但它比现在走得更远。每一家公司都是不同的,与丹尼斯打交道的一些中等市场公司可能非常适合他所描述的观点。在西尔斯,我们非常清楚自己已经做了110年的生意,我们计划至少再做110年。当你思考你需要做些什么来确保这一点时,你会意识到财务保守主义可以让你度过各种可能影响你公司的经济周期和竞争变化。我们对公司的感觉很大程度上来自于对公司成就的了解,来自于我们作为一个做过大事的团队的一员的感觉。我们于1931年白手起家创立了Allstate,并于20世纪80年代末白手起家创办了Discover Card。公司财务主管必须了解执行战略计划和支持商业模式所需的资本资源(及其成本)。这需要一定程度的融资灵活性,而丹尼斯所描述的高杠杆资产负债表的公司却无法做到这一点。迈尔斯:我同意爱丽丝的观点。我不否认,在某些情况下,债务和重组的药物非常合适,而且非常成功。但在其他情况下,你不想让公司“节食”,或者至少不想“速成节食”。在这种情况下,当然不想让你的想法被税收等二阶问题所驱动。首先要考虑的应该是投资机会和商业机会。第二个考虑因素是企业的财务结构。第三个问题——在我看来,这是远远的第三个——是资产负债表中债务和股权的百分比组合。当你谈到资产负债表上的百分比问题时,税收只是我们所知道的四、五件可能重要的事情之一。出于这个原因,我认为从税收开始并说这是主要关注点有点过时,尽管我们可以同意这是一个重要因素。爱丽丝,我的第二个看法是,如果我用学术术语来形容你的演讲……彼得森:当然可以。迈尔斯:……应该是这样的:经济理论犯了一个大错误,把公司的所有员工都当作临时工。正如我之前所建议的,要想成功,一家公司需要外部金融资本和企业内部人力资本的共同投资。从长远来看,你需要人力资本才能使企业运转起来。对于那些将大部分人力资本与企业挂钩的人来说,保守地保护人力资本并不一定是低效的。在人力资本是可替代的,人们四处流动的地方,比如掉期交易员,公司可以更积极地承担金融风险。员工们也不会在意。但是,在一个组织中确实存在大量人力资本的情况下——例如,某人的整个职业生涯都在一家公司度过——他们想要保护这种投资是可以理解的。STERN:好吧,Stew,我想给你提个建议。我认为你所说的几乎可以肯定是真的——特别是考虑到大多数上市公司现有的固定薪酬和可变薪酬之间的分配。如果你看看中层及以下管理层的人,他们的可变薪酬部分通常是非常适中的。但是,当你把他们放在EVA激励系统中时,他们的行为几乎在一夜之间发生了变化。EVA激励系统对他们的奖励没有上限,而且有一个奖金银行系统来确保他们的付款是基于业绩的持续改善。在某些情况下,他们倾向于更激进的资本结构,因为这降低了他们的资本成本,增加了他们的EVA。除了Dennis刚才提到的SPX,Equifax、Briggs和Stratton等其他公司在首次实施EVA计划后,也进行了杠杆资本重组。我还建议,在进行EVA之后,所谓成熟行业的公司往往开始表现得好像他们的行业没有管理层想象的那么成熟。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信