Progressive taxation in the face of inflation and instability: lessons from Argentina

IF 2.2 3区 经济学 Q2 BUSINESS, FINANCE
Roberto Arias, Vedanth Nair
{"title":"Progressive taxation in the face of inflation and instability: lessons from Argentina","authors":"Roberto Arias,&nbsp;Vedanth Nair","doi":"10.1111/1475-5890.12344","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>Gabriel Zucman's article in this symposium sets out an agenda for how international cooperation can overcome barriers to progressive taxation and barriers to the taxation of wealth. Argentina has been at the forefront of developments in international tax cooperation. It has been one of the global minimum tax's strongest proponents, and has pushed for it to go even further by increasing the minimum rate to 21 per cent or 25 per cent. Argentina has also made use of automatic exchange of information (AEOI) to detect offshore tax evasion, signing AEOI agreements with almost 100 countries. AEOI has had modest results for Argentina. Zucman's article notes that offshore real estate is exempted under AEOI, but offshore currency holdings – which are an important asset class for wealthy Argentinians – are also poorly reported.</p><p>Whilst international cooperation is important, it is not the only barrier that needs to be overcome to tax the wealthy. Argentina presents a case study in how a progressive tax system can unravel in the face of high and volatile inflation, and how large swings in the tax rate due to political polarisation can limit the effectiveness of tax policy. This case study will be important for other developing and developed countries which are also often experiencing the high levels of inflation and political polarisation that Argentina has struggled with for decades.</p><p>Argentina is one of the few countries to already have a comprehensive wealth tax as advocated for by Zucman.1 The wealth tax is intended to be highly progressive, but high and volatile inflation, ranging from 20 to 40 per cent in the last 15 years, has at times brought many more people into the purview of the tax than initially intended. Figure 1 shows that the threshold to start paying wealth tax fell from 15 times GDP per capita in 2007 to 2 times GDP per capita in 2015, leading to the share of wealth tax payers increasing from 0.5 per cent to 1.9 per cent of the total population. Between 2016 and 2020, the wealth tax threshold was periodically updated, and from 2021 it was indexed to the consumer price index (CPI). This has not entirely fixed the problem, as official estimates of property values, which are a major component of the wealth tax base, are not regularly updated in Argentina. As property price growth tends to be higher than the CPI rate of inflation, a lack of revaluation means that the wealth tax falls on an ever-decreasing share of true wealth.</p><p>The story is similar for personal income taxation. As Figure 2 shows, the fraction of employees who were liable for the personal income tax grew from 10 per cent to 30 per cent in just four years between 2009 and 2013, as the tax-free allowance was fixed in nominal terms despite inflation of 20–40 per cent. This was corrected in 2014, and from 2016 the personal allowance threshold was indexed to nominal wages. However, indexation failed to stop the rise in the share of employees paying personal income tax, possibly because nominal wage growth for workers just under the threshold was faster than growth in the nominal wage index used.2</p><p>This highlights a deeper question: what is the goal of indexation for personal income taxes? One potential goal is to maintain consistency in the tax system in real terms, so an individual with a constant real wage does not experience fluctuating tax rates year-on-year due to inflation. Indexation of thresholds to the CPI is a simple way to try to achieve this. Another potential goal could be to keep the share of workers within each tax bracket constant, irrespective of the inflation rate or real wage growth, which approximately preserves the progressivity of the tax system. In that case, nominal wage indexation would be more natural. However, Argentina's experience between 2016 and 2020 shows that even nominal wage indexation may not always keep the share of workers paying personal income tax constant, if nominal wage growth varies across the wage distribution or if the measure of earnings used for indexation is partial or outdated. Since 2021, Argentina has set the threshold so that the share of workers paying personal income tax remains around 10 per cent. Although this type of ad-hoc rule may not be desirable from an optimal taxation point of view, some stability after a decade of substantial fluctuation is welcome.</p><p>Political polarisation has further complicated tax stability. Prior to 2015, the wealth tax rate was 1.25 per cent. It was reduced to 0.25 per cent by the centre-right Macri administration, only to be increased to 1.75 per cent (for domestic assets) and 2.25 per cent (for offshore assets) by the left-wing Fernández administration when it came to power in 2019. Corporate income tax followed a similar trajectory. The Macri administration reduced the corporate income tax rate from 35 per cent to 30 per cent in 2017, and had planned to reduce it further to 25 per cent, but the Fernández administration restored the rate to 35 per cent. Such drastic swings in tax policies can distort the behaviour of individuals and firms, further complicating tax design. For example, firms may not increase investment in response to a corporate tax cut, if they believe that tax rates will be higher after the next election. On the other hand, revenue from a corporate tax rate increase may fall short of expectations, if firms try to delay realising profits until the next election.</p><p>Unlike high inflation, it is harder for economists to make tax systems robust to political polarisation. However, global tax floors, such as the OECD's 15 per cent minimum corporate tax rate, may at least put some constraint on tax rates being tied to the political cycle.</p>","PeriodicalId":51602,"journal":{"name":"Fiscal Studies","volume":"44 3","pages":"247-249"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2000,"publicationDate":"2023-09-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/1475-5890.12344","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Fiscal Studies","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/1475-5890.12344","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"BUSINESS, FINANCE","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

Gabriel Zucman's article in this symposium sets out an agenda for how international cooperation can overcome barriers to progressive taxation and barriers to the taxation of wealth. Argentina has been at the forefront of developments in international tax cooperation. It has been one of the global minimum tax's strongest proponents, and has pushed for it to go even further by increasing the minimum rate to 21 per cent or 25 per cent. Argentina has also made use of automatic exchange of information (AEOI) to detect offshore tax evasion, signing AEOI agreements with almost 100 countries. AEOI has had modest results for Argentina. Zucman's article notes that offshore real estate is exempted under AEOI, but offshore currency holdings – which are an important asset class for wealthy Argentinians – are also poorly reported.

Whilst international cooperation is important, it is not the only barrier that needs to be overcome to tax the wealthy. Argentina presents a case study in how a progressive tax system can unravel in the face of high and volatile inflation, and how large swings in the tax rate due to political polarisation can limit the effectiveness of tax policy. This case study will be important for other developing and developed countries which are also often experiencing the high levels of inflation and political polarisation that Argentina has struggled with for decades.

Argentina is one of the few countries to already have a comprehensive wealth tax as advocated for by Zucman.1 The wealth tax is intended to be highly progressive, but high and volatile inflation, ranging from 20 to 40 per cent in the last 15 years, has at times brought many more people into the purview of the tax than initially intended. Figure 1 shows that the threshold to start paying wealth tax fell from 15 times GDP per capita in 2007 to 2 times GDP per capita in 2015, leading to the share of wealth tax payers increasing from 0.5 per cent to 1.9 per cent of the total population. Between 2016 and 2020, the wealth tax threshold was periodically updated, and from 2021 it was indexed to the consumer price index (CPI). This has not entirely fixed the problem, as official estimates of property values, which are a major component of the wealth tax base, are not regularly updated in Argentina. As property price growth tends to be higher than the CPI rate of inflation, a lack of revaluation means that the wealth tax falls on an ever-decreasing share of true wealth.

The story is similar for personal income taxation. As Figure 2 shows, the fraction of employees who were liable for the personal income tax grew from 10 per cent to 30 per cent in just four years between 2009 and 2013, as the tax-free allowance was fixed in nominal terms despite inflation of 20–40 per cent. This was corrected in 2014, and from 2016 the personal allowance threshold was indexed to nominal wages. However, indexation failed to stop the rise in the share of employees paying personal income tax, possibly because nominal wage growth for workers just under the threshold was faster than growth in the nominal wage index used.2

This highlights a deeper question: what is the goal of indexation for personal income taxes? One potential goal is to maintain consistency in the tax system in real terms, so an individual with a constant real wage does not experience fluctuating tax rates year-on-year due to inflation. Indexation of thresholds to the CPI is a simple way to try to achieve this. Another potential goal could be to keep the share of workers within each tax bracket constant, irrespective of the inflation rate or real wage growth, which approximately preserves the progressivity of the tax system. In that case, nominal wage indexation would be more natural. However, Argentina's experience between 2016 and 2020 shows that even nominal wage indexation may not always keep the share of workers paying personal income tax constant, if nominal wage growth varies across the wage distribution or if the measure of earnings used for indexation is partial or outdated. Since 2021, Argentina has set the threshold so that the share of workers paying personal income tax remains around 10 per cent. Although this type of ad-hoc rule may not be desirable from an optimal taxation point of view, some stability after a decade of substantial fluctuation is welcome.

Political polarisation has further complicated tax stability. Prior to 2015, the wealth tax rate was 1.25 per cent. It was reduced to 0.25 per cent by the centre-right Macri administration, only to be increased to 1.75 per cent (for domestic assets) and 2.25 per cent (for offshore assets) by the left-wing Fernández administration when it came to power in 2019. Corporate income tax followed a similar trajectory. The Macri administration reduced the corporate income tax rate from 35 per cent to 30 per cent in 2017, and had planned to reduce it further to 25 per cent, but the Fernández administration restored the rate to 35 per cent. Such drastic swings in tax policies can distort the behaviour of individuals and firms, further complicating tax design. For example, firms may not increase investment in response to a corporate tax cut, if they believe that tax rates will be higher after the next election. On the other hand, revenue from a corporate tax rate increase may fall short of expectations, if firms try to delay realising profits until the next election.

Unlike high inflation, it is harder for economists to make tax systems robust to political polarisation. However, global tax floors, such as the OECD's 15 per cent minimum corporate tax rate, may at least put some constraint on tax rates being tied to the political cycle.

Abstract Image

面对通货膨胀和不稳定的累进税:阿根廷的经验教训
加布里埃尔·祖克曼在本次研讨会上的文章为国际合作如何克服累进税和财富税的障碍提出了议程。阿根廷一直处于国际税务合作发展的前沿。它一直是全球最低税最有力的支持者之一,并通过将最低税率提高到21%或25%来推动它走得更远。阿根廷还利用自动信息交换(AEOI)来侦查离岸逃税行为,与近100个国家签署了AEOI协议。AEOI在阿根廷的表现平平。Zucman的文章指出,根据AEOI,离岸房地产是免税的,但离岸货币持有量——这是阿根廷富人的一个重要资产类别——也很少被报道。虽然国际合作很重要,但它并不是向富人征税需要克服的唯一障碍。阿根廷提供了一个案例研究,研究累进税制如何在高通胀和动荡的通货膨胀面前瓦解,以及政治两极分化导致的税率大幅波动如何限制税收政策的有效性。这一案例研究对其他发展中国家和发达国家来说很重要,这些国家也经常经历阿根廷几十年来一直在与之斗争的高通胀和政治两极分化。阿根廷是为数不多的几个已经按照祖克曼的主张制定了全面财富税的国家之一。1财富税本应具有高度累进性,但在过去15年中,高通胀率从20%到40%不等,有时会使更多的人进入该税的范围,这比最初的预期要多得多。图1显示,开始缴纳财富税的门槛从2007年的人均国内生产总值的15倍下降到2015年的人均国民生产总值的2倍,导致财富税纳税人在总人口中所占的比例从0.5%增加到1.9%。2016年至2020年间,财富税起征点定期更新,从2021年起,它与消费者价格指数(CPI)挂钩。这并没有完全解决这个问题,因为作为财富税基础主要组成部分的官方财产价值估计在阿根廷没有定期更新。由于房地产价格增长往往高于CPI通胀率,缺乏重估意味着财富税在真实财富中所占份额不断下降。个人所得税也是如此。如图2所示,在2009年至2013年的短短四年内,应缴纳个人所得税的员工比例从10%增长到30%,因为尽管通货膨胀率为20-40%,免税津贴仍按名义计算。这一点在2014年得到了纠正,从2016年起,个人津贴门槛与名义工资挂钩。然而,指数化未能阻止缴纳个人所得税的员工比例的上升,可能是因为低于门槛的工人的名义工资增长速度快于所用名义工资指数的增长速度。2这突出了一个更深层次的问题:个人所得税指数化的目标是什么?一个潜在的目标是保持税收制度的实际一致性,这样一个实际工资不变的个人就不会因为通货膨胀而经历同比波动的税率。将阈值指数化为CPI是实现这一目标的一种简单方法。另一个潜在目标可能是保持每个税阶内工人的份额不变,而不考虑通货膨胀率或实际工资增长,这大致保持了税收制度的累进性。在这种情况下,名义工资指数化将更加自然。然而,阿根廷在2016年至2020年期间的经验表明,如果名义工资增长在工资分配中有所不同,或者用于指数化的收入衡量标准是部分的或过时的,即使名义工资指数化也可能无法始终保持工人缴纳个人所得税的份额不变。自2021年以来,阿根廷设定了起征点,使缴纳个人所得税的工人比例保持在10%左右。尽管从最佳税收的角度来看,这种类型的特别规则可能不可取,但在经历了十年的大幅波动后,出现一些稳定是值得欢迎的。政治两极分化使税收稳定性进一步复杂化。2015年之前,财富税税率为1.25%。中右翼的马克里政府将其降至0.25%,但左翼的费尔南德斯政府在2019年上台时将其分别提高到1.75%(国内资产)和2.25%(海外资产)。企业所得税也遵循了类似的轨迹。2017年,马克里政府将企业所得税税率从35%降至30%,并计划进一步降至25%,但费尔南德斯政府将税率恢复至35%。 税收政策的这种剧烈波动可能会扭曲个人和企业的行为,使税收设计更加复杂。例如,如果公司认为下次选举后税率会更高,那么他们可能不会为了应对公司减税而增加投资。另一方面,如果公司试图将利润实现推迟到下次选举,那么公司税率上调带来的收入可能会低于预期。与高通胀不同,经济学家更难使税收制度对政治两极分化保持稳健。然而,全球最低税率,如经合组织15%的最低企业税率,可能至少会对与政治周期挂钩的税率施加一些限制。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
Fiscal Studies
Fiscal Studies Multiple-
CiteScore
13.50
自引率
1.40%
发文量
18
期刊介绍: The Institute for Fiscal Studies publishes the journal Fiscal Studies, which serves as a bridge between academic research and policy. This esteemed journal, established in 1979, has gained global recognition for its publication of high-quality and original research papers. The articles, authored by prominent academics, policymakers, and practitioners, are presented in an accessible format, ensuring a broad international readership.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信