Comment on “Higher Education in the United States: Laissez-Faire, Differentiation, and Research”

IF 4.5 3区 经济学 Q1 ECONOMICS
Michael Spence
{"title":"Comment on “Higher Education in the United States: Laissez-Faire, Differentiation, and Research”","authors":"Michael Spence","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12420","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>I have served as dean of the Faculty of Arts and Sciences at Harvard and as dean of the Graduate School of Business at Stanford University. As a result of these 15 years of experience in academic administration, I learned quite a lot about the history of these institutions, their competitors, and their modes of operation and financing. Urquiola's (<span>2023</span>) account of the origins and current industry configuration of American higher education is precise and accurate. Since it has evolved to be a very complex system, this is no small achievement.</p><p>A distinctive, and I would say nearly unique, feature of the American higher education complex is the relatively large size of the private sector and the fact that it operates alongside and competes with a similarly large set of public sector institutions. In most countries, the public sector dominates, and even what is sometimes called the private sector has a much larger element of public sector funding.</p><p>As a result of this unusual configuration and the fact that (excluding federal research funding) public sector institutions are largely funded at the state level, it is a highly decentralized system. Urquiola correctly makes the point that this contributes to a high degree of product differentiation across the system and probably an unusual amount of experimentation. Perhaps this is in part what Urquiola means by laissez-faire in this context. It also leads to a relatively high variation in quality.</p><p>As Urquiola documents, US higher education in the early years consisted of small, mainly local, mainly religious in origin colleges with no ability or pretense to conduct research or advance scientific and technological frontiers. This changed dramatically at the end of the 19th century when a version of the German Research University model was imported and adapted to US conditions. Johns Hopkins is widely viewed as a key early adopter and leader, with others like Harvard following quickly.</p><p>Leadership played a key role within and across institutions. Significant expansion of federal government funding for research was, and continues to be, an important enabler. Urquiola suggests that an increasingly technologically sophisticated set of industrial sectors may have provided additional impetus, and that may be true, though it is hard to document. It is important in this context, to emphasize that government funding is critical. Even the institutions with the largest endowments could not come close to funding research at the levels and costs that characterize the present system.</p><p>The development of an American version of the research university began a process of differentiation in the entire sector. A few public institutions followed with support from their states, but not all. A group of colleges decided to remain 4-year colleges, to focus on education, not compete in the research sphere, and like the elite research university, restrict their size so they became increasingly selective over time, a process that continues to the present. This has turned out to be a highly successful segment, as Urquiola (<span>2023</span>) documents.</p><p>There followed many dimensions of differentiation that are covered well in the paper: public and private institutions outside the research and elite teaching colleges and universities: 2-year colleges, locally publicly funded community colleges, and more recently private or non-profit versions of the same, focused on professional and skills training.</p><p>Let me focus on selectivity for a moment, as it is often misunderstood. Why would not institutions move to try to satisfy the “excess demand.” There are several complimentary reasons (see Urquiola, <span>2023</span>, Section 8). Learning from one's peers is one. A second is the signaling effect (a derivative of imperfect information in job markets) (Spence, <span>1974</span>). Higher education certainly adds human capital to the students, to which there is a return in employment. But the signaling effect associated with degrees from highly selective institutions adds an additional return to the investment in education at that level. A third one, perhaps more important in professional schools, but still present at the undergraduate level, is the alumni network. It is an asset that creates valuable options in the future for those who are in it.</p><p>Selectivity and an actively supported alumni network are important parts of the financial model. An active alumni network is a key ingredient in fund-raising. Since elite institutions are expensive places to attend, that funding permits, among other things, a scholarship system that frees the admissions process to some extent from the constraint of “ability to pay,” which in turn expands the merit pool.</p><p>The development of the highly selective model led to an expansion of the target population. Early on, colleges served largely local markets. Now, the major research institutions, especially the private ones, serve a fully nationwide market with a significant additional component consisting of international students. That transition, to be able to recruit and evaluate on a national and international scale, required a major additional commitment of resources.</p><p>Selectivity is highest on the private sector side of the system. It is much more difficult to justify high degrees of selectivity when one is deploying public funds. And there are continuing contentious issues about the criteria to be used in selecting.</p><p>The federal research funding mechanisms are highly competitive, and generally, the screening is carried out by experts and is of high quality. This is not to say there are no biases in the direction of conventional wisdom or problems funding completely new lines of inquiry. But it is critical that the funding agencies do not directly fund universities. The funding goes to scientists who compete for funding. Provisions are made to help cover “overhead” costs that universities incur. In many countries, research funding goes to the institutions and then gets allocated to principal investigators, giving rise to additional layers in allocating resources and quality slippage.</p><p>The modern version of the US system has produced many internationally recognized research universities (public and private) and important research output along with highly trained scientific human capital. Whether it has served the broader population and the country well is more complex. It is on average, for the students and their families, an expensive system. And the real costs keep rising rapidly. Student debt, in excess of the value added in some segments, is also a persistent problem.</p><p>Urquiola (<span>2023</span>) is a valuable contribution, especially for readers whose experience is largely in state dominated systems (the normal case internationally). It very effectively captures the essential and somewhat unusual features of the US higher education sector.</p>","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":"18 2","pages":"217-219"},"PeriodicalIF":4.5000,"publicationDate":"2023-03-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12420","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Asian Economic Policy Review","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/aepr.12420","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

I have served as dean of the Faculty of Arts and Sciences at Harvard and as dean of the Graduate School of Business at Stanford University. As a result of these 15 years of experience in academic administration, I learned quite a lot about the history of these institutions, their competitors, and their modes of operation and financing. Urquiola's (2023) account of the origins and current industry configuration of American higher education is precise and accurate. Since it has evolved to be a very complex system, this is no small achievement.

A distinctive, and I would say nearly unique, feature of the American higher education complex is the relatively large size of the private sector and the fact that it operates alongside and competes with a similarly large set of public sector institutions. In most countries, the public sector dominates, and even what is sometimes called the private sector has a much larger element of public sector funding.

As a result of this unusual configuration and the fact that (excluding federal research funding) public sector institutions are largely funded at the state level, it is a highly decentralized system. Urquiola correctly makes the point that this contributes to a high degree of product differentiation across the system and probably an unusual amount of experimentation. Perhaps this is in part what Urquiola means by laissez-faire in this context. It also leads to a relatively high variation in quality.

As Urquiola documents, US higher education in the early years consisted of small, mainly local, mainly religious in origin colleges with no ability or pretense to conduct research or advance scientific and technological frontiers. This changed dramatically at the end of the 19th century when a version of the German Research University model was imported and adapted to US conditions. Johns Hopkins is widely viewed as a key early adopter and leader, with others like Harvard following quickly.

Leadership played a key role within and across institutions. Significant expansion of federal government funding for research was, and continues to be, an important enabler. Urquiola suggests that an increasingly technologically sophisticated set of industrial sectors may have provided additional impetus, and that may be true, though it is hard to document. It is important in this context, to emphasize that government funding is critical. Even the institutions with the largest endowments could not come close to funding research at the levels and costs that characterize the present system.

The development of an American version of the research university began a process of differentiation in the entire sector. A few public institutions followed with support from their states, but not all. A group of colleges decided to remain 4-year colleges, to focus on education, not compete in the research sphere, and like the elite research university, restrict their size so they became increasingly selective over time, a process that continues to the present. This has turned out to be a highly successful segment, as Urquiola (2023) documents.

There followed many dimensions of differentiation that are covered well in the paper: public and private institutions outside the research and elite teaching colleges and universities: 2-year colleges, locally publicly funded community colleges, and more recently private or non-profit versions of the same, focused on professional and skills training.

Let me focus on selectivity for a moment, as it is often misunderstood. Why would not institutions move to try to satisfy the “excess demand.” There are several complimentary reasons (see Urquiola, 2023, Section 8). Learning from one's peers is one. A second is the signaling effect (a derivative of imperfect information in job markets) (Spence, 1974). Higher education certainly adds human capital to the students, to which there is a return in employment. But the signaling effect associated with degrees from highly selective institutions adds an additional return to the investment in education at that level. A third one, perhaps more important in professional schools, but still present at the undergraduate level, is the alumni network. It is an asset that creates valuable options in the future for those who are in it.

Selectivity and an actively supported alumni network are important parts of the financial model. An active alumni network is a key ingredient in fund-raising. Since elite institutions are expensive places to attend, that funding permits, among other things, a scholarship system that frees the admissions process to some extent from the constraint of “ability to pay,” which in turn expands the merit pool.

The development of the highly selective model led to an expansion of the target population. Early on, colleges served largely local markets. Now, the major research institutions, especially the private ones, serve a fully nationwide market with a significant additional component consisting of international students. That transition, to be able to recruit and evaluate on a national and international scale, required a major additional commitment of resources.

Selectivity is highest on the private sector side of the system. It is much more difficult to justify high degrees of selectivity when one is deploying public funds. And there are continuing contentious issues about the criteria to be used in selecting.

The federal research funding mechanisms are highly competitive, and generally, the screening is carried out by experts and is of high quality. This is not to say there are no biases in the direction of conventional wisdom or problems funding completely new lines of inquiry. But it is critical that the funding agencies do not directly fund universities. The funding goes to scientists who compete for funding. Provisions are made to help cover “overhead” costs that universities incur. In many countries, research funding goes to the institutions and then gets allocated to principal investigators, giving rise to additional layers in allocating resources and quality slippage.

The modern version of the US system has produced many internationally recognized research universities (public and private) and important research output along with highly trained scientific human capital. Whether it has served the broader population and the country well is more complex. It is on average, for the students and their families, an expensive system. And the real costs keep rising rapidly. Student debt, in excess of the value added in some segments, is also a persistent problem.

Urquiola (2023) is a valuable contribution, especially for readers whose experience is largely in state dominated systems (the normal case internationally). It very effectively captures the essential and somewhat unusual features of the US higher education sector.

评《美国高等教育:公平、分化与研究》
现在,主要的研究机构,尤其是私立研究机构,服务于一个由国际学生组成的全国性市场。为了能够在国家和国际范围内进行征聘和评估,这一过渡需要大量额外的资源投入。私营部门的选择性最高。在部署公共资金时,要证明高度选择性的合理性要困难得多。关于选择的标准,仍存在争议。联邦研究资助机制竞争激烈,通常情况下,筛查由专家进行,质量高。这并不是说在传统智慧的方向上没有偏见,也不是说在资助全新的调查领域方面没有问题。但至关重要的是,资助机构不能直接资助大学。这笔资金流向了争夺资金的科学家。提供经费是为了帮助支付大学产生的“间接费用”。在许多国家,研究资金流向机构,然后分配给主要研究人员,这导致了资源分配的额外层次和质量下滑。现代美国体制产生了许多国际公认的研究型大学(公立和私立)和重要的研究成果,以及训练有素的科学人力资本。它是否能很好地为广大民众和国家服务,则更为复杂。对于学生和他们的家庭来说,这是一个昂贵的系统。实际成本持续快速上升。学生债务超过了某些领域的附加值,也是一个持续存在的问题。Urquiola(2023)是一个有价值的贡献,尤其是对于那些经验主要在国家主导的系统中(国际上的正常情况)的读者来说。它非常有效地捕捉到了美国高等教育部门的基本特征和一些不同寻常的特征。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
CiteScore
12.90
自引率
2.60%
发文量
39
期刊介绍: The goal of the Asian Economic Policy Review is to become an intellectual voice on the current issues of international economics and economic policy, based on comprehensive and in-depth analyses, with a primary focus on Asia. Emphasis is placed on identifying key issues at the time - spanning international trade, international finance, the environment, energy, the integration of regional economies and other issues - in order to furnish ideas and proposals to contribute positively to the policy debate in the region.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信