What role for aid in countries with and without a development bargain?

IF 2 3区 经济学 Q2 DEVELOPMENT STUDIES
{"title":"What role for aid in countries with and without a development bargain?","authors":"","doi":"10.1111/dpr.12701","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>\n <b>Contents</b>\n </p><p>1. Introduction – Annalisa Prizzon and Steve Wiggins</p><p>2. What role for aid in countries with and without a “development bargain”? – Stefan Dercon</p><p>3. Donors are already part of the development bargain—for better or, often, for worse – Naomi Hossain</p><p>4. Development co-operation can help with the first steps, but it is the national government that makes the development journey – Liang Ma</p><p>5. Which elite bargain drives development assistance? – Arkebe Oqubay</p><p>6. Development actors cannot help form development bargains – Rathin Roy</p><p>7. Development partners need to support external grand struggles – Hannah Ryder</p><p>8. Aid and the development bargain: What should development partners do? – Kunal Sen</p><p>9. Latin America and the Caribbean and the urgency of building a development agenda – Carolina Trivelli</p><p>10. Rejoinder – Stefan Dercon</p><p>\n <i>Annalisa Prizzon, Principal Research Fellow, ODI and Steve Wiggins, Principal Research Fellow, ODI – editors, Development Policy Review</i>\n </p><p>Foreign aid is meant to support economic growth and development in the global South. But what drives development? Debate over key ingredients is as old as development co-operation itself, with thinking going back to the late 1940s. Early thinkers stressed capital investment; later, attention turned to structural factors, such as land reform; by 1980 the Washington Consensus had formed, emphasizing free trade and strong macroeconomic management. In the early 2000s, the spotlight then fell back on economic growth, in appreciation of its several, complicated, and frankly elusive determinants. As ideas about the drivers of development have changed, so have ideas about the role of aid.</p><p>In his 2022 book, <b><i>Gambling on development</i>,</b> Stefan Dercon compares country experiences, arguing that countries develop strongly when their leaders and elites reach a shared vision for their country's development, and bet on its success—though the outcome cannot be guaranteed. This vision and its implementation he dubs a “development bargain.” What matters for development is national leadership, politics, and policies. But if domestic matters are crucial, what is the role of outsiders?</p><p>Professor Dercon—as a scholar and former senior adviser in the erstwhile UK Department for International Development—brings a rare perspective to the question of why and how development happens, and the role aid can play. But aid is not central to his argument, the core of which concerns domestic leadership and politics. This is not necessarily the most welcome message for those concerned with directing foreign aid, which is subject to increasing scepticism, with persistent threats to cut budgets.</p><p>We posed two questions to Dercon. If aid works best where development bargains have been struck, what should aid do in such cases? More importantly, what should aid do in countries that lack a development bargain?</p><p>In his answer, Stefan recommends development partners accept a smaller role than they may feel they warrant. Aid should be complementary to, and supportive of, national policies when a development bargain has formed or is emerging.</p><p>When elites fail to reach a shared vision for growth and development—they may share other visions, for example, of power and self-enrichment—the role of development partners becomes more difficult. Globally, development partners should try to set incentives for better elite bargains, while deterring bargains that do not lead to growth and development. Examples are setting extensive trade preferences and fighting illicit finance. Within countries lacking a development bargain, development partners may need to be less ambitious, prioritizing the needs of the most deprived citizens, rather than imagining that aid alone can stimulate development.</p><p>We asked seven distinguished scholars and practitioners from the global South to answer the same questions Stefan was asked, and to respond to his propositions. They were, in alphabetical order, Naomi Hossain, Ma Liang, Arkebe Oqubay, Rathin Roy, Hannah Ryder, Kunal Sen and Carolina Trivelli.</p><p>Most were sympathetic to Dercon's argument: they agreed that development will only be achieved if some domestic compact is in place. Some took it a stage further: development partners need to recognize that they are political players; and, in some cases, donor interests will be antithetical to those of the country they purport to assist. One respondent pointed out the wider framing: the road to a domestic development bargain begins with, or began with, a struggle against colonialism and its continuing echoes. Development bargains may be internal, but they may have to be formed in the teeth of pressures to conform to international norms.</p><p>But read on: to appreciate the arguments you need to read the individual contributions—they are short—and Professor Dercon's reply. As ever, the views constitute a debate, one that still leaves several important questions that will not be answered readily or quickly; above all that of how a development bargain can be identified in its infancy.</p><p><i>Stefan Dercon, Professor of Economic Policy at the Blavatnik School of Government and the Economics Department, University of Oxford, and Director of the Centre for the Study of African Economies</i>.</p><p>ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4496-1623</p><p>My book <b><i>Gambling on development: Why some countries win and others lose</i></b> is not about aid or international development actors. There are 13 chapters and only from chapter 11 are aid or these actors seriously mentioned. There is a good reason for this. The role of international development actors in the success or failure of countries in growth and development is just a bitpart, and they do not have a key starring role, despite attempts to present it otherwise.</p><p>My book is about how some countries managed to grow their economies with broad-based development, starting from low GDP per capita levels in the last three to four decades. Not Singapore-level growth rates or perfectly inclusive growth—but rather growth of at least 4% to 5% per year, a serious reduction in poverty and, generally, a sense of development progress. Examples include countries like China, Indonesia, India, Bangladesh, Ghana, Ethiopia, and Rwanda. Each did it in its own way: the specific set of policies were different, political systems were not alike, and they definitely did not do it starting from <b><i>Why nations fail</i></b>-style perfect institutions, but rather with a lot of imperfection and much unfinished business.</p><p>My core argument is that these countries had a specific elite bargain—an implicit “deal” involving those with power or influence in politics, business, military, civil service, even civil society and media—in which growth and development played a central role. Not just in words, but in actions and behaviour that meant politics valued peace and stability in the economy and the state. It involved a state that was self-aware enough to take on what it could, but not more, given its own context and capability, and whereby there was a political and bureaucratic learning and accountability culture so that there were course corrections possible. I call this type of elite bargain a development bargain.</p><p>Such an elite bargain for growth and development is required for progress—there is no way around this. However, for those with power, it is a gamble, as success is not guaranteed, and incumbents may lose, as happened over time to Suharto in Indonesia, or it may tear apart elite bargains as in Ethiopia. And don't take for granted that it exists everywhere: the game in town for the elite in Nigeria or DRC for example is not growth and development — they are examples of failing countries.</p><p>Aid and development partners are not centre stage in any of the examples discussed, and they do not warrant top billing in the show. Still, with their influence in the media and research communities in donor countries, non-governmental organizations, multilateral banks, or the UN see themselves as the headline acts. This is not very helpful—more humility and awareness of the real importance of their role is required.</p><p>It does not mean that development partners are irrelevant. In places where a development bargain is present or emerging, aid can play a hugely helpful <i>complementary</i> role in supporting the direction this society and economy is taking, with aid, with technical support and, yes, with critical advocacy to deepen and strengthen the development bargain. Ghana and Bangladesh are countries where this role has been possible, given the nature of the state and the development bargain.</p><p>When a development bargain does not exist, caution is required. Then, objectives of (well-meaning) donors are not aligned with those of people with power and influence in the countries. It is then crucial to think through the incentives created by outside support as regards the nature of the political deal involved. Many official development partners love to hide behind their “apolitical” nature. Their political analysis of countries is usually lacking a sense of longer-term history and politics, and the underlying social and political contract. The key issue is that, however these outsiders act in trying to contribute to “development,” they will influence not just outcomes for people, but also the underlying incentives in the elite bargain.</p><p>If done well, development partners' actions may improve outcomes for the population, but also create conditions for a better elite bargain to emerge and be sustained. However, it is also perfectly possible that doing seemingly “good” may embed a bad elite bargain, giving excuses not to act on growth or development. Indeed, as discussed in the book, over time I have become worried about how, in countries like Malawi or Nigeria, aid and development partners may well make circumstances worse, by making it too easy for political actors to ignore the need for change as development partners compensate for their failure to deliver progress for the population, or how, in South Sudan, humanitarian aid may even help to embed the conflict.</p><p>So…what to do? First, globally, try to set incentives for better elite bargains to be successful while undermining rogue elite bargains. For example, a focus on exports outside natural resources is often a sign of a commitment to growth, as it is really hard to do with the usual shenanigans of business connected to rent-seeking elites. Hence, offering extensive trade preferences rarely rewards poor elite bargains but typically encourages decent ones. Similarly, seriously fighting illicit finance, that key instrument of financing rogue elite bargains, would be really helpful to shift the incentives, too.</p><p>What to do within countries? This is the hardest. Surely there are plenty of needs—anti-developmental elite bargains, such as in the DRC, Nigeria, or Madagascar coincide with huge deprivation. So doing “good” by helping those suffering is an honourable objective. However, all I am asking is that this be done with one's eyes wide open, conscious of what large-scale outside engagement does for the incentives in these countries to become more developmental. And not label all such efforts as “development” but as at best trying to do “good”—and, of course, still using the best evidence on how to have most impact in these often dysfunctional settings.</p><p>And then, based on deep knowledge, maybe some can do more, carefully, and maybe by stealth. It could involve working with those within elites who are up for change. Or working with technocrats in central banks or ministries that want growth and development. It may mean working with political leaders and public intellectuals to contribute to crafting new narratives to reset the direction of a country. Or strengthening those in business who would benefit from growth and broad-based development. It may involve supporting civil society in calling for transparency, better governance, or, indeed, rights.</p><p>I for one do not want to give up yet and I still think that outside development actors can contribute to change—even though much is wrong with the incentives inside the development system, such as pressure to be seen to deliver quick results or a narrow focus on finance, which tend to stymie change. And, as we are talking about what outsiders can do, they had better show both humility and self-awareness that, when outsiders act, they are not necessarily making matters better.</p><p><i>Naomi Hossain, Accountability Research Center, American University, Washington DC</i>.</p><p>ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-3244-2319</p><p>\n <b>“Should development partners help form development bargains, and if so, how?”</b>\n </p><p>This question, like Stefan's book, speaks to a gentler and more optimistic era of development aid. It assumes that aid donors are good faith actors with interests in reducing poverty and promoting inclusive and sustainable growth, peace, and prosperity for all. Many of us have worked with those assumptions for the 20-odd years since the Cold War ended. But it is not clear that those assumptions still hold—if they ever did. Certainly, the UK government department formerly known as the Department for International Development (DFID) was a moderately progressive aid donor; it could potentially have supported the formation of pro-poor political bargains in the countries in which it had influence. But in its current form, on life-support at the tail-end of a post-Brexit far-right Conservative government, the UK's Foreign, Commonwealth &amp; Development Office (FCDO) is focused chiefly on making the world profitable for UK business, a fact about which it makes no bones.</p><p>So the answer is no. Aid donors like the UK should not be in the business of forming development bargains. There is no reason to believe those bargains will be in the interests of anyone but those with elite connections. The antics of the British party of government in the past few years have in any case left the UK without credibility as a champion of good governance in the eyes of the global South. Stefan notes that tackling impunity is crucial for enabling enduring development bargains to emerge, as it makes it harder for corrupt elites to get away with their illicit spoils. Yet the UK continues to protect tax havens and financial sector secrecy in ways that are designed to shield elites from being held accountable for corruption. How can they possibly set an example?</p><p>However, aid donors do deserve to be treated as political actors in the development bargains of development countries. This is not because they <i>should</i> be getting involved, but because they already always are<i>. <b>Gambling on development</b></i> pays too little attention to donors as political actors, treating them as though capable of intervening in politics cleanly from above without adverse consequences or messy side-effects. Stefan would have done well to include the insights of the Effective States and Inclusive Development research programme at the University of Manchester,1 which showed how donors shaped political economy across settings. Donors are already part of any development bargains, and when bargains fail to deliver inclusive development, donors should shoulder some of the blame. In short, donors should not actively help form development bargains because there is always the risk they may interfere—catastrophically—in the politics of other countries but we should be more alert to the fact that donors are already involved in the politics of development.</p><p>\n <b>“What should they do in circumstances when such bargains are absent and unlikely to form in the short run?”</b>\n </p><p>Donors should put their hands in their pockets and find the money needed for climate change adaptation, mitigation, and social protection. They should provide the humanitarian aid that is increasingly needed, and they should provide for the world's growing number of refugees and asylum-seekers. They should do these things anyway, regardless of whether or not development bargains are present. People in the global South are owed at least that by the countries that industrialized and pumped carbon into the atmosphere on their own pathways to development, and colonized and robbed, before more recently interfering in domestic politics in their quests for foreign policy influence and power.</p><p>But it is also the case that no development is possible under conditions of chronic crisis and subsistence failure. People must be able to live without fearing the next attack or storm or famine before they can take advantage of any opportunities afforded by open markets. The development bargains that feature in <b><i>Gambling on development</i></b> were often the fruits of investment in basic human security rather than deliberate shifts towards market-driven growth. Most of the cases that Stefan describes so well in his book are instances where elites only arrived at a consensus about development after disasters made business-as-usual unthinkable. War, famine, disasters, and genocide feature prominently, and in each case proved to be the turning point. At such turning points, the lessons in <b><i>Gambling on development</i></b> suggest that aid donors can either be helpful by supporting humanitarian efforts or they can get out of the way.</p><p>\n <i>Liang Ma, Renmin University of China</i>\n </p><p>ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-8779-5891</p><p>Countries can benefit from development aid, but development aid should not influence national policy choices. Development assistance is not value free. It is usually accompanied by the strong ideological preferences of development partners, and these might not suit local situations in developing countries. One-size-fits-all development co-operation programmes cannot address the key challenges faced by developing countries, not to mention help them escape the poverty trap. Countries differ in many important aspects. Development programmes should be country specific, which means those offered by development partners cannot be a panacea for all. It is much more important to do the right things than to do things right, and development partners should be conscious of their roles and boundaries.</p><p>Developing countries usually cannot resist or afford to ignore the conditions required by international organizations on development assistance. Post-colonial countries in particular are rarely self-confident in holding to the development paths with their own characteristics and can often be trapped by development partners' recommendations. Strong nationalism can further distort elite bargaining by leading to citizens labelling development aid as unpatriotic, which can impact relations with development partners.</p><p>China learned much from the Soviet Union following the establishment in 1949 of the People's Republic of China, but some of these lessons were painful. Experts from the Soviet Union helped China build its industrial infrastructure. China's overreliance on the Soviet Union saw its industrial structure lean disproportionately towards heavy industry, and the central planning regime jeopardized its economy by stifling local improvisation. By binding its future to the Soviet Union, China was losing its economic sovereignty.</p><p>China's remarkable growth after the Reform and Opening-up in the late 1970s could be attributed to smart learning from the West. The government learned from Western countries, but kept Chinese style as the ruling principle. For instance, China learned from international practices about administrative reforms (e.g., one-stop services), but approached them with domestic considerations. In some situations, the government declined advice, mainly in the fields of financial development and regulation. In effect, the government worked as a smart shopper to introduce Western practices and to combine them with Chinese ones, producing a novel development state with Chinese characteristics.</p><p>What can we learn from the Chinese experience? Development assistance should not be overemphasized. It is governments themselves that should develop effective policies to boost national development. In other words, development partners can give advice and recommendations, but it is the domestic elites who collectively make decisions crucial for themselves and national development. China's merit lies in its incremental trial-and-error approach, which gave the elites confidence to support development.</p><p>It is very important to calibrate and highlight the boundaries between development partners and domestic elites. Development partners can work as consultants or knowledge brokers to inspire and enlighten national government decision-makers with best practices and evidence, but they should not get deeply involved. They come and leave, but it is national government that makes the development journey.</p><p>Some countries may not develop elite bargains essential to sustainable development. In such cases development partners can help to some extent. To convince elites, used to reaping short-term profits, of the long-term benefits of development is challenging, so development partners must develop more effective approaches to elicit development bargains. For instance, development partners can help by investing in concrete programmes, but their operations may not be sustained if and when they leave. Instead, pilot programmes with convincing demonstrations and achievements may help reshape elites' attitudes towards development, and bargains would be kick-started.</p><p>Development partners should return to the essential meaning of development. Go to the nature of development, it is more about economic and social aspects than political ones. Without indigenous development paths embedded in the local development community, countries do not develop in a sustainable way. As the saying has it, teaching people how to fish is more important than giving them fish.</p><p>Previously North–South development assistance and policy transfer mattered, but with the emerging of China and other economies, a South–South model has been playing an ever more important role. China's leading role in the Belt and Road Initiative (BRI) is different from most other development assistance. It has vividly shown how development partners can help in elite bargains. Focusing on and providing what developing countries really want (e.g., infrastructure, agriculture, and affordable financing), BRI is positioning itself to be fruitful for future development assistance.</p><p>China benefitted and learned from development assistance, and it has developed its own version of development aid to help other developing countries. China's experience, like all development aid, might not be universally applicable. The spirit of its development assistance, however, could be transferred to other contexts.</p><p><i>Arkebe Oqubay, British Academy Global Professor and Professor of Practice at SOAS University of London, Senior Minister</i>.2</p><p>In this context, there is new pressure to rethink approaches to international development. Dercon's book is a valuable contribution to thinking about aid and, more broadly, the political economy of development. Given his stature and experience, his views on the inherent flaws in development assistance will carry much weight in donor circles.</p><p>As a senior policy-maker in Ethiopia for over three decades, I worked with—and closely observed—development partners and the mechanics of development assistance during a period when Ethiopia sustained rates of economic growth of 10% and above for more than 15 years, and when average life expectancy rose by 22 years from 1991 to 2016. Ethiopia's development model assigned a leading role to the developmental state. A clear degree and exercise of policy ownership earned it both keen interest from other African countries and sharp criticism from mainstream media and some influential persons within international development circles.</p><p>I must confess my belief that development assistance plays a secondary role in economic development. The relationship is always shaped by political tensions, where its positive contribution results primarily from the recipient government's development strategy and policies. In this, I very much agree with Dercon's argument that official development assistance plays, at best, a “bit part” in the drama of development. Imposing long lists of conditionalities and flooding a developing country with the helpful advice of international consultants have not proved a recipe for long-term sustained growth and economic transformation.</p><p>The Ethiopian government resisted donor pressure, conditionalities, and interference in internal politics, often on very sensible grounds, as I repeatedly witnessed from the early 1990s onwards. Joseph Stiglitz's description of the pressure exerted by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to liberalize Ethiopia's banking industry (Stiglitz, <span>2001</span>); and the World Bank's unwarranted engagement in the negotiation of the geopolitically contentious Grand Ethiopian Renaissance Dam (GERD) on the Nile, Africa's largest hydropower dam during the Trump administration, are telling examples (van Eyssen, <span>2020</span>). There are also positive examples that contributed to economic transformation, including: Japan's support for the Industrial Policy Dialogue; the German programme for reform of university, vocational, and technical education; UK assistance for investment promotion and industrialization; and US support for rural primary health. However, the key was that the government was squarely in the driving seat for each of these reforms.</p><p>Yet donors' ideas and priorities are often not aligned with developing countries' long-term development strategies, policies, and priorities. Resources are committed annually, making it difficult to rely upon them for long-term investment, especially when donors often change their “flavour of the month” preferences. The very idea of a “development bargain” may well have a turn on the catwalk before going out of fashion, rather like Growth Diagnostics, the “good governance agenda,” and indeed the Washington Consensus before it. Development assistance also fluctuates depending on the changing domestic politics of the donor country. Whatever the rhetoric of “partnership,” donor governments typically make aid decisions unilaterally, underscoring a fundamental power asymmetry. Aid often risks fundamentally derailing development trajectories, as was seen in the damage done by Washington Consensus policies pushed on African countries and (often with eager supporters within these countries, it must be said) dismantling the apparatus of state and industrial policy.</p><p>The aid relationship is also often shaped by an incessant ideological barrage orchestrated by sophisticated mainstream media, bureaucracy, consultancy, and influential policy intellectuals. Stefan Dercon's recommendations on how donors can influence elite bargains risks being patronizing, implicitly assuming that donors have the right ideas so that it is just a matter of how best to tweak the “bargain” among interest groups in a developing country so the latter absorb these ideas, and the aid that comes with them, more smoothly.</p><p>The same barrage of conventional wisdom (radical “shock therapy” deregulation and liberalization) was a powerful feature of much engagement with China from the mid-1970s, as it was in the wake of the collapse, later, of the Soviet Union. Isabella Weber's book <b><i>How China escaped shock therapy</i></b> shows how China's reforms would have failed had China followed the wisdom of much international advice. My point is that it cannot be assumed that the conventional wisdom—whatever that may be at any given time—among the donors is best suited to the needs of various developing countries, which need to form their own policy ideas and to nurture their own decision-making capabilities. Policy independence is, first and foremost, the freedom to experiment and learn from success and failure.</p><p>Moving beyond the “aid relationship,” Dercon's book is an important discussion of concepts that have risen to the forefront of thinking about development transformations in recent years. He is quite right to highlight the concept of an “elite bargain” or “political settlement” as key to patterns of economic growth—ideas developed especially by Mushtaq Khan, Jonathan Di John, and James Putzel among others. He is also right to defy the popular view that a specific set of institutions constitutes a precondition for growth. Here, he follows the much earlier insights of Albert Hirschman as well as more recent thinkers such as Ha-Joon Chang. It helps that he popularizes this thinking, but his approach nonetheless raises questions.</p><p>The selected country cases are based on loose criteria—such as modest growth of 4% to 5% a year and a functioning political bargain—which raises questions about whether countries with divergent political economies and development paths (such as China and Bangladesh, Ghana and Ethiopia, India and Rwanda) can be lumped into the same basket. The distinctions between these economies matter more than any shared similarity. What economic policies did these countries use for economic catch-up and transformation? What developmental role did the state play? In what ways did they “get prices wrong” rather than following advice to “get prices right”? What type of partnerships characterized the relations between governments, the private sector, the scientific community, and broader society? And, if a pro-growth “bargain” among elites did emerge, then how and why? In my own country's experience, this had virtually nothing to do with external donors. Indeed, there may be a host of unintended consequences and “butterfly effects” resulting from donor attempts to shape political settlements.</p><p>In <b><i>African economic development: Evidence, theory, policy</i></b> (Cramer et al., 2020), I and my fellow authors, Christopher Cramer and John Sender, argue for the centrality of understanding the drivers of unevenness and variations as a source of learning for development. A country's prospects for economic development, we insist, are determined by what a country <i>does</i> and what it becomes as a result of this, rather than by what it <i>has</i> and <i>is</i>—which may include some black box “bargain” that is usually difficult to identify other than after the event.</p><p><b><i>Gambling on development</i></b> will stimulate productive debates on conceptual issues and practical development challenges, and I congratulate Stefan for his contribution. It should help to move discussion and understanding forward.</p><p>\n <i>Rathin Roy, Managing Director, ODI</i>\n </p><p>Stefan Dercon's important narrative allows us to transition to a more symmetric reflection on the political economy of development co-operation.</p><p>Dercon's central premise is that domestic elites matter and that their political compact, reflected in the actions of a dirigiste state, impacts the success or failure of development initiatives. Although his focus is on the efficacy of external interventions, this thesis stands independently. Equally, his eloquent excoriation of external development actors for claiming credit for development successes and their alleged “apolitical” basis for recommending interventions resonates with the discourse on development imperialism in the global South, a line of political economy critique applied to aid, structural adjustment, and most recently the climate discourse.</p><p>The questions that the editors pose: “If aid works best where development bargains have been struck, what should aid do in such cases? More importantly, what should aid do in countries that lack a development bargain?” fail the Dercon test if taken literally; they are profoundly apolitical. So, I offer a political economy response, to both the long- and short-term questions. From this vantage point the temporal dimension is not directly relevant.</p><p>Development actors cannot help form development bargains. Superficially, it may appear that they can; preferential trading arrangements may have helped Bangladesh develop the garment industry that set it on the road to prosperity. But this would ignore a central tenet of Dercon's thesis—that external actors can act only in a way that is <i>complementary</i> to the national effort. Despite having a common history, being plagued by military interference, and having elites with similar, even common, roots, why did Bangladesh do what Pakistan could not—foster a global garments industry, create domestic finance institutions, and improve human development outcomes?</p><p>It is notable that in many of the success stories that Dercon highlights—India, Bangladesh, Vietnam, China, Rwanda—the elites made economic, political, and social policy choices that were not aimed at “development” but rather at fostering economic nationalism to counter a current or recent existential threat—colonialism, partition, genocide. These choices are not central to a development thesis, but aimed at preventing recolonization, surviving secession, avoiding a repeat of opium hegemony, preserving a unification won by contesting a superpower. The elite bargain was to rule legitimately by executing these anti-hegemonic choices, which motivated economic policy for many years after the trigger event. India, China, and Vietnam did not even <i>mention</i> ending poverty as a tenet of their development and planning strategies for many years after embarking on their development journey. The transformation imperative intersected with development imperatives in that it was tied to a project of economic modernization that enabled many of these countries to leapfrog levels of dependence—but not stages of development.</p><p>For external actors who engage, for reasons of ideological affinity or mutual interest, these bargains can deliver significant value, as in South Korea and Rwanda. Otherwise, they were simply irrelevant. The contempt with which a poor country like India was held by many Western powers for investing in “above its paygrade science and technology” reflected an absence of understanding of the logic of doing so. Similarly, the dismissal of Mao as a development failure led countries to underestimate and misunderstand the ideological transition following Deng and, therefore, caused complete bafflement when Xi Jinping Thought manifested itself at the centre of Chinese development policy—the underlying unity from a political economy perspective was easy to see, but apolitical development studies was not equipped to see it.</p><p>But, often, elites are interested solely in maximization of rents from ownership or capture of the state, with stability payments—and investments in coercive repression—made to those who threaten to undermine this process. This, unfortunately, describes a rather large group of countries, with both stable and unstable low-level equilibrium. Interestingly, this is not confined to developing and emerging economies. Developed countries, too, have struck such bargains. What else is much of the welfare state if not an exposition of the second theorem of welfare economics in the form of stability payments to compensate for a fundamentally unequalizing economic process, when public services, equity, and collective prosperity have all atrophied or declined over the long term? In this case there is no bargain to be had because external and internal actors are indifferent to the greater good. Nowhere is this better played out than in the United Kingdom and France, where the compacts between domestic elites and oligarchs, dictators, and money launderers from coercive and failed states are demonstrably more effective than taxpayer-funded interventions. So, in the short and long term, the domestic political economy of both sides of the development bargain matters.</p><p>\n <i>Hannah Ryder, CEO, Development Reimagined</i>\n </p><p>Having worked in the development field for over 20 years, sat in similar ministerial meetings to those Stefan Dercon eloquently and entertainingly describes in <b><i>Gambling on development</i>,</b> I have been consistently struck by the lack of “humility and self-awareness” of development partners that Dercon calls for.</p><p>Professor Dercon is right do so. His dual concerns, that development actors—both local and international—are too eager to find panaceas for development, as well as being too keen to claim results from their own interventions—often designed with little input from recipient countries and actors—are both well-stated and well-founded.</p><p>His critiques at the beginning of his book of the various development theories put forward by others—from Jeff Sachs to Dambisa Moyo to Acemoglu and Robinson—are also cogent.</p><p>That said, while Dercon is at pains to explain that his “grand bargain” theory is no “one-size-fits-all” solution because, by definition, it must be adapted to the situation of each elite and each country, it is nevertheless a new theory. And it thus deserves as much interrogation as the other theories he evaluates.</p><p>Dercon's ideas, and those of the other international development superstars he reviews, suffer from a similar omission. They all exclude from their narratives—consciously or not—imperial history in the form of slavery and then colonialism. As a result, their theories—including Dercon's—are incomplete.</p><p>Let me explain.</p><p>For almost all the countries mentioned in this book, Professor Dercon starts his account soon after colonialism and decades after slavery. For instance, his story of Indonesia begins in 1945 when it finally won in its struggle for (Dercon writes “declared”) independence from the Netherlands. Dercon refers to Ethiopia's successful resistance against Italians, though a few sentences later suggests the early Ethiopian state was “colonial.” He does also refer to Belgium's colonization of Congo, but later suggests Congo could have been seen as a “<i>colonial development success</i>.” With these references, he brushes off the gross human rights violations and lasting effects of economic imperialism associated with European colonialism and the slave trade—a point I will return to.</p><p>Part of the problem is the limited range of literature Professor Dercon and the other leading development thinkers rely on for their analysis. Dercon refers to one helpful text in this regard, Yuen Yuen Ang's <b><i>How China escaped the poverty trap</i>.</b> Although Professor Dercon's interpretation of Ang's perspectives on China's development history is somewhat limited, he at least gives it some well-deserved attention. But there are other equally important texts. Walter Rodney's <b><i>How Europe underdeveloped Africa</i></b>, Edward Said's <b><i>Orientalism</i></b>, Eric Beinhocker's <b><i>The Origin of Wealth</i></b>, Howard French's <b><i>Born in Blackness</i></b>, Victor Bulmer-Thomas' <b><i>From Slavery to Services</i></b>, and Susan William's <b><i>White Malice</i></b> might not be seen as a traditional development economics texts, but they fall into the same broader yet essential reading list as Ang. These texts directly and frankly tackle the global, complex, and difficult histories of the same countries that Dercon considers, while also setting their interpretations over a longer period.</p><p>Why? History, long-run history, matters because it forms the states and the very elites that Professor Dercon hopes will strike development deals.</p><p>While Dercon suggests Nkrumah was a better political strategist than an economist, Nkrumah was explaining in no uncertain terms the deep economic challenges his own country and the rest of Africa were facing.</p><p>The fact is, for the vast majority of countries, the question of a grand bargain is less about a</p><p>grand bargain <i>within a</i> country, it is more about a bargain with international partners. Or rather, a grand struggle.</p><p>Taking a longer view, all the “successes” and “failures” of the grand bargains Dercon cites are fundamentally united over whether or not they were able to remove the shackles of colonial—often extractive—patterns of international trade and investment. For example, China's success in “going out” from 1978 onwards was not just about “inviting in” foreign direct investment, it was about having the confidence to force foreign investors to bow to its rules. Such policies—as well as several by India, Ethiopia, and other countries Dercon reviews—were at the time, and even now, seen as directly oppositional to the interests of their donors. However, with hindsight, it is clear that these policies were good for development.</p><p>In contrast, for example, DRC's failure today to escape its extractive statehood can be explained better by the myriad ways in which foreign mining firms legally retain a grip on the country, despite being regulated and financed in the UK and other “donor” countries, than by focusing on the lack of a development accord among domestic elites.</p><p>Where Dercon and I fully agree is on the role of aid. Aid can do very little to change these structural circumstances and can even serve to distract attention from them.</p><p>But taking a longer, more complete view of history, I would augment Dercon's theory to suggest that encouraging international partners to build capacity for internal grand bargains will also be insufficient.</p><p>The real trick is for international partners to recognize the need to deliver what might seem oppositional to their well-established national and business interests, and/or oppositional to established multilateral norms.</p><p>Taking a long view of history, development partners need to support external grand struggles more than they need to encourage internal development deals.</p><p>It won't be easy, and may not be possible, but an informed development debate and theory of change needs to begin with more humility, with more awareness of history and the structures that have been imposed on the global South. For this reason, I'm glad Dercon has written his book, to help push our profession into making this difficult journey.</p><p>\n <i>Kunal Sen, UNU-WIDER and University of Manchester</i>\n </p><p>ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5439-6619</p><p>In <b><i>Gambling on development</i></b>, Stefan Dercon argues that countries that have managed to grow with broad-based development, did not do so with perfect institutions, but where elites formed development bargains, namely “an underlying commitment to growth and development by members of a country's elite” (Dercon, <span>2022</span>, p. 4). Without such a development elite bargain, economic development is unlikely to occur. Dercon further argues that the development bargain is a gamble on the part of elites, as success is not guaranteed and incumbent elites may lose power in the process.</p><p>What role do development partners play to form development bargains? Dercon argues that in countries where the development bargain is present or emerging, aid can play a very important complementary role in providing technical support and advice to deepen and strengthen the development bargain. Dercon offers Bangladesh and Ghana as examples of countries where aid played a facilitating role in contributing to the emergence of the development bargain. This seems sensible advice, and is consistent with what has been noted by Pritchett, Sen, and Werker, who argue that sustained economic growth is underpinned by an inclusive or pro-growth settlement, where constituencies interested in broad-based growth get a seat at the table, and where aid can influence the character of the political settlement, at least at the margin (Pritchett et al., <span>2018</span>). The challenge here is in recognizing when a genuine development bargain is being formed, rather than “isomorphic mimicry,” where elites provide the veneer of an inclusive political settlement to attract aid (say, through stage managed elections), when the reality is quite different. Is there a benefit of hindsight when one looks at the success stories of Bangladesh and Ghana? Was the development bargain evident when Jerry Rawlings took power in 1981 in Ghana, and suspended the constitution, effectively banning political parties in the country? The onset of autocratic rule was also the period when rapid economic growth was initiated in Ghana, subsequently sustained over several decades. However, most observers of Ghana at that time would have been hard-pressed to classify the Rawlings era as a development bargain. Similarly, when growth took off in 1996, Bangladesh was in the middle of a vulnerable democratic transition period, characterized by zero-sum elite conflicts (Hassan &amp; Raihan, <span>2018</span>). What would development partners have recognized in this transition period that had elements of a development bargain, when there was little evidence of a stable settlement among competing elites? And if the elite bargain is inherently unstable, is it truly developmental? Is there risk of a post hoc ergo propter hoc fallacy here?</p><p>So, what should development actors do in circumstances when such bargains are absent and unlikely to form in the short run? Dercon rightly argues that, by making it easy for political actors to ignore the need for change, aid and development partners can make things worse in cases where elite bargains are not developmental. In such cases, foreign aid provides “appropriable and transferable resources to the ruling elite to maintain otherwise weakening patronage networks, with negative implications for growth and stability” (Pritchett et al., <span>2018</span>, p. 348).</p><p>However, it should also be recognized that, in many of the cases where elite bargains are not developmental, these countries are often experiencing widespread and protracted conflict. Here, most development assistance tends to be for humanitarian purposes, often crowding out aid for developmental purposes. So, for all practical purposes, aid is of the “sticking plaster” variety, and relatively little attention is paid by development partners to the long-term growth and development needs of the country. What can development partners do to turn things around, contributing to the emergence of some semblance of a development bargain in fragile and conflict affected states (as occurred in Indonesia in the late 1960s, Cambodia in the 1980s, and Rwanda in the 1990s). Dercon advises caution and limited engagement on the part of development partners in such complex country contexts. Yet there may be an argument for a more proactive approach, such as identification of alternative foundational bargains than the status quo. This in turn might permit more inclusive growth and interventions to increase inclusion, representation, and political participation of marginalized groups to make the political settlement more inclusive (Werker &amp; Sen, <span>2021</span>). This does not mean we should repeat the mistakes of the past, where development partners often came with wildly ambitious plans for reforms (as was evident in Afghanistan recently), but rather work with the grain, prioritizing pragmatism over ideological purity, and recognizing the limits of external actors to bring about economic and political transformation in fragile contexts.</p><p>\n <i>Carolina Trivelli, Instituto de Estudios Peruanos</i>\n </p><p>Professor Dercon's text, as with most of his work, is provocative and suggestive. While <b><i>Gambling on development</i></b> builds on his work in Africa and Asia, it is highly relevant to Latin America. This is especially so today, when slowing economic growth and rising citizen disenchantment with democracy, give rise to political polarization that calls into question the very existence of agreements on national development.</p><p>Doubts about the route to development, and the efforts required, haunt even those countries that managed to sustain coherent agreements over the last 20 years. Today, everything looks more complex and confusing than it once did. Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC), the region of greatest inequality, faces problems of economy and governance: low growth (less than 2% forecast in 2023),3 rising poverty,4 and dissatisfaction with democracy. Less than half the citizens of countries like Brazil, Colombia, the Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Paraguay, and Peru are satisfied with democracy, and more than 40% of them believe the rich buy elections (Lupu et al., <span>2021</span>).</p><p>In this context, the questions that matter more than ever are about how to generate agreements about development that is desirable, possible, achievable; about how to implement bargains with the best chance of success. Today, the elites, in their broadest sense,5 are not even discussing, much less negotiating, development proposals. Rather, it seems they are too busy surviving within the polarized disputes that mark each of their countries. Concern for development is not, it seems, a priority. It has been left by the wayside.</p><p>Stefan Dercon's proposals prompt us to discuss how to achieve bargains conducive to development in the context of the region, and how to negotiate them so that elites “bet” on them.</p><p>The agenda requires starting to (re)build trust among actors—particularly within elites, and between them and citizens—and renewing their confidence in the future; in which the democratic system will not only be sustained, but will also emerge strengthened from the current crisis.</p><p>To meet these challenges, we must create meeting spaces, spaces for dialogue between actors who must negotiate. Given the current high polarization, this is complex. It requires deliberate and intentional efforts. But who can promote these dialogues and encounters? There is a key role for local academics and intellectuals, and for external actors committed to the development of LAC. These local and external actors in turn require a strategy, in effect a joint agreement negotiated between them, if they are to be effective.</p><p>We also need elites to engage more in politics. Not necessarily party politics, although this too matters; but rather that they take up the challenge of strengthening our fragile democracies to avoid falling into perverse autocratic machinations, even when the latter emerge from popular elections—as we have already seen in the region. For this, more politics, more participation, more involvement of the elites in public affairs is vital. Easy to say, hard to do.</p><p>Today, more than ever, external development partners should focus less on specific instruments, but more on institutional strengthening and the construction of cohesive proposals. As Stefan Dercon proposes, pay less attention to the technical content, to the packages of instruments that will help development, and instead pay more attention to a sustained effort, based on a shared vision of future development.</p><p>Perhaps now is the time to stop looking for silver bullets to solve a social or economic problem, and instead to support well-informed dialogue, institutional strengthening, the exercise of citizenship, and political debate—to pressure, support, and strengthen elites to negotiate a medium term that is feasible, better, and inclusive—a desirable and achievable future for themselves and for their fellow citizens.</p><p>Latin America and the Caribbean faces enormous challenges to advancing its development, reducing poverty and inequality, and assuming responsibility for its environment. None of this will be possible without a commitment agreed by, and with, its elites. We need to invest, mobilize support, and help to make it happen, as Stefan Dercon recommends.</p><p><i>Stefan Dercon, Professor of Economic Policy at the Blavatnik School of Government and the Economics Department at the University of Oxford, and Director of the Centre for the Study of African Economies</i>.</p><p>ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4496-1623</p><p>“We never intended this to reduce poverty,” said the senior official advising the State Council of the People's Republic of China, essentially the Cabinet of China, led by the Prime Minister. He was speaking about the reforms in the early 1980s that unleashed growth and much job creation via industrialization. At this closed meeting in 2016, I had joined a small delegation of UK academics and government officials for the UK–China Development Forum. I had just praised China for the massive success in poverty reduction through this strategy—possibly the largest poverty reduction in a country in one decade ever.</p><p>I was reminded of this story when reading Rathin Roy's comments in this collection. China's decision-makers did not have a Damascene conversion in 1979 to the virtues of development simply because they cared for the poor, but because they had strong political interests in pursuing growth and food security, to keep the hegemonic position of the Party. They risked losing power through a continuing erosion of legitimacy, but also simply for lack of economic resources to sustain their dominance. Poverty reduction was an outcome gratefully received, but in China, just as anywhere else, the poor rarely have the political clout to warrant too much attention—but a confluence of sensible and feasible policy-making can benefit them nevertheless.</p><p>The editors of this volume asked the other commentators and me to consider the question of what my book meant for aid and for donors. I am glad that Naomi Hossain, Rathin Roy, and Arkebe Oqubay take issue with the question and, to some extent, am happy with my own answers. As for myself, I found writing the last few chapters of my book a rather unsatisfactory experience. I know the expectation was to be propositional, to state “what to do.” Surely, given my background working for a decade for an important donor, I should be able to say something! How could I have been a useful adviser if I could identify the problem but not offer solutions?</p><p>That is one way, but the problem is that when suggesting the role for aid and development partners, their role can too easily take centre stage. I am glad that many of the commentators agree with my view that aid has never been the central driver of development success. With enough humility on the part of donors, aid can play a productive complementary role, including the fostering and strengthening of development bargains.</p><p>Kunal Sen makes some excellent points inspired by his and his co-authors' seminal work on related issues (Pritchett et al., <span>2018</span>). His points on Ghana and Bangladesh are intriguing: the nature of political deals was clearly not enough in the 1980s in Ghana and the 1990s in Bangladesh to simply conclude that the political settlement was stable and democratic. But here I see a real case of a gamble by the international community (led by some well-informed players) as it sensed an opportunity. Aid was flowing generously in this period, and both countries can arguably be considered as cases in which aid and donor activity successfully complemented the locally chosen development direction—as carefully discussed with nuance in Naomi Hossain's book on Bangladesh (Hossain, <span>2017</span>).</p><p>Still, I can only agree with Arkebe Oqubay that using aid to foster the emergence of, or the strengthening, of development bargains all too easily smells patronizing—and, boy, have I seen patronizing behaviour across the donor community! Rathin Roy goes further. He pushes for an ever deeper recognition of the political nature of aid and other engagement, not inconsistent with some of my arguments, but in ways that lead to a conclusion that there is no role for aid in forging or strengthening development bargains. I don't want to give up on aid as yet. Leastways, I recognize that some leaders in donor countries still want aid to play a role—and so suggest my final chapters be read for some ideas on doing aid and development co-operation better, even if my suggestions reflect at times more hope than reason.</p><p>Of course, maybe Western donors did not want to learn, and Hannah Ryder and Naomi Hossain go one step further in their critique that I have not treated development partners enough as political players themselves.</p><p>I focused less on donors as political actors because I wanted to emphasize the role of elites in shaping their own countries—too often I have heard Nigerian or Congolese elite players invoke outsiders as the real villains of the piece. Of course, there are outside villains involved, but plenty inside these countries too—villains with much power and influence to keep on plundering, with or without outside help.</p><p>I fear this is not a sufficient answer to the points Hannah Ryder eloquently makes about my apparent neglect of the deep colonial exploitation still affecting countries' destiny today. I accept she is right, or as a West African academic who heckled me during a talk at Université Cheikh Anta Diop in Dakar said: “these are things that have to be said” when talking about African development.</p><p>I had my reasons for saying what I did. Professor Leonard Wantchekon, originally from Benin and currently James Madison Professor of Political Economy and Professor of Politics and International Affairs at the Princeton School of Public and International Affairs, argued in his 2022 Kuznets Memorial Lecture at Yale that to understand the present situation in economics and politics of Africa, history matters a great deal—maybe up to 50%, and that includes colonial exploitation and slavery. But that means that the remaining 50% lies in the present: the agency, the actions, and behaviours of those who have power today in these countries. I agree with him, and I for one do not want those in power to hide behind the excuse that it is 100% the fault of the historical preconditions. In fact, the differential progress of previously colonized states in the last three decades is at the core of my thesis: that the choices of those with power may be constrained by history, but they can still make choices about the direction of their countries. Bangladesh's and Ghana's elites, with all their weaknesses, make different choices from Pakistan's and Nigeria's elites. I am sick and tired of powerful decision-makers supported by crooks sticking to stupid economic policies and making terrible choices for development.</p><p>And this brings me back to the core of my argument: development needs elites committed to development. And much more, of course. I agree with Arkebe Oqubay that “a country's prospects…are determined by what a country <i>does</i>” and not what it has. As I would put it: the actual choices by those with power and influence matter.</p><p>It is therefore very pleasing to read the comments by Carolina Trivelli, and the relevance of the framework and analysis for Peru and other Latin American countries. I have been surprised (and flattered) by the positive reactions by scholars, journalists, and development observers in Latin American to this book that never mentions Latin America. Her appeal, to find ways to foster, despite political divisions, at least some consensus on development among elites is the only way, even if the route is difficult.</p>","PeriodicalId":51478,"journal":{"name":"Development Policy Review","volume":"41 3","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":2.0000,"publicationDate":"2023-03-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/dpr.12701","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Development Policy Review","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/dpr.12701","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"DEVELOPMENT STUDIES","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

Contents

1. Introduction – Annalisa Prizzon and Steve Wiggins

2. What role for aid in countries with and without a “development bargain”? – Stefan Dercon

3. Donors are already part of the development bargain—for better or, often, for worse – Naomi Hossain

4. Development co-operation can help with the first steps, but it is the national government that makes the development journey – Liang Ma

5. Which elite bargain drives development assistance? – Arkebe Oqubay

6. Development actors cannot help form development bargains – Rathin Roy

7. Development partners need to support external grand struggles – Hannah Ryder

8. Aid and the development bargain: What should development partners do? – Kunal Sen

9. Latin America and the Caribbean and the urgency of building a development agenda – Carolina Trivelli

10. Rejoinder – Stefan Dercon

Annalisa Prizzon, Principal Research Fellow, ODI and Steve Wiggins, Principal Research Fellow, ODI – editors, Development Policy Review

Foreign aid is meant to support economic growth and development in the global South. But what drives development? Debate over key ingredients is as old as development co-operation itself, with thinking going back to the late 1940s. Early thinkers stressed capital investment; later, attention turned to structural factors, such as land reform; by 1980 the Washington Consensus had formed, emphasizing free trade and strong macroeconomic management. In the early 2000s, the spotlight then fell back on economic growth, in appreciation of its several, complicated, and frankly elusive determinants. As ideas about the drivers of development have changed, so have ideas about the role of aid.

In his 2022 book, Gambling on development, Stefan Dercon compares country experiences, arguing that countries develop strongly when their leaders and elites reach a shared vision for their country's development, and bet on its success—though the outcome cannot be guaranteed. This vision and its implementation he dubs a “development bargain.” What matters for development is national leadership, politics, and policies. But if domestic matters are crucial, what is the role of outsiders?

Professor Dercon—as a scholar and former senior adviser in the erstwhile UK Department for International Development—brings a rare perspective to the question of why and how development happens, and the role aid can play. But aid is not central to his argument, the core of which concerns domestic leadership and politics. This is not necessarily the most welcome message for those concerned with directing foreign aid, which is subject to increasing scepticism, with persistent threats to cut budgets.

We posed two questions to Dercon. If aid works best where development bargains have been struck, what should aid do in such cases? More importantly, what should aid do in countries that lack a development bargain?

In his answer, Stefan recommends development partners accept a smaller role than they may feel they warrant. Aid should be complementary to, and supportive of, national policies when a development bargain has formed or is emerging.

When elites fail to reach a shared vision for growth and development—they may share other visions, for example, of power and self-enrichment—the role of development partners becomes more difficult. Globally, development partners should try to set incentives for better elite bargains, while deterring bargains that do not lead to growth and development. Examples are setting extensive trade preferences and fighting illicit finance. Within countries lacking a development bargain, development partners may need to be less ambitious, prioritizing the needs of the most deprived citizens, rather than imagining that aid alone can stimulate development.

We asked seven distinguished scholars and practitioners from the global South to answer the same questions Stefan was asked, and to respond to his propositions. They were, in alphabetical order, Naomi Hossain, Ma Liang, Arkebe Oqubay, Rathin Roy, Hannah Ryder, Kunal Sen and Carolina Trivelli.

Most were sympathetic to Dercon's argument: they agreed that development will only be achieved if some domestic compact is in place. Some took it a stage further: development partners need to recognize that they are political players; and, in some cases, donor interests will be antithetical to those of the country they purport to assist. One respondent pointed out the wider framing: the road to a domestic development bargain begins with, or began with, a struggle against colonialism and its continuing echoes. Development bargains may be internal, but they may have to be formed in the teeth of pressures to conform to international norms.

But read on: to appreciate the arguments you need to read the individual contributions—they are short—and Professor Dercon's reply. As ever, the views constitute a debate, one that still leaves several important questions that will not be answered readily or quickly; above all that of how a development bargain can be identified in its infancy.

Stefan Dercon, Professor of Economic Policy at the Blavatnik School of Government and the Economics Department, University of Oxford, and Director of the Centre for the Study of African Economies.

ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4496-1623

My book Gambling on development: Why some countries win and others lose is not about aid or international development actors. There are 13 chapters and only from chapter 11 are aid or these actors seriously mentioned. There is a good reason for this. The role of international development actors in the success or failure of countries in growth and development is just a bitpart, and they do not have a key starring role, despite attempts to present it otherwise.

My book is about how some countries managed to grow their economies with broad-based development, starting from low GDP per capita levels in the last three to four decades. Not Singapore-level growth rates or perfectly inclusive growth—but rather growth of at least 4% to 5% per year, a serious reduction in poverty and, generally, a sense of development progress. Examples include countries like China, Indonesia, India, Bangladesh, Ghana, Ethiopia, and Rwanda. Each did it in its own way: the specific set of policies were different, political systems were not alike, and they definitely did not do it starting from Why nations fail-style perfect institutions, but rather with a lot of imperfection and much unfinished business.

My core argument is that these countries had a specific elite bargain—an implicit “deal” involving those with power or influence in politics, business, military, civil service, even civil society and media—in which growth and development played a central role. Not just in words, but in actions and behaviour that meant politics valued peace and stability in the economy and the state. It involved a state that was self-aware enough to take on what it could, but not more, given its own context and capability, and whereby there was a political and bureaucratic learning and accountability culture so that there were course corrections possible. I call this type of elite bargain a development bargain.

Such an elite bargain for growth and development is required for progress—there is no way around this. However, for those with power, it is a gamble, as success is not guaranteed, and incumbents may lose, as happened over time to Suharto in Indonesia, or it may tear apart elite bargains as in Ethiopia. And don't take for granted that it exists everywhere: the game in town for the elite in Nigeria or DRC for example is not growth and development — they are examples of failing countries.

Aid and development partners are not centre stage in any of the examples discussed, and they do not warrant top billing in the show. Still, with their influence in the media and research communities in donor countries, non-governmental organizations, multilateral banks, or the UN see themselves as the headline acts. This is not very helpful—more humility and awareness of the real importance of their role is required.

It does not mean that development partners are irrelevant. In places where a development bargain is present or emerging, aid can play a hugely helpful complementary role in supporting the direction this society and economy is taking, with aid, with technical support and, yes, with critical advocacy to deepen and strengthen the development bargain. Ghana and Bangladesh are countries where this role has been possible, given the nature of the state and the development bargain.

When a development bargain does not exist, caution is required. Then, objectives of (well-meaning) donors are not aligned with those of people with power and influence in the countries. It is then crucial to think through the incentives created by outside support as regards the nature of the political deal involved. Many official development partners love to hide behind their “apolitical” nature. Their political analysis of countries is usually lacking a sense of longer-term history and politics, and the underlying social and political contract. The key issue is that, however these outsiders act in trying to contribute to “development,” they will influence not just outcomes for people, but also the underlying incentives in the elite bargain.

If done well, development partners' actions may improve outcomes for the population, but also create conditions for a better elite bargain to emerge and be sustained. However, it is also perfectly possible that doing seemingly “good” may embed a bad elite bargain, giving excuses not to act on growth or development. Indeed, as discussed in the book, over time I have become worried about how, in countries like Malawi or Nigeria, aid and development partners may well make circumstances worse, by making it too easy for political actors to ignore the need for change as development partners compensate for their failure to deliver progress for the population, or how, in South Sudan, humanitarian aid may even help to embed the conflict.

So…what to do? First, globally, try to set incentives for better elite bargains to be successful while undermining rogue elite bargains. For example, a focus on exports outside natural resources is often a sign of a commitment to growth, as it is really hard to do with the usual shenanigans of business connected to rent-seeking elites. Hence, offering extensive trade preferences rarely rewards poor elite bargains but typically encourages decent ones. Similarly, seriously fighting illicit finance, that key instrument of financing rogue elite bargains, would be really helpful to shift the incentives, too.

What to do within countries? This is the hardest. Surely there are plenty of needs—anti-developmental elite bargains, such as in the DRC, Nigeria, or Madagascar coincide with huge deprivation. So doing “good” by helping those suffering is an honourable objective. However, all I am asking is that this be done with one's eyes wide open, conscious of what large-scale outside engagement does for the incentives in these countries to become more developmental. And not label all such efforts as “development” but as at best trying to do “good”—and, of course, still using the best evidence on how to have most impact in these often dysfunctional settings.

And then, based on deep knowledge, maybe some can do more, carefully, and maybe by stealth. It could involve working with those within elites who are up for change. Or working with technocrats in central banks or ministries that want growth and development. It may mean working with political leaders and public intellectuals to contribute to crafting new narratives to reset the direction of a country. Or strengthening those in business who would benefit from growth and broad-based development. It may involve supporting civil society in calling for transparency, better governance, or, indeed, rights.

I for one do not want to give up yet and I still think that outside development actors can contribute to change—even though much is wrong with the incentives inside the development system, such as pressure to be seen to deliver quick results or a narrow focus on finance, which tend to stymie change. And, as we are talking about what outsiders can do, they had better show both humility and self-awareness that, when outsiders act, they are not necessarily making matters better.

Naomi Hossain, Accountability Research Center, American University, Washington DC.

ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-3244-2319

“Should development partners help form development bargains, and if so, how?”

This question, like Stefan's book, speaks to a gentler and more optimistic era of development aid. It assumes that aid donors are good faith actors with interests in reducing poverty and promoting inclusive and sustainable growth, peace, and prosperity for all. Many of us have worked with those assumptions for the 20-odd years since the Cold War ended. But it is not clear that those assumptions still hold—if they ever did. Certainly, the UK government department formerly known as the Department for International Development (DFID) was a moderately progressive aid donor; it could potentially have supported the formation of pro-poor political bargains in the countries in which it had influence. But in its current form, on life-support at the tail-end of a post-Brexit far-right Conservative government, the UK's Foreign, Commonwealth & Development Office (FCDO) is focused chiefly on making the world profitable for UK business, a fact about which it makes no bones.

So the answer is no. Aid donors like the UK should not be in the business of forming development bargains. There is no reason to believe those bargains will be in the interests of anyone but those with elite connections. The antics of the British party of government in the past few years have in any case left the UK without credibility as a champion of good governance in the eyes of the global South. Stefan notes that tackling impunity is crucial for enabling enduring development bargains to emerge, as it makes it harder for corrupt elites to get away with their illicit spoils. Yet the UK continues to protect tax havens and financial sector secrecy in ways that are designed to shield elites from being held accountable for corruption. How can they possibly set an example?

However, aid donors do deserve to be treated as political actors in the development bargains of development countries. This is not because they should be getting involved, but because they already always are. Gambling on development pays too little attention to donors as political actors, treating them as though capable of intervening in politics cleanly from above without adverse consequences or messy side-effects. Stefan would have done well to include the insights of the Effective States and Inclusive Development research programme at the University of Manchester,1 which showed how donors shaped political economy across settings. Donors are already part of any development bargains, and when bargains fail to deliver inclusive development, donors should shoulder some of the blame. In short, donors should not actively help form development bargains because there is always the risk they may interfere—catastrophically—in the politics of other countries but we should be more alert to the fact that donors are already involved in the politics of development.

“What should they do in circumstances when such bargains are absent and unlikely to form in the short run?”

Donors should put their hands in their pockets and find the money needed for climate change adaptation, mitigation, and social protection. They should provide the humanitarian aid that is increasingly needed, and they should provide for the world's growing number of refugees and asylum-seekers. They should do these things anyway, regardless of whether or not development bargains are present. People in the global South are owed at least that by the countries that industrialized and pumped carbon into the atmosphere on their own pathways to development, and colonized and robbed, before more recently interfering in domestic politics in their quests for foreign policy influence and power.

But it is also the case that no development is possible under conditions of chronic crisis and subsistence failure. People must be able to live without fearing the next attack or storm or famine before they can take advantage of any opportunities afforded by open markets. The development bargains that feature in Gambling on development were often the fruits of investment in basic human security rather than deliberate shifts towards market-driven growth. Most of the cases that Stefan describes so well in his book are instances where elites only arrived at a consensus about development after disasters made business-as-usual unthinkable. War, famine, disasters, and genocide feature prominently, and in each case proved to be the turning point. At such turning points, the lessons in Gambling on development suggest that aid donors can either be helpful by supporting humanitarian efforts or they can get out of the way.

Liang Ma, Renmin University of China

ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-8779-5891

Countries can benefit from development aid, but development aid should not influence national policy choices. Development assistance is not value free. It is usually accompanied by the strong ideological preferences of development partners, and these might not suit local situations in developing countries. One-size-fits-all development co-operation programmes cannot address the key challenges faced by developing countries, not to mention help them escape the poverty trap. Countries differ in many important aspects. Development programmes should be country specific, which means those offered by development partners cannot be a panacea for all. It is much more important to do the right things than to do things right, and development partners should be conscious of their roles and boundaries.

Developing countries usually cannot resist or afford to ignore the conditions required by international organizations on development assistance. Post-colonial countries in particular are rarely self-confident in holding to the development paths with their own characteristics and can often be trapped by development partners' recommendations. Strong nationalism can further distort elite bargaining by leading to citizens labelling development aid as unpatriotic, which can impact relations with development partners.

China learned much from the Soviet Union following the establishment in 1949 of the People's Republic of China, but some of these lessons were painful. Experts from the Soviet Union helped China build its industrial infrastructure. China's overreliance on the Soviet Union saw its industrial structure lean disproportionately towards heavy industry, and the central planning regime jeopardized its economy by stifling local improvisation. By binding its future to the Soviet Union, China was losing its economic sovereignty.

China's remarkable growth after the Reform and Opening-up in the late 1970s could be attributed to smart learning from the West. The government learned from Western countries, but kept Chinese style as the ruling principle. For instance, China learned from international practices about administrative reforms (e.g., one-stop services), but approached them with domestic considerations. In some situations, the government declined advice, mainly in the fields of financial development and regulation. In effect, the government worked as a smart shopper to introduce Western practices and to combine them with Chinese ones, producing a novel development state with Chinese characteristics.

What can we learn from the Chinese experience? Development assistance should not be overemphasized. It is governments themselves that should develop effective policies to boost national development. In other words, development partners can give advice and recommendations, but it is the domestic elites who collectively make decisions crucial for themselves and national development. China's merit lies in its incremental trial-and-error approach, which gave the elites confidence to support development.

It is very important to calibrate and highlight the boundaries between development partners and domestic elites. Development partners can work as consultants or knowledge brokers to inspire and enlighten national government decision-makers with best practices and evidence, but they should not get deeply involved. They come and leave, but it is national government that makes the development journey.

Some countries may not develop elite bargains essential to sustainable development. In such cases development partners can help to some extent. To convince elites, used to reaping short-term profits, of the long-term benefits of development is challenging, so development partners must develop more effective approaches to elicit development bargains. For instance, development partners can help by investing in concrete programmes, but their operations may not be sustained if and when they leave. Instead, pilot programmes with convincing demonstrations and achievements may help reshape elites' attitudes towards development, and bargains would be kick-started.

Development partners should return to the essential meaning of development. Go to the nature of development, it is more about economic and social aspects than political ones. Without indigenous development paths embedded in the local development community, countries do not develop in a sustainable way. As the saying has it, teaching people how to fish is more important than giving them fish.

Previously North–South development assistance and policy transfer mattered, but with the emerging of China and other economies, a South–South model has been playing an ever more important role. China's leading role in the Belt and Road Initiative (BRI) is different from most other development assistance. It has vividly shown how development partners can help in elite bargains. Focusing on and providing what developing countries really want (e.g., infrastructure, agriculture, and affordable financing), BRI is positioning itself to be fruitful for future development assistance.

China benefitted and learned from development assistance, and it has developed its own version of development aid to help other developing countries. China's experience, like all development aid, might not be universally applicable. The spirit of its development assistance, however, could be transferred to other contexts.

Arkebe Oqubay, British Academy Global Professor and Professor of Practice at SOAS University of London, Senior Minister.2

In this context, there is new pressure to rethink approaches to international development. Dercon's book is a valuable contribution to thinking about aid and, more broadly, the political economy of development. Given his stature and experience, his views on the inherent flaws in development assistance will carry much weight in donor circles.

As a senior policy-maker in Ethiopia for over three decades, I worked with—and closely observed—development partners and the mechanics of development assistance during a period when Ethiopia sustained rates of economic growth of 10% and above for more than 15 years, and when average life expectancy rose by 22 years from 1991 to 2016. Ethiopia's development model assigned a leading role to the developmental state. A clear degree and exercise of policy ownership earned it both keen interest from other African countries and sharp criticism from mainstream media and some influential persons within international development circles.

I must confess my belief that development assistance plays a secondary role in economic development. The relationship is always shaped by political tensions, where its positive contribution results primarily from the recipient government's development strategy and policies. In this, I very much agree with Dercon's argument that official development assistance plays, at best, a “bit part” in the drama of development. Imposing long lists of conditionalities and flooding a developing country with the helpful advice of international consultants have not proved a recipe for long-term sustained growth and economic transformation.

The Ethiopian government resisted donor pressure, conditionalities, and interference in internal politics, often on very sensible grounds, as I repeatedly witnessed from the early 1990s onwards. Joseph Stiglitz's description of the pressure exerted by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to liberalize Ethiopia's banking industry (Stiglitz, 2001); and the World Bank's unwarranted engagement in the negotiation of the geopolitically contentious Grand Ethiopian Renaissance Dam (GERD) on the Nile, Africa's largest hydropower dam during the Trump administration, are telling examples (van Eyssen, 2020). There are also positive examples that contributed to economic transformation, including: Japan's support for the Industrial Policy Dialogue; the German programme for reform of university, vocational, and technical education; UK assistance for investment promotion and industrialization; and US support for rural primary health. However, the key was that the government was squarely in the driving seat for each of these reforms.

Yet donors' ideas and priorities are often not aligned with developing countries' long-term development strategies, policies, and priorities. Resources are committed annually, making it difficult to rely upon them for long-term investment, especially when donors often change their “flavour of the month” preferences. The very idea of a “development bargain” may well have a turn on the catwalk before going out of fashion, rather like Growth Diagnostics, the “good governance agenda,” and indeed the Washington Consensus before it. Development assistance also fluctuates depending on the changing domestic politics of the donor country. Whatever the rhetoric of “partnership,” donor governments typically make aid decisions unilaterally, underscoring a fundamental power asymmetry. Aid often risks fundamentally derailing development trajectories, as was seen in the damage done by Washington Consensus policies pushed on African countries and (often with eager supporters within these countries, it must be said) dismantling the apparatus of state and industrial policy.

The aid relationship is also often shaped by an incessant ideological barrage orchestrated by sophisticated mainstream media, bureaucracy, consultancy, and influential policy intellectuals. Stefan Dercon's recommendations on how donors can influence elite bargains risks being patronizing, implicitly assuming that donors have the right ideas so that it is just a matter of how best to tweak the “bargain” among interest groups in a developing country so the latter absorb these ideas, and the aid that comes with them, more smoothly.

The same barrage of conventional wisdom (radical “shock therapy” deregulation and liberalization) was a powerful feature of much engagement with China from the mid-1970s, as it was in the wake of the collapse, later, of the Soviet Union. Isabella Weber's book How China escaped shock therapy shows how China's reforms would have failed had China followed the wisdom of much international advice. My point is that it cannot be assumed that the conventional wisdom—whatever that may be at any given time—among the donors is best suited to the needs of various developing countries, which need to form their own policy ideas and to nurture their own decision-making capabilities. Policy independence is, first and foremost, the freedom to experiment and learn from success and failure.

Moving beyond the “aid relationship,” Dercon's book is an important discussion of concepts that have risen to the forefront of thinking about development transformations in recent years. He is quite right to highlight the concept of an “elite bargain” or “political settlement” as key to patterns of economic growth—ideas developed especially by Mushtaq Khan, Jonathan Di John, and James Putzel among others. He is also right to defy the popular view that a specific set of institutions constitutes a precondition for growth. Here, he follows the much earlier insights of Albert Hirschman as well as more recent thinkers such as Ha-Joon Chang. It helps that he popularizes this thinking, but his approach nonetheless raises questions.

The selected country cases are based on loose criteria—such as modest growth of 4% to 5% a year and a functioning political bargain—which raises questions about whether countries with divergent political economies and development paths (such as China and Bangladesh, Ghana and Ethiopia, India and Rwanda) can be lumped into the same basket. The distinctions between these economies matter more than any shared similarity. What economic policies did these countries use for economic catch-up and transformation? What developmental role did the state play? In what ways did they “get prices wrong” rather than following advice to “get prices right”? What type of partnerships characterized the relations between governments, the private sector, the scientific community, and broader society? And, if a pro-growth “bargain” among elites did emerge, then how and why? In my own country's experience, this had virtually nothing to do with external donors. Indeed, there may be a host of unintended consequences and “butterfly effects” resulting from donor attempts to shape political settlements.

In African economic development: Evidence, theory, policy (Cramer et al., 2020), I and my fellow authors, Christopher Cramer and John Sender, argue for the centrality of understanding the drivers of unevenness and variations as a source of learning for development. A country's prospects for economic development, we insist, are determined by what a country does and what it becomes as a result of this, rather than by what it has and is—which may include some black box “bargain” that is usually difficult to identify other than after the event.

Gambling on development will stimulate productive debates on conceptual issues and practical development challenges, and I congratulate Stefan for his contribution. It should help to move discussion and understanding forward.

Rathin Roy, Managing Director, ODI

Stefan Dercon's important narrative allows us to transition to a more symmetric reflection on the political economy of development co-operation.

Dercon's central premise is that domestic elites matter and that their political compact, reflected in the actions of a dirigiste state, impacts the success or failure of development initiatives. Although his focus is on the efficacy of external interventions, this thesis stands independently. Equally, his eloquent excoriation of external development actors for claiming credit for development successes and their alleged “apolitical” basis for recommending interventions resonates with the discourse on development imperialism in the global South, a line of political economy critique applied to aid, structural adjustment, and most recently the climate discourse.

The questions that the editors pose: “If aid works best where development bargains have been struck, what should aid do in such cases? More importantly, what should aid do in countries that lack a development bargain?” fail the Dercon test if taken literally; they are profoundly apolitical. So, I offer a political economy response, to both the long- and short-term questions. From this vantage point the temporal dimension is not directly relevant.

Development actors cannot help form development bargains. Superficially, it may appear that they can; preferential trading arrangements may have helped Bangladesh develop the garment industry that set it on the road to prosperity. But this would ignore a central tenet of Dercon's thesis—that external actors can act only in a way that is complementary to the national effort. Despite having a common history, being plagued by military interference, and having elites with similar, even common, roots, why did Bangladesh do what Pakistan could not—foster a global garments industry, create domestic finance institutions, and improve human development outcomes?

It is notable that in many of the success stories that Dercon highlights—India, Bangladesh, Vietnam, China, Rwanda—the elites made economic, political, and social policy choices that were not aimed at “development” but rather at fostering economic nationalism to counter a current or recent existential threat—colonialism, partition, genocide. These choices are not central to a development thesis, but aimed at preventing recolonization, surviving secession, avoiding a repeat of opium hegemony, preserving a unification won by contesting a superpower. The elite bargain was to rule legitimately by executing these anti-hegemonic choices, which motivated economic policy for many years after the trigger event. India, China, and Vietnam did not even mention ending poverty as a tenet of their development and planning strategies for many years after embarking on their development journey. The transformation imperative intersected with development imperatives in that it was tied to a project of economic modernization that enabled many of these countries to leapfrog levels of dependence—but not stages of development.

For external actors who engage, for reasons of ideological affinity or mutual interest, these bargains can deliver significant value, as in South Korea and Rwanda. Otherwise, they were simply irrelevant. The contempt with which a poor country like India was held by many Western powers for investing in “above its paygrade science and technology” reflected an absence of understanding of the logic of doing so. Similarly, the dismissal of Mao as a development failure led countries to underestimate and misunderstand the ideological transition following Deng and, therefore, caused complete bafflement when Xi Jinping Thought manifested itself at the centre of Chinese development policy—the underlying unity from a political economy perspective was easy to see, but apolitical development studies was not equipped to see it.

But, often, elites are interested solely in maximization of rents from ownership or capture of the state, with stability payments—and investments in coercive repression—made to those who threaten to undermine this process. This, unfortunately, describes a rather large group of countries, with both stable and unstable low-level equilibrium. Interestingly, this is not confined to developing and emerging economies. Developed countries, too, have struck such bargains. What else is much of the welfare state if not an exposition of the second theorem of welfare economics in the form of stability payments to compensate for a fundamentally unequalizing economic process, when public services, equity, and collective prosperity have all atrophied or declined over the long term? In this case there is no bargain to be had because external and internal actors are indifferent to the greater good. Nowhere is this better played out than in the United Kingdom and France, where the compacts between domestic elites and oligarchs, dictators, and money launderers from coercive and failed states are demonstrably more effective than taxpayer-funded interventions. So, in the short and long term, the domestic political economy of both sides of the development bargain matters.

Hannah Ryder, CEO, Development Reimagined

Having worked in the development field for over 20 years, sat in similar ministerial meetings to those Stefan Dercon eloquently and entertainingly describes in Gambling on development, I have been consistently struck by the lack of “humility and self-awareness” of development partners that Dercon calls for.

Professor Dercon is right do so. His dual concerns, that development actors—both local and international—are too eager to find panaceas for development, as well as being too keen to claim results from their own interventions—often designed with little input from recipient countries and actors—are both well-stated and well-founded.

His critiques at the beginning of his book of the various development theories put forward by others—from Jeff Sachs to Dambisa Moyo to Acemoglu and Robinson—are also cogent.

That said, while Dercon is at pains to explain that his “grand bargain” theory is no “one-size-fits-all” solution because, by definition, it must be adapted to the situation of each elite and each country, it is nevertheless a new theory. And it thus deserves as much interrogation as the other theories he evaluates.

Dercon's ideas, and those of the other international development superstars he reviews, suffer from a similar omission. They all exclude from their narratives—consciously or not—imperial history in the form of slavery and then colonialism. As a result, their theories—including Dercon's—are incomplete.

Let me explain.

For almost all the countries mentioned in this book, Professor Dercon starts his account soon after colonialism and decades after slavery. For instance, his story of Indonesia begins in 1945 when it finally won in its struggle for (Dercon writes “declared”) independence from the Netherlands. Dercon refers to Ethiopia's successful resistance against Italians, though a few sentences later suggests the early Ethiopian state was “colonial.” He does also refer to Belgium's colonization of Congo, but later suggests Congo could have been seen as a “colonial development success.” With these references, he brushes off the gross human rights violations and lasting effects of economic imperialism associated with European colonialism and the slave trade—a point I will return to.

Part of the problem is the limited range of literature Professor Dercon and the other leading development thinkers rely on for their analysis. Dercon refers to one helpful text in this regard, Yuen Yuen Ang's How China escaped the poverty trap. Although Professor Dercon's interpretation of Ang's perspectives on China's development history is somewhat limited, he at least gives it some well-deserved attention. But there are other equally important texts. Walter Rodney's How Europe underdeveloped Africa, Edward Said's Orientalism, Eric Beinhocker's The Origin of Wealth, Howard French's Born in Blackness, Victor Bulmer-Thomas' From Slavery to Services, and Susan William's White Malice might not be seen as a traditional development economics texts, but they fall into the same broader yet essential reading list as Ang. These texts directly and frankly tackle the global, complex, and difficult histories of the same countries that Dercon considers, while also setting their interpretations over a longer period.

Why? History, long-run history, matters because it forms the states and the very elites that Professor Dercon hopes will strike development deals.

While Dercon suggests Nkrumah was a better political strategist than an economist, Nkrumah was explaining in no uncertain terms the deep economic challenges his own country and the rest of Africa were facing.

The fact is, for the vast majority of countries, the question of a grand bargain is less about a

grand bargain within a country, it is more about a bargain with international partners. Or rather, a grand struggle.

Taking a longer view, all the “successes” and “failures” of the grand bargains Dercon cites are fundamentally united over whether or not they were able to remove the shackles of colonial—often extractive—patterns of international trade and investment. For example, China's success in “going out” from 1978 onwards was not just about “inviting in” foreign direct investment, it was about having the confidence to force foreign investors to bow to its rules. Such policies—as well as several by India, Ethiopia, and other countries Dercon reviews—were at the time, and even now, seen as directly oppositional to the interests of their donors. However, with hindsight, it is clear that these policies were good for development.

In contrast, for example, DRC's failure today to escape its extractive statehood can be explained better by the myriad ways in which foreign mining firms legally retain a grip on the country, despite being regulated and financed in the UK and other “donor” countries, than by focusing on the lack of a development accord among domestic elites.

Where Dercon and I fully agree is on the role of aid. Aid can do very little to change these structural circumstances and can even serve to distract attention from them.

But taking a longer, more complete view of history, I would augment Dercon's theory to suggest that encouraging international partners to build capacity for internal grand bargains will also be insufficient.

The real trick is for international partners to recognize the need to deliver what might seem oppositional to their well-established national and business interests, and/or oppositional to established multilateral norms.

Taking a long view of history, development partners need to support external grand struggles more than they need to encourage internal development deals.

It won't be easy, and may not be possible, but an informed development debate and theory of change needs to begin with more humility, with more awareness of history and the structures that have been imposed on the global South. For this reason, I'm glad Dercon has written his book, to help push our profession into making this difficult journey.

Kunal Sen, UNU-WIDER and University of Manchester

ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5439-6619

In Gambling on development, Stefan Dercon argues that countries that have managed to grow with broad-based development, did not do so with perfect institutions, but where elites formed development bargains, namely “an underlying commitment to growth and development by members of a country's elite” (Dercon, 2022, p. 4). Without such a development elite bargain, economic development is unlikely to occur. Dercon further argues that the development bargain is a gamble on the part of elites, as success is not guaranteed and incumbent elites may lose power in the process.

What role do development partners play to form development bargains? Dercon argues that in countries where the development bargain is present or emerging, aid can play a very important complementary role in providing technical support and advice to deepen and strengthen the development bargain. Dercon offers Bangladesh and Ghana as examples of countries where aid played a facilitating role in contributing to the emergence of the development bargain. This seems sensible advice, and is consistent with what has been noted by Pritchett, Sen, and Werker, who argue that sustained economic growth is underpinned by an inclusive or pro-growth settlement, where constituencies interested in broad-based growth get a seat at the table, and where aid can influence the character of the political settlement, at least at the margin (Pritchett et al., 2018). The challenge here is in recognizing when a genuine development bargain is being formed, rather than “isomorphic mimicry,” where elites provide the veneer of an inclusive political settlement to attract aid (say, through stage managed elections), when the reality is quite different. Is there a benefit of hindsight when one looks at the success stories of Bangladesh and Ghana? Was the development bargain evident when Jerry Rawlings took power in 1981 in Ghana, and suspended the constitution, effectively banning political parties in the country? The onset of autocratic rule was also the period when rapid economic growth was initiated in Ghana, subsequently sustained over several decades. However, most observers of Ghana at that time would have been hard-pressed to classify the Rawlings era as a development bargain. Similarly, when growth took off in 1996, Bangladesh was in the middle of a vulnerable democratic transition period, characterized by zero-sum elite conflicts (Hassan & Raihan, 2018). What would development partners have recognized in this transition period that had elements of a development bargain, when there was little evidence of a stable settlement among competing elites? And if the elite bargain is inherently unstable, is it truly developmental? Is there risk of a post hoc ergo propter hoc fallacy here?

So, what should development actors do in circumstances when such bargains are absent and unlikely to form in the short run? Dercon rightly argues that, by making it easy for political actors to ignore the need for change, aid and development partners can make things worse in cases where elite bargains are not developmental. In such cases, foreign aid provides “appropriable and transferable resources to the ruling elite to maintain otherwise weakening patronage networks, with negative implications for growth and stability” (Pritchett et al., 2018, p. 348).

However, it should also be recognized that, in many of the cases where elite bargains are not developmental, these countries are often experiencing widespread and protracted conflict. Here, most development assistance tends to be for humanitarian purposes, often crowding out aid for developmental purposes. So, for all practical purposes, aid is of the “sticking plaster” variety, and relatively little attention is paid by development partners to the long-term growth and development needs of the country. What can development partners do to turn things around, contributing to the emergence of some semblance of a development bargain in fragile and conflict affected states (as occurred in Indonesia in the late 1960s, Cambodia in the 1980s, and Rwanda in the 1990s). Dercon advises caution and limited engagement on the part of development partners in such complex country contexts. Yet there may be an argument for a more proactive approach, such as identification of alternative foundational bargains than the status quo. This in turn might permit more inclusive growth and interventions to increase inclusion, representation, and political participation of marginalized groups to make the political settlement more inclusive (Werker & Sen, 2021). This does not mean we should repeat the mistakes of the past, where development partners often came with wildly ambitious plans for reforms (as was evident in Afghanistan recently), but rather work with the grain, prioritizing pragmatism over ideological purity, and recognizing the limits of external actors to bring about economic and political transformation in fragile contexts.

Carolina Trivelli, Instituto de Estudios Peruanos

Professor Dercon's text, as with most of his work, is provocative and suggestive. While Gambling on development builds on his work in Africa and Asia, it is highly relevant to Latin America. This is especially so today, when slowing economic growth and rising citizen disenchantment with democracy, give rise to political polarization that calls into question the very existence of agreements on national development.

Doubts about the route to development, and the efforts required, haunt even those countries that managed to sustain coherent agreements over the last 20 years. Today, everything looks more complex and confusing than it once did. Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC), the region of greatest inequality, faces problems of economy and governance: low growth (less than 2% forecast in 2023),3 rising poverty,4 and dissatisfaction with democracy. Less than half the citizens of countries like Brazil, Colombia, the Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Paraguay, and Peru are satisfied with democracy, and more than 40% of them believe the rich buy elections (Lupu et al., 2021).

In this context, the questions that matter more than ever are about how to generate agreements about development that is desirable, possible, achievable; about how to implement bargains with the best chance of success. Today, the elites, in their broadest sense,5 are not even discussing, much less negotiating, development proposals. Rather, it seems they are too busy surviving within the polarized disputes that mark each of their countries. Concern for development is not, it seems, a priority. It has been left by the wayside.

Stefan Dercon's proposals prompt us to discuss how to achieve bargains conducive to development in the context of the region, and how to negotiate them so that elites “bet” on them.

The agenda requires starting to (re)build trust among actors—particularly within elites, and between them and citizens—and renewing their confidence in the future; in which the democratic system will not only be sustained, but will also emerge strengthened from the current crisis.

To meet these challenges, we must create meeting spaces, spaces for dialogue between actors who must negotiate. Given the current high polarization, this is complex. It requires deliberate and intentional efforts. But who can promote these dialogues and encounters? There is a key role for local academics and intellectuals, and for external actors committed to the development of LAC. These local and external actors in turn require a strategy, in effect a joint agreement negotiated between them, if they are to be effective.

We also need elites to engage more in politics. Not necessarily party politics, although this too matters; but rather that they take up the challenge of strengthening our fragile democracies to avoid falling into perverse autocratic machinations, even when the latter emerge from popular elections—as we have already seen in the region. For this, more politics, more participation, more involvement of the elites in public affairs is vital. Easy to say, hard to do.

Today, more than ever, external development partners should focus less on specific instruments, but more on institutional strengthening and the construction of cohesive proposals. As Stefan Dercon proposes, pay less attention to the technical content, to the packages of instruments that will help development, and instead pay more attention to a sustained effort, based on a shared vision of future development.

Perhaps now is the time to stop looking for silver bullets to solve a social or economic problem, and instead to support well-informed dialogue, institutional strengthening, the exercise of citizenship, and political debate—to pressure, support, and strengthen elites to negotiate a medium term that is feasible, better, and inclusive—a desirable and achievable future for themselves and for their fellow citizens.

Latin America and the Caribbean faces enormous challenges to advancing its development, reducing poverty and inequality, and assuming responsibility for its environment. None of this will be possible without a commitment agreed by, and with, its elites. We need to invest, mobilize support, and help to make it happen, as Stefan Dercon recommends.

Stefan Dercon, Professor of Economic Policy at the Blavatnik School of Government and the Economics Department at the University of Oxford, and Director of the Centre for the Study of African Economies.

ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4496-1623

“We never intended this to reduce poverty,” said the senior official advising the State Council of the People's Republic of China, essentially the Cabinet of China, led by the Prime Minister. He was speaking about the reforms in the early 1980s that unleashed growth and much job creation via industrialization. At this closed meeting in 2016, I had joined a small delegation of UK academics and government officials for the UK–China Development Forum. I had just praised China for the massive success in poverty reduction through this strategy—possibly the largest poverty reduction in a country in one decade ever.

I was reminded of this story when reading Rathin Roy's comments in this collection. China's decision-makers did not have a Damascene conversion in 1979 to the virtues of development simply because they cared for the poor, but because they had strong political interests in pursuing growth and food security, to keep the hegemonic position of the Party. They risked losing power through a continuing erosion of legitimacy, but also simply for lack of economic resources to sustain their dominance. Poverty reduction was an outcome gratefully received, but in China, just as anywhere else, the poor rarely have the political clout to warrant too much attention—but a confluence of sensible and feasible policy-making can benefit them nevertheless.

The editors of this volume asked the other commentators and me to consider the question of what my book meant for aid and for donors. I am glad that Naomi Hossain, Rathin Roy, and Arkebe Oqubay take issue with the question and, to some extent, am happy with my own answers. As for myself, I found writing the last few chapters of my book a rather unsatisfactory experience. I know the expectation was to be propositional, to state “what to do.” Surely, given my background working for a decade for an important donor, I should be able to say something! How could I have been a useful adviser if I could identify the problem but not offer solutions?

That is one way, but the problem is that when suggesting the role for aid and development partners, their role can too easily take centre stage. I am glad that many of the commentators agree with my view that aid has never been the central driver of development success. With enough humility on the part of donors, aid can play a productive complementary role, including the fostering and strengthening of development bargains.

Kunal Sen makes some excellent points inspired by his and his co-authors' seminal work on related issues (Pritchett et al., 2018). His points on Ghana and Bangladesh are intriguing: the nature of political deals was clearly not enough in the 1980s in Ghana and the 1990s in Bangladesh to simply conclude that the political settlement was stable and democratic. But here I see a real case of a gamble by the international community (led by some well-informed players) as it sensed an opportunity. Aid was flowing generously in this period, and both countries can arguably be considered as cases in which aid and donor activity successfully complemented the locally chosen development direction—as carefully discussed with nuance in Naomi Hossain's book on Bangladesh (Hossain, 2017).

Still, I can only agree with Arkebe Oqubay that using aid to foster the emergence of, or the strengthening, of development bargains all too easily smells patronizing—and, boy, have I seen patronizing behaviour across the donor community! Rathin Roy goes further. He pushes for an ever deeper recognition of the political nature of aid and other engagement, not inconsistent with some of my arguments, but in ways that lead to a conclusion that there is no role for aid in forging or strengthening development bargains. I don't want to give up on aid as yet. Leastways, I recognize that some leaders in donor countries still want aid to play a role—and so suggest my final chapters be read for some ideas on doing aid and development co-operation better, even if my suggestions reflect at times more hope than reason.

Of course, maybe Western donors did not want to learn, and Hannah Ryder and Naomi Hossain go one step further in their critique that I have not treated development partners enough as political players themselves.

I focused less on donors as political actors because I wanted to emphasize the role of elites in shaping their own countries—too often I have heard Nigerian or Congolese elite players invoke outsiders as the real villains of the piece. Of course, there are outside villains involved, but plenty inside these countries too—villains with much power and influence to keep on plundering, with or without outside help.

I fear this is not a sufficient answer to the points Hannah Ryder eloquently makes about my apparent neglect of the deep colonial exploitation still affecting countries' destiny today. I accept she is right, or as a West African academic who heckled me during a talk at Université Cheikh Anta Diop in Dakar said: “these are things that have to be said” when talking about African development.

I had my reasons for saying what I did. Professor Leonard Wantchekon, originally from Benin and currently James Madison Professor of Political Economy and Professor of Politics and International Affairs at the Princeton School of Public and International Affairs, argued in his 2022 Kuznets Memorial Lecture at Yale that to understand the present situation in economics and politics of Africa, history matters a great deal—maybe up to 50%, and that includes colonial exploitation and slavery. But that means that the remaining 50% lies in the present: the agency, the actions, and behaviours of those who have power today in these countries. I agree with him, and I for one do not want those in power to hide behind the excuse that it is 100% the fault of the historical preconditions. In fact, the differential progress of previously colonized states in the last three decades is at the core of my thesis: that the choices of those with power may be constrained by history, but they can still make choices about the direction of their countries. Bangladesh's and Ghana's elites, with all their weaknesses, make different choices from Pakistan's and Nigeria's elites. I am sick and tired of powerful decision-makers supported by crooks sticking to stupid economic policies and making terrible choices for development.

And this brings me back to the core of my argument: development needs elites committed to development. And much more, of course. I agree with Arkebe Oqubay that “a country's prospects…are determined by what a country does” and not what it has. As I would put it: the actual choices by those with power and influence matter.

It is therefore very pleasing to read the comments by Carolina Trivelli, and the relevance of the framework and analysis for Peru and other Latin American countries. I have been surprised (and flattered) by the positive reactions by scholars, journalists, and development observers in Latin American to this book that never mentions Latin America. Her appeal, to find ways to foster, despite political divisions, at least some consensus on development among elites is the only way, even if the route is difficult.

援助在有和没有发展协议的国家中扮演什么角色?
内容 1。引言——Annalisa Prizzon和Steve wiggins援助在有或没有“发展协议”的国家中扮演什么角色?-斯特凡·德康捐助者已经成为发展交易的一部分——无论好坏——Naomi Hossain4。发展合作可以帮助迈出第一步,但要靠国家政府来完成整个发展之旅。哪个精英交易推动了发展援助?——阿克贝·奥克贝发展行为体不能帮助形成发展交易- Rathin Roy7。发展伙伴需要支持外部的宏大斗争——汉娜·莱德。援助与发展:发展伙伴应该怎么做?——库纳尔·森拉丁美洲和加勒比地区以及制定发展议程的紧迫性- Carolina Trivelli10。Annalisa Prizzon,对外开放研究所首席研究员,Steve Wiggins,对外开放研究所首席研究员,《发展政策评论》编辑。对外援助是为了支持全球南方国家的经济增长和发展。但是,是什么推动了发展?关于关键要素的争论与发展合作本身一样古老,其思想可以追溯到上世纪40年代末。早期思想家强调资本投资;后来,注意力转向结构性因素,如土地改革;到1980年,“华盛顿共识”形成,强调自由贸易和强有力的宏观经济管理。21世纪初,人们的注意力又回到了经济增长上,认识到经济增长的几个复杂的、坦率地说难以捉摸的决定因素。随着对发展动力的看法发生了变化,对援助作用的看法也发生了变化。在其2022年出版的著作《赌发展》(Gambling on development)中,斯特凡·德康(Stefan Dercon)比较了各国的经验,认为当国家的领导人和精英对国家的发展达成共同愿景,并押注于国家的成功时,国家就会强劲发展——尽管结果无法保证。他将这一愿景及其实现称为“发展交易”。对发展至关重要的是国家领导、政治和政策。但是,如果国内事务至关重要,那么外部人士的角色是什么?作为一名学者和前英国国际发展部的前高级顾问,德康教授对发展为什么和如何发生以及援助可以发挥的作用等问题提出了罕见的观点。但是援助并不是他的论点的中心,他的论点的核心是国内领导和政治。对于那些关注对外援助指导的人来说,这未必是最受欢迎的消息。由于不断有削减预算的威胁,对外援助受到越来越多的怀疑。我们向德康提出了两个问题。如果援助在达成发展协议的地方效果最好,那么在这种情况下援助应该做些什么呢?更重要的是,援助在缺乏发展协议的国家应该做些什么?在他的回答中,Stefan建议开发伙伴接受比他们认为自己应该承担的更小的角色。当发展协议已经形成或正在形成时,援助应该是对国家政策的补充和支持。当精英们无法达成增长和发展的共同愿景时——他们可能会分享其他愿景,例如权力和自我充实——发展伙伴的角色就会变得更加困难。在全球范围内,发展伙伴应努力为更好的精英交易设定激励机制,同时阻止不利于增长和发展的交易。例如设定广泛的贸易优惠和打击非法融资。在缺乏发展协议的国家,发展伙伴可能需要降低雄心,优先考虑最贫困公民的需求,而不是想象仅靠援助就能刺激发展。我们邀请了七位来自全球南方的杰出学者和实践者来回答斯蒂芬被问到的同样的问题,并回应他的主张。按字母顺序排列,他们是内奥米·侯赛因、马良、阿克贝·奥克贝、拉辛·罗伊、汉娜·莱德、库纳尔·森和卡罗莱纳·特里维利。大多数人对德康的观点表示赞同:他们同意,只有在某种国内契约到位的情况下,发展才能实现。有些人则更进一步:发展伙伴需要认识到他们是政治参与者;而且,在某些情况下,捐助者的利益将与他们声称要援助的国家的利益背道而驰。一位回答者指出了更广泛的框架:国内发展谈判的道路始于或开始于反对殖民主义及其持续回响的斗争。发展谈判可能是内部的,但它们可能必须在符合国际规范的压力下形成。但请继续读下去:要理解这些论点,你需要阅读个人的贡献——它们都很短——以及德康教授的回复。 然而,当时大多数观察加纳的人都很难将罗林斯时代归类为发展交易。同样,当1996年增长开始时,孟加拉国正处于脆弱的民主过渡期,其特点是零和精英冲突(Hassan &Raihan, 2018)。在这个具有发展交易要素的过渡时期,当几乎没有证据表明相互竞争的精英之间有一个稳定的解决方案时,发展伙伴会认识到什么?如果精英交易本质上是不稳定的,它真的是发展的吗?这里是否有事后推论谬误的风险?那么,在这种交易不存在且短期内不太可能形成的情况下,发展行为体应该做些什么呢?德康正确地指出,援助和发展伙伴使政治行为者很容易忽视变革的必要性,从而在精英们达成的协议不利于发展的情况下,使事情变得更糟。在这种情况下,外国援助“为统治精英提供了可挪用和可转移的资源,以维持否则会削弱的庇护网络,对增长和稳定产生负面影响”(Pritchett et al., 2018,第348页)。然而,也应该认识到,在许多精英交易不是发展的情况下,这些国家经常经历广泛和持久的冲突。在这方面,大多数发展援助往往用于人道主义目的,往往挤占了用于发展目的的援助。因此,出于各种实际目的,援助是一种“膏药”,发展伙伴对该国的长期增长和发展需求的关注相对较少。发展伙伴可以做些什么来扭转局面,在脆弱和受冲突影响的国家(如20世纪60年代末的印度尼西亚、80年代的柬埔寨和90年代的卢旺达)促成某种表面上的发展交易?德康建议,在这种复杂的国家情况下,发展伙伴应谨慎行事,并有限度地参与。然而,或许有人主张采取更积极主动的方式,比如确定替代性的基础交易,而不是维持现状。这反过来可能会允许更具包容性的增长和干预措施,以增加边缘化群体的包容性、代表性和政治参与,从而使政治解决更具包容性(Werker &森,2021)。这并不意味着我们应该重复过去的错误,在过去,发展伙伴经常提出雄心勃勃的改革计划(最近在阿富汗就很明显),而是要与现实合作,优先考虑实用主义而不是意识形态的纯洁性,并认识到外部行动者在脆弱环境中实现经济和政治转型的局限性。德康教授的文章,和他的大部分作品一样,具有挑衅性和暗示性。虽然《发展赌博》建立在他在非洲和亚洲的工作基础上,但它与拉丁美洲高度相关。今天尤其如此,经济增长放缓和公民对民主越来越不抱幻想,导致政治两极分化,使人们对国家发展协议的存在产生疑问。对发展道路和所需努力的怀疑,甚至困扰着那些在过去20年中设法维持一致协议的国家。今天,一切看起来都比以前更加复杂和令人困惑。拉丁美洲和加勒比地区(LAC)是最不平等的地区,面临着经济和治理问题:低增长(2023年预计不到2%)、贫困加剧、对民主的不满。在巴西、哥伦比亚、多米尼加共和国、厄瓜多尔、巴拉圭和秘鲁等国,不到一半的公民对民主感到满意,超过40%的人认为富人购买选举(Lupu et al., 2021)。在这方面,比以往任何时候都更重要的问题是,如何就可取、可能和可实现的发展达成协议;关于如何以最大的成功机会进行讨价还价。今天,从最广泛的意义上说,精英们甚至不讨论发展建议,更不用说谈判了。相反,他们似乎忙于在各自国家的两极分化争端中生存。对发展的关注似乎不是一个优先事项。它被遗弃在路边了。Stefan Dercon的建议促使我们讨论如何在该地区的背景下达成有利于发展的交易,以及如何通过谈判使精英们“押注”于这些交易。该议程要求开始(重新)建立行为者之间的信任,特别是在精英内部,以及他们与公民之间的信任,并恢复他们对未来的信心;在这种情况下,民主制度不仅将得到维持,而且还将从目前的危机中得到加强。 为了应对这些挑战,我们必须创造会议空间,为必须进行谈判的行动者之间的对话创造空间。考虑到目前的高度极化,这是复杂的。它需要深思熟虑和有意的努力。但谁能推动这些对话和接触呢?当地学者和知识分子以及致力于拉丁美洲和加勒比地区发展的外部行动者都可以发挥关键作用。这些地方和外部行动者反过来需要一项战略,实际上是他们之间谈判达成的一项联合协议,才能发挥作用。我们还需要精英们更多地参与政治。不一定是政党政治,尽管这也很重要;而是要他们接受挑战,加强我们脆弱的民主制度,避免陷入反常的专制阴谋,即使后者是由普选产生的——正如我们在该地区已经看到的那样。为此,更多的政治、更多的参与、精英更多地参与公共事务是至关重要的。说起来容易,做起来难。今天,外部发展伙伴比以往任何时候都更应减少对具体文书的关注,而应更多地注重加强体制和提出有凝聚力的建议。正如Stefan Dercon所建议的那样,不要太关注技术内容,不要太关注有助于发展的一揽子工具,而要更多地关注基于对未来发展的共同愿景的持续努力。也许现在是停止寻找解决社会或经济问题的灵丹妙药的时候了,而应该支持消息灵通的对话、加强制度、行使公民权利和政治辩论——向精英施加压力、支持和加强他们的力量,让他们谈判出一个可行的、更好的、包容的中期方案——一个他们自己和他们的同胞都想要的、可实现的未来。拉丁美洲和加勒比地区在促进发展、减少贫困和不平等以及承担环境责任方面面临巨大挑战。如果没有精英们一致同意的承诺,这一切都不可能实现。正如斯蒂芬·德康所建议的那样,我们需要投资、动员支持并帮助实现这一目标。Stefan Dercon,牛津大学布拉瓦特尼克政府学院和经济系经济政策教授,非洲经济研究中心主任。ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4496-1623“我们从来没有想过这样做是为了减少贫困,”这位为中国国务院(即由总理领导的中国内阁)提供咨询的高级官员说。他指的是上世纪80年代初的改革,那次改革通过工业化释放了经济增长,创造了大量就业机会。在2016年的这次闭门会议上,我加入了一个由英国学者和政府官员组成的小型代表团,参加中英发展论坛。我刚刚赞扬了中国通过这一战略在减贫方面取得的巨大成功——这可能是十年来一个国家减贫规模最大的一次。当我读到Rathin Roy的评论时,我想起了这个故事。中国的决策者在1979年对发展的美德有了大马士革式的转变,并不仅仅是因为他们关心穷人,而是因为他们在追求增长和粮食安全方面有强烈的政治利益,以保持党的霸权地位。他们冒着失去权力的风险,因为合法性不断受到侵蚀,但也因为缺乏维持其统治地位的经济资源。减少贫困是一个可喜的结果,但在中国,就像在其他地方一样,穷人很少有足够的政治影响力来获得太多的关注,但明智和可行的政策制定可以使他们受益。这本书的编辑要求我和其他评论员考虑我的书对援助和捐助者意味着什么。我很高兴Naomi Hossain, Rathin Roy和Arkebe Oqubay对这个问题提出了异议,在某种程度上,我对自己的答案感到满意。至于我自己,我发现写我的书的最后几章是一个相当不满意的经历。我知道大家的期望是命题式的,说明“该怎么做”。当然,考虑到我为一个重要的捐赠者工作了十年的背景,我应该能说点什么!如果我能发现问题,却不能提供解决方案,我怎么能成为一个有用的顾问呢?这是一种方式,但问题在于,当提出援助和发展伙伴的作用时,它们的作用很容易占据中心位置。我很高兴许多评论员同意我的观点,即援助从来不是发展成功的核心驱动力。只要捐助国表现出足够的谦逊,援助就能发挥富有成效的补充作用,包括促进和加强发展谈判。Kunal Sen在他和他的合著者在相关问题上的开创性工作的启发下提出了一些很好的观点(Pritchett et al., 2018)。 他关于加纳和孟加拉国的观点很有趣:政治交易的性质显然不足以在20世纪80年代的加纳和90年代的孟加拉国简单地得出政治解决方案是稳定和民主的结论。但在这里,我看到了一个由国际社会(由一些消息灵通的参与者领导)在感觉到机会时进行赌博的真实案例。在此期间,援助大量流动,这两个国家都可以被认为是援助和捐赠活动成功地补充了当地选择的发展方向的案例——正如内奥米·侯赛因(Naomi Hossain)关于孟加拉国的书(Hossain, 2017)中所细致讨论的那样。尽管如此,我只能同意Arkebe Oqubay的观点,即利用援助来促进发展交易的出现或加强,这太容易让人觉得傲慢——而且,天哪,我在整个捐赠界都看到过傲慢的行为!拉辛·罗伊更进一步。他推动了对援助和其他接触的政治本质的更深层次的认识,这与我的一些论点并不矛盾,但其方式导致了一个结论,即援助在形成或加强发展交易中没有任何作用。我还不想放弃援助。至少,我认识到捐助国的一些领导人仍然希望援助发挥作用,因此建议大家阅读我的最后几章,了解如何更好地开展援助和发展合作,尽管我的建议有时更多地反映了希望而非理性。当然,也许西方捐助者不想学习,汉娜·莱德和内奥米·侯赛因在他们的批评中更进一步,认为我没有把发展伙伴当作政治参与者来对待。我不太关注捐助者作为政治行动者的作用,因为我想强调精英在塑造自己国家方面的作用——我经常听到尼日利亚或刚果的精英们把局外人称为真正的恶棍。当然,有外部的恶棍参与其中,但这些国家内部也有很多恶棍,他们有很大的权力和影响力,不管有没有外部的帮助,都在继续掠夺。我担心这不足以回答汉娜·莱德(Hannah Ryder)雄辩地指出的几点,即我明显忽视了今天仍在影响各国命运的深刻殖民剥削。我承认她是对的,或者正如一位西非学者在达喀尔的谢赫·安塔·迪奥普大学(university of sheikh Anta Diop)的一次演讲中质问我的那样:在谈论非洲发展时,“这些是必须说的”。我那样做是有原因的。伦纳德·万切孔教授来自贝宁,现任普林斯顿大学公共与国际事务学院詹姆斯·麦迪逊政治经济学教授和政治与国际事务教授。他在2022年耶鲁大学的库兹涅茨纪念演讲中指出,要了解非洲经济和政治的现状,历史非常重要——可能高达50%,其中包括殖民剥削和奴隶制。但这意味着剩下的50%取决于现在:这些国家中掌权者的机构、行动和行为。我同意他的观点,我个人不希望当权者躲在百分之百是历史先决条件的错误的借口后面。事实上,前殖民地国家在过去三十年中取得的不同进步正是我论文的核心:当权者的选择可能会受到历史的限制,但他们仍然可以选择自己国家的方向。孟加拉国和加纳的精英们尽管有种种弱点,却与巴基斯坦和尼日利亚的精英们做出了不同的选择。我厌倦了那些由骗子支持的强大的决策者,他们坚持愚蠢的经济政策,为发展做出了糟糕的选择。这让我回到了我论点的核心:发展需要致力于发展的精英。当然,还有更多。我同意Arkebe Oqubay的观点,“一个国家的前景……取决于一个国家做了什么”,而不是它拥有什么。正如我想说的:那些有权力和影响力的人的实际选择很重要。因此,我们非常高兴地看到卡罗莱纳·特里维利的评论,以及该框架和分析对秘鲁和其他拉丁美洲国家的相关性。拉丁美洲的学者、记者和发展观察家对这本从未提及拉丁美洲的书做出了积极的反应,这让我感到惊讶(也感到荣幸)。她呼吁,尽管存在政治分歧,但至少要在精英阶层之间就发展问题达成一些共识,这是唯一的途径,即使这条道路很艰难。 和以往一样,这些观点构成了一场辩论,其中仍有几个重要的问题无法轻易或迅速得到回答;最重要的是,如何在发展初期确定一项交易。Stefan Dercon,牛津大学布拉瓦特尼克政府学院和经济系经济政策教授,非洲经济研究中心主任。ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0003-4496-1623My《发展赌博:为什么一些国家赢而另一些国家输》一书与援助或国际发展行动者无关。全书有13章,只有第11章严肃地提到了这些演员。这是有充分理由的。国际发展行动者在各国增长和发展的成败中所起的作用只是很小的一部分,它们并没有发挥关键的主演作用,尽管它们试图以其他方式表现这种作用。我的书讲的是一些国家如何在过去三四十年里,从较低的人均GDP水平开始,实现了基础广泛的经济增长。不是新加坡水平的增长率,也不是完全包容性的增长,而是每年至少4%到5%的增长,贫困的严重减少,总体上有一种发展进步的感觉。例子包括中国、印度尼西亚、印度、孟加拉国、加纳、埃塞俄比亚和卢旺达等国家。每个国家都以自己的方式做到了这一点:具体的政策不同,政治制度也不相似,而且它们肯定不是从“国家为什么会失败”开始的,而是有很多不完美之处和许多未完成的工作。我的核心论点是,这些国家有一种特殊的精英交易——一种隐含的“交易”,涉及那些在政治、商业、军事、公务员制度、甚至公民社会和媒体中有权力或影响力的人——在这种交易中,增长和发展起着核心作用。不仅在口头上,而且在行动和行为上表明,政治重视经济和国家的和平与稳定。它涉及到一个有足够自我意识的国家,根据其自身的背景和能力,采取力所能及的措施,但不会更多,因此有一种政治和官僚学习和问责文化,这样就有可能纠正方向。我把这种精英讨价还价称为发展讨价还价。进步需要精英们为增长和发展讨价还价——这是无可回避的。然而,对于当权者来说,这是一场赌博,因为成功并没有保证,现任者可能会失败,就像苏哈托在印度尼西亚发生的那样,或者像在埃塞俄比亚那样,它可能会破坏精英们的交易。不要想当然地认为它无处不在:例如,尼日利亚或刚果民主共和国的精英们正在玩的游戏不是增长和发展——它们是失败国家的例子。援助和发展伙伴在讨论的任何例子中都不是中心舞台,它们也不值得在展示中占据最重要的位置。尽管如此,由于它们在捐助国、非政府组织、多边银行或联合国的媒体和研究界的影响力,它们仍将自己视为头条新闻。这不是很有帮助——需要更多的谦卑和对自己角色真正重要性的认识。这并不意味着发展伙伴是无关紧要的。在发展协议已经存在或正在形成的地方,援助可以发挥巨大的有益补充作用,通过援助、技术支持,当然,通过关键的宣传来深化和加强发展协议,支持社会和经济的发展方向。考虑到加纳和孟加拉国的国家性质和发展协议,这两个国家有可能发挥这一作用。当开发交易不存在时,就需要谨慎。然后,(善意的)捐助者的目标与在这些国家有权力和影响力的人的目标不一致。因此,考虑到所涉及的政治交易的性质,外部支持所产生的激励机制是至关重要的。许多官方发展伙伴喜欢隐藏在他们“非政治”的本质背后。他们对国家的政治分析通常缺乏长期的历史和政治意识,以及潜在的社会和政治契约。关键的问题是,无论这些局外人如何努力为“发展”做出贡献,他们不仅会影响人们的结果,还会影响精英交易的潜在动机。如果做得好,发展伙伴的行动可能会改善人口的结果,但也会为更好的精英交易的出现和持续创造条件。然而,也完全有可能的是,做表面上“好的”事情,可能隐含着一种糟糕的精英交易,为不采取行动促进增长或发展提供借口。 事实上,正如书中所讨论的那样,随着时间的推移,我开始担心,在马拉维或尼日利亚等国家,援助和发展伙伴很可能会使情况变得更糟,因为在发展伙伴弥补其未能为人民带来进步的过程中,援助和发展伙伴很容易让政治行为体忽视变革的必要性,或者在南苏丹,人道主义援助甚至可能有助于加剧冲突。那么,该怎么办呢?首先,在全球范围内,努力制定激励措施,促使更好的精英讨价还价取得成功,同时削弱流氓精英讨价还价。例如,关注自然资源以外的出口往往是致力于增长的标志,因为与寻租精英有关的企业通常的诡计真的很难做到。因此,提供广泛的贸易优惠很少会奖励那些讨价还价的穷精英,而通常会鼓励那些体面的精英。同样,严肃打击非法金融——为流氓精英提供交易融资的关键工具——也将真正有助于改变激励机制。在国内该怎么做?这是最难的。当然,在刚果民主共和国、尼日利亚或马达加斯加等地,存在着大量反发展精英讨价还价的需求,同时也存在着巨大的贫困。因此,通过帮助那些受苦的人来做“好事”是一个光荣的目标。然而,我所要求的是,在做这件事的时候要睁大眼睛,意识到大规模的外部参与对这些国家的激励作用,使它们变得更加发展。不要把所有这些努力都贴上“发展”的标签,而最好是把它们贴上“做好事”的标签——当然,在这些经常功能失调的环境中,如何发挥最大的影响,仍然要使用最好的证据。然后,基于深刻的知识,也许有些人可以做得更多,小心翼翼,也许是秘密的。这可能涉及到与那些渴望变革的精英人士合作。或者与希望增长和发展的央行或部委的技术官僚合作。这可能意味着与政治领导人和公共知识分子合作,为重新设定一个国家的方向做出贡献。或者加强那些将从增长和广泛发展中受益的商界人士。它可能涉及支持公民社会呼吁透明度、更好的治理,或者实际上是权利。就我个人而言,我还不想放弃,我仍然认为,外部发展参与者可以为变革做出贡献——尽管发展体系内部的激励机制存在很多问题,比如要求人们看到自己能迅速取得成果的压力,或者狭隘地关注资金,这些往往会阻碍变革。而且,当我们谈论外人能做什么时,他们最好表现出谦逊和自我意识,当外人采取行动时,他们不一定会使事情变得更好。内奥米·侯赛因,华盛顿特区美国大学问责研究中心。ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-3244-2319“发展伙伴是否应该帮助达成发展协议,如果是,如何帮助?”这个问题,就像斯蒂芬的书一样,反映了一个更温和、更乐观的发展援助时代。它假定援助国是真诚的行为体,对减少贫困和促进包容和可持续的增长、和平与繁荣感兴趣。自冷战结束以来的20多年里,我们中的许多人一直在用这些假设工作。但目前尚不清楚这些假设是否仍然成立——如果它们曾经成立的话。当然,以前被称为国际发展部(DFID)的英国政府部门是一个适度进步的援助捐助国;它有可能支持在其有影响力的国家形成有利于穷人的政治交易。但以目前的形式,在英国脱欧后的极右翼保守党政府执政末期,英国外交部(Foreign, Commonwealth & &英国发展办公室(FCDO)主要致力于让英国企业在世界范围内获利,这是它毫不掩饰的事实。所以答案是否定的。像英国这样的援助国不应该参与发展谈判。没有理由相信,除了那些与精英有联系的人,这些交易将符合任何人的利益。无论如何,过去几年英国执政党的滑稽行为,已经让英国在全球南方国家眼中失去了善治捍卫者的信誉。Stefan指出,解决有罪不罚问题对于促成持久的发展交易至关重要,因为这使得腐败精英更难带着他们的非法战利品逃脱惩罚。然而,英国继续保护避税天堂和金融业的秘密,其目的是让精英们免于为腐败负责。他们怎么可能树立榜样呢?然而,援助国确实应该在发展中国家的发展谈判中被视为政治行动者。这不是因为他们应该参与进来,而是因为他们一直都在参与。 对发展的赌博对捐助者作为政治行动者的关注太少,认为他们似乎有能力从上面干净利落地干预政治,而不会产生不利后果或混乱的副作用。如果斯特凡能把曼彻斯特大学(University of Manchester)“有效国家与包容性发展”(Effective States and Inclusive Development)研究项目的见解包括进来,就会做得很好。该项目展示了捐助者如何在不同背景下塑造政治经济。捐助者已经是任何发展谈判的一部分,当谈判未能实现包容性发展时,捐助者应该承担一些责任。简而言之,捐助者不应该积极地帮助形成发展谈判,因为他们总是有可能灾难性地干涉其他国家的政治,但我们应该更加警惕这样一个事实,即捐助者已经参与了发展政治。“在短期内不太可能形成这样的交易的情况下,他们应该怎么做?”捐助者应该把手伸进口袋,找到适应、减缓气候变化和社会保护所需的资金。他们应该提供日益需要的人道主义援助,他们应该为世界上越来越多的难民和寻求庇护者提供援助。无论如何,他们都应该做这些事情,不管是否存在开发交易。这些国家在自己的发展道路上实现了工业化,向大气中排放了碳,并进行了殖民和掠夺,直到最近才干预国内政治,以寻求外交政策的影响力和权力。但是,在长期危机和生存失败的条件下,任何发展都是不可能的。人们必须能够在不担心下一次袭击、风暴或饥荒的情况下生活,才能利用开放市场提供的任何机会。《关于发展的赌博》中的发展讨价还价往往是投资于基本人类安全的成果,而不是刻意转向市场驱动的增长。斯特凡在他的书中描述得很好的大多数案例都是这样的例子:在灾难使一切照旧变得不可思议之后,精英们才就发展达成共识。战争、饥荒、灾难和种族灭绝是突出的特征,每一次都被证明是转折点。在这样的转折点上,《赌发展》的教训表明,援助国要么通过支持人道主义努力发挥作用,要么退让。马亮,中国人民大学ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-8779-5891Countries可以从发展援助中受益,但发展援助不应该影响国家的政策选择。发展援助不是没有价值的。它通常伴随着发展伙伴强烈的意识形态偏好,而这些偏好可能不适合发展中国家的当地情况。一刀切的发展合作项目无法解决发展中国家面临的关键挑战,更不用说帮助它们摆脱贫困陷阱了。各国在许多重要方面存在差异。发展方案应该针对具体国家,这意味着发展伙伴提供的方案不可能是万能的。做正确的事比把事情做好重要得多,发展伙伴应该意识到他们的角色和界限。发展中国家通常无法抗拒或忽视国际组织对发展援助所要求的条件。特别是后殖民国家很少有信心坚持具有本国特色的发展道路,往往会被发展伙伴的建议所困。强烈的民族主义可能进一步扭曲精英们的讨价还价,导致公民将发展援助贴上不爱国的标签,从而影响与发展伙伴的关系。1949年中华人民共和国成立后,中国从苏联那里学到了很多东西,但其中一些教训是痛苦的。苏联专家帮助中国建立了工业基础设施。由于对苏联的过度依赖,中国的工业结构不成比例地向重工业倾斜,而中央计划经济体制扼杀了地方的即兴创作,从而危及了中国经济。通过将自己的未来与苏联捆绑在一起,中国正在失去其经济主权。中国在20世纪70年代末改革开放后的显著增长可以归因于对西方的聪明学习。政府向西方国家学习,但保留了中国风格作为统治原则。例如,中国在行政改革方面借鉴了国际实践(如一站式服务),但又结合国内的考虑进行了改革。 在某些情况下,政府拒绝了建议,主要是在金融发展和监管领域。实际上,政府是一个聪明的购物者,将西方的做法与中国的做法结合起来,形成了一种具有中国特色的新型发展状态。我们可以从中国的经验中学到什么?不应过分强调发展援助。政府本身应该制定有效的政策来促进国家的发展。换句话说,发展伙伴可以提供意见和建议,但是国内精英集体做出对他们自己和国家发展至关重要的决定。中国的优点在于循序渐进的试错方法,这给了精英们支持发展的信心。校准和突出发展伙伴与国内精英之间的界限非常重要。发展伙伴可以作为顾问或知识经纪人,用最佳实践和证据激励和启发国家政府决策者,但他们不应该深入参与。他们来了又走,但这是国家政府的发展之旅。一些国家可能无法达成对可持续发展至关重要的精英交易。在这种情况下,发展伙伴可以在一定程度上提供帮助。要使习惯于获取短期利益的精英们相信发展的长期利益是具有挑战性的,因此发展伙伴必须开发出更有效的方法来促成发展谈判。例如,发展伙伴可以通过投资具体方案来提供帮助,但如果它们离开,它们的业务可能无法维持。相反,具有令人信服的示范和成就的试点项目可能有助于重塑精英们对发展的态度,讨价还价将会启动。发展伙伴应回归发展的根本意义。说到发展的本质,与其说是政治方面,不如说是经济和社会方面。没有融入当地发展社区的本土发展道路,各国就无法以可持续的方式发展。俗话说,授人以鱼不如授人以渔。以前,南北发展援助和政策转移很重要,但随着中国和其他经济体的崛起,南南模式正在发挥越来越重要的作用。中国在“一带一路”倡议中的主导作用不同于大多数其他发展援助。它生动地展示了发展伙伴如何在精英交易中提供帮助。“一带一路”关注并提供发展中国家真正需要的东西(如基础设施、农业和负担得起的融资),为未来的发展援助带来丰硕成果。中国是发展援助的受益者和借鉴者,发展了中国特色的发展援助模式,帮助其他发展中国家。与所有发展援助一样,中国的经验可能并不普遍适用。但是,其发展援助的精神可以转移到其他方面。Arkebe Oqubay,英国科学院全球教授、伦敦亚非学院实践教授,高级部长。2在此背景下,面临着重新思考国际发展方法的新压力。德康的书对思考援助,更广泛地说,是对发展的政治经济学的宝贵贡献。鉴于他的地位和经验,他对发展援助固有缺陷的看法将在捐助界具有很大的分量。在埃塞俄比亚担任高级政策制定者30多年的时间里,我与发展伙伴和发展援助机制一起工作,并密切观察了这段时间,埃塞俄比亚在1991年至2016年期间保持了10%及以上的经济增长率,平均预期寿命增加了22岁。埃塞俄比亚的发展模式赋予了发展型国家主导地位。它明确的程度和行使政策自主权,既引起了其他非洲国家的浓厚兴趣,也引起了主流媒体和国际发展界一些有影响人士的尖锐批评。我必须承认,我认为发展援助在经济发展中起次要作用。这种关系总是受到政治紧张局势的影响,其积极贡献主要来自受援国政府的发展战略和政策。在这一点上,我非常同意德康的观点,即官方发展援助在发展的戏剧中充其量只是“一小部分”。事实证明,强加一长串附加条件和向发展中国家大量提供国际顾问的有益建议,并不是实现长期持续增长和经济转型的良方。 埃塞俄比亚政府经常以非常合理的理由抵制捐助者的压力、附加条件和对内部政治的干涉,正如我从20世纪90年代初开始反复目睹的那样。约瑟夫·斯蒂格利茨(Joseph Stiglitz)描述了国际货币基金组织(IMF)对埃塞俄比亚银行业自由化施加的压力(Stiglitz, 2001);特朗普执政期间,世界银行毫无根据地参与了尼罗河上具有地缘政治争议的大埃塞俄比亚复兴大坝(GERD)的谈判,这是非洲最大的水电站大坝,都是很好的例子(van Eyssen, 2020)。也有促进经济转型的积极例子,包括:日本对工业政策对话的支持;德国大学、职业和技术教育改革方案;英国对促进投资和工业化的援助;以及美国对农村初级保健的支持。然而,关键在于,每一项改革都是由政府直接主导的。然而,捐助者的想法和优先事项往往与发展中国家的长期发展战略、政策和优先事项不一致。资源是每年承诺的,因此很难依靠它们进行长期投资,特别是当捐助者经常改变他们的“口味”偏好时。“发展讨价还价”的概念很可能在过时之前走上t台,就像“增长诊断”、“善治议程”以及之前的“华盛顿共识”一样。发展援助也随着捐助国国内政治的变化而波动。无论“伙伴关系”的口号是什么,捐助国政府通常都是单方面做出援助决定,这凸显了一种根本的权力不对称。援助往往冒着从根本上破坏发展轨迹的风险,正如华盛顿共识政策对非洲国家造成的破坏所看到的那样,而且(必须说,这些国家往往有热心的支持者)拆除了国家和工业政策机构。援助关系也经常受到复杂的主流媒体、官僚机构、咨询机构和有影响力的政策知识分子精心策划的持续不断的意识形态轰炸的影响。斯蒂芬·德康(Stefan Dercon)关于捐助者如何影响精英讨价还价的建议,有一种傲慢的风险,他含蓄地假设捐助者有正确的想法,因此问题只是如何最好地调整发展中国家利益集团之间的“讨价还价”,以便后者更顺利地吸收这些想法,以及随之而来的援助。同样的传统智慧(激进的“休克疗法”放松管制和自由化)是20世纪70年代中期与中国接触的一个强大特征,就像苏联解体之后一样。伊莎贝拉•韦伯(Isabella Weber)的著作《中国如何逃脱休克疗法》(How China escape shock therapy)表明,如果中国采纳了许多国际建议的智慧,那么中国的改革将会失败。我的观点是,不能假设捐助国的传统智慧——无论在任何特定时间是什么——最适合各种发展中国家的需要,这些国家需要形成自己的政策理念,培养自己的决策能力。政策独立性首先是试验和从成功与失败中学习的自由。在“援助关系”之外,德康的书对近年来发展转型思考的前沿概念进行了重要讨论。他强调“精英交易”或“政治解决”的概念是经济增长模式的关键,这是非常正确的——尤其是由穆斯塔克·汗、乔纳森·迪·约翰和詹姆斯·普策尔等人提出的想法。他也正确地反驳了一种流行的观点,即一套特定的制度是经济增长的先决条件。在这里,他继承了阿尔伯特·赫希曼(Albert Hirschman)更早的见解,以及张夏准(Ha-Joon Chang)等近代思想家的见解。他普及了这种思想,这是有帮助的,但他的方法仍然提出了问题。选定的国家案例是基于宽松的标准——比如每年4%到5%的适度增长和有效的政治交易——这引发了一个问题,即政治经济和发展道路不同的国家(如中国和孟加拉国,加纳和埃塞俄比亚,印度和卢旺达)能否被归为同一篮子。这些经济体之间的差异比任何共同之处都重要。 这些国家在经济追赶和转型中采取了哪些经济政策?国家在发展中扮演了什么样的角色?他们在哪些方面“定价错误”,而不是遵循“定价正确”的建议?什么样的伙伴关系是政府、私营部门、科学界和更广泛的社会之间关系的特点?而且,如果精英们真的达成了有利于增长的“协议”,那么是如何达成的,又是为什么达成的?根据我国的经验,这实际上与外部捐助者毫无关系。事实上,由于捐助者试图塑造政治解决方案,可能会产生许多意想不到的后果和“蝴蝶效应”。在《非洲经济发展:证据、理论和政策》(Cramer et al., 2020)一书中,我和我的同事Christopher Cramer和John Sender认为,理解不平衡和变化的驱动因素是学习发展的重要来源。我们坚持认为,一个国家的经济发展前景取决于这个国家做了什么,以及由此产生的结果是什么,而不是取决于它拥有什么和现在是什么——这可能包括一些黑匣子“交易”,这些交易通常只有在事后才能确定。以发展为赌注将激发关于概念问题和实际发展挑战的富有成效的辩论,我祝贺Stefan的贡献。它应该有助于推动讨论和理解向前发展。ODI常务董事Rathin Roy的重要叙述使我们能够过渡到对发展合作的政治经济的更对称的反思。德康的核心前提是,国内精英很重要,他们的政治契约反映在一个统制国家的行动中,影响着发展计划的成败。虽然他关注的是外部干预的有效性,但这篇论文是独立的。同样,他对外部发展参与者声称自己是发展成功的功名者,以及他们所谓的“非政治”干预建议的基础进行了雄辩的痛斥,这与关于发展中国家发展帝国主义的论述产生了共鸣,这是一种适用于援助、结构调整以及最近的气候论述的政治经济学批判。编辑们提出的问题是:“如果援助在达成发展协议的地方效果最好,那么在这种情况下,援助应该做什么?”更重要的是,援助在缺乏发展协议的国家应该做些什么?“如果从字面上理解,就不能通过Dercon测试;他们完全不关心政治。因此,我对长期和短期问题都提出了政治经济学的回答。从这个有利的角度来看,时间维度并不直接相关。发展行为体不能帮助形成发展交易。从表面上看,他们似乎可以;优惠贸易安排可能帮助孟加拉国发展了服装工业,使其走上了繁荣之路。但这就忽略了德康理论的核心原则——外部行动者只能以一种与国家努力相辅相成的方式行事。尽管有着共同的历史,受到军事干涉的困扰,有着相似甚至共同的根源的精英,为什么孟加拉国做到了巴基斯坦做不到的事情——培育全球服装业,建立国内金融机构,改善人类发展成果?值得注意的是,在德康强调的许多成功案例中——印度、孟加拉国、越南、中国、卢旺达——精英们做出的经济、政治和社会政策选择不是为了“发展”,而是为了培养经济民族主义,以对抗当前或最近的生存威胁——殖民主义、分裂、种族灭绝。这些选择并不是发展理论的核心,而是为了防止再殖民,在分裂中幸存下来,避免鸦片霸权的重演,维护通过与超级大国竞争而赢得的统一。精英们的交易是通过执行这些反霸权的选择来合法统治,这些选择在触发事件后的许多年里推动了经济政策。印度、中国和越南在踏上发展之旅后的许多年里,甚至没有把消除贫困作为其发展和规划战略的宗旨。转型的必要性与发展的必要性交织在一起,因为它与一个经济现代化项目有关,该项目使许多这些国家能够跨越依赖水平,但不是发展阶段。对于出于意识形态亲和或共同利益的原因而参与其中的外部行动者来说,这些交易可以带来重大价值,就像韩国和卢旺达一样。否则,它们就是无关紧要的。像印度这样的贫穷国家,由于投资于“超出其收入水平的科学和技术”而受到许多西方大国的蔑视,这反映了对这样做的逻辑缺乏理解。 为什么?历史,长期的历史,很重要,因为它形成了德康教授希望达成发展协议的国家和精英。尽管德康认为,恩克鲁玛是一个比经济学家更好的政治战略家,但恩克鲁玛毫不含糊地解释了他自己的国家和非洲其他国家所面临的深刻的经济挑战。事实是,对于绝大多数国家来说,大谈判的问题不是一个国家内部的土地谈判,而是与国际伙伴的谈判。或者更确切地说,是一场宏大的斗争。从更长远的角度来看,所有的“成功”和“失败”都在于它们是否能够摆脱国际贸易和投资的殖民模式——通常是榨取模式——的束缚。例如,中国从1978年开始“走出去”的成功,不仅在于“邀请”外国直接投资,还在于有信心迫使外国投资者遵守中国的规则。这样的政策——以及印度、埃塞俄比亚和其他国家的一些政策——在当时,甚至现在,都被视为与他们的捐助者的利益直接对立。然而,事后看来,这些政策显然有利于发展。相比之下,例如,刚果民主共和国今天未能摆脱其采掘业国家的地位,可以更好地解释为,尽管外国矿业公司在英国和其他“捐赠”国受到监管和资助,但它们仍以各种方式合法地控制着该国,而不是把重点放在国内精英之间缺乏发展协议上。我和德康完全同意援助的作用。援助几乎无法改变这些结构性环境,甚至可能分散人们对它们的注意力。但从更长远、更全面的历史观来看,我想对德康的理论加以补充,认为鼓励国际合作伙伴为国内的大交易建立能力也是不够的。真正的诀窍在于,国际合作伙伴要认识到,有必要提供可能与他们既定的国家和商业利益相悖的东西,以及/或与既定的多边准则相悖的东西。从历史的长远来看,发展伙伴更需要支持外部的宏大斗争,而不是鼓励内部的发展交易。这并不容易,也可能不可能,但一场有根据的发展辩论和变革理论需要以更谦逊的态度开始,对历史和强加给全球南方的结构有更多的认识。出于这个原因,我很高兴德康写了这本书,以帮助推动我们的职业走上这段艰难的旅程。Kunal Sen, UNU-WIDER和曼彻斯特大学ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5439-6619In赌发展,Stefan Dercon认为,那些成功实现基础广泛发展的国家,并不是通过完善的制度实现的,而是精英们形成了发展协议,即“一个国家精英成员对增长和发展的潜在承诺”(Dercon, 2022,第4页)。经济发展不太可能发生。德康进一步认为,发展交易是精英们的一场赌博,因为成功并不能得到保证,在职精英可能会在这个过程中失去权力。发展伙伴在达成发展协议方面发挥什么作用?Dercon认为,在发展协议已经存在或正在形成的国家,援助可以在提供技术支持和建议以深化和加强发展协议方面发挥非常重要的补充作用。德康以孟加拉国和加纳为例,说明援助在促进发展谈判的出现方面发挥了促进作用。这似乎是明智的建议,与Pritchett、Sen和Werker所指出的一致,他们认为持续的经济增长是由包容性或支持增长的解决方案支撑的,对广泛增长感兴趣的选区在谈判桌上获得了一席之地,援助可以影响政治解决方案的性质,至少在边际上(Pritchett等人,2018)。这里的挑战在于认识到真正的发展交易何时形成,而不是“同质模仿”,即精英们提供包容性政治解决方案的表面,以吸引援助(例如,通过阶段管理的选举),而现实却截然不同。当我们回顾孟加拉国和加纳的成功故事时,事后诸葛明会有什么好处吗?杰里·罗林斯(Jerry Rawlings) 1981年在加纳掌权,并暂停宪法,有效地禁止了该国的政党,这一发展交易是否显而易见?专制统治的开始也是加纳经济开始快速增长的时期,随后持续了几十年。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
Development Policy Review
Development Policy Review DEVELOPMENT STUDIES-
CiteScore
3.50
自引率
5.90%
发文量
87
期刊介绍: Development Policy Review is the refereed journal that makes the crucial links between research and policy in international development. Edited by staff of the Overseas Development Institute, the London-based think-tank on international development and humanitarian issues, it publishes single articles and theme issues on topics at the forefront of current development policy debate. Coverage includes the latest thinking and research on poverty-reduction strategies, inequality and social exclusion, property rights and sustainable livelihoods, globalisation in trade and finance, and the reform of global governance. Informed, rigorous, multi-disciplinary and up-to-the-minute, DPR is an indispensable tool for development researchers and practitioners alike.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信