Madeleine Fairbairn. Fields of Gold: Financing the Global Land Rush

IF 0.8 Q1 HISTORY
B. O’Neill
{"title":"Madeleine Fairbairn. Fields of Gold: Financing the Global Land Rush","authors":"B. O’Neill","doi":"10.1515/ngs-2022-0031","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"In the late-aughts, a surge of transnational investment in farmland became a major driver of land dispossession and concentration, agrarian protest, and ultimately scholarship. Although geographers and other social scientists had studied various forms of land dispossession for decades,1 those who entered the topic through this new wave of transnational farmland investment quickly advanced terms like “the global land grab” or the “the global land rush”, while alarmed NGOs sought to quantify it based on “deals” signed between investors and host governments. Since land grabbing was not, of course, new, such constructions begged the question of what, if any, relationship existed between these transnational investments in farmland qua farmland and other longstanding forms of rural land dispossession for mining, industry, and urban real estate – all of which also appeared to be increasing and changing in character in many regions during the neoliberal period. Then there was the problem of whether all of these transnational farmland “deals” actually involved “grabs”, which implies coercive dispossession. Since many evidently did not and farmers continued to lose land in many other ways, another vein of scholarship pushed back against the growing focus on coercive “land grabs” with the finding that dispossession could be driven by the market (Li 2014; Vijayabaskar and Menon 2018), though the dynamics of this process – land concentration and agrarian differentiation – had already been the bread and butter of “the agrarian question” for over a century (Kautsky 1988; Lenin 1964; Patnaik 1990). Further debates over whether land grabs constituted “primitive accumulation” (Marx 1977) or “accumulation by dispossession” (Harvey 2003) often created","PeriodicalId":42013,"journal":{"name":"New Global Studies","volume":"0 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.8000,"publicationDate":"2022-06-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"New Global Studies","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1515/ngs-2022-0031","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"HISTORY","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

In the late-aughts, a surge of transnational investment in farmland became a major driver of land dispossession and concentration, agrarian protest, and ultimately scholarship. Although geographers and other social scientists had studied various forms of land dispossession for decades,1 those who entered the topic through this new wave of transnational farmland investment quickly advanced terms like “the global land grab” or the “the global land rush”, while alarmed NGOs sought to quantify it based on “deals” signed between investors and host governments. Since land grabbing was not, of course, new, such constructions begged the question of what, if any, relationship existed between these transnational investments in farmland qua farmland and other longstanding forms of rural land dispossession for mining, industry, and urban real estate – all of which also appeared to be increasing and changing in character in many regions during the neoliberal period. Then there was the problem of whether all of these transnational farmland “deals” actually involved “grabs”, which implies coercive dispossession. Since many evidently did not and farmers continued to lose land in many other ways, another vein of scholarship pushed back against the growing focus on coercive “land grabs” with the finding that dispossession could be driven by the market (Li 2014; Vijayabaskar and Menon 2018), though the dynamics of this process – land concentration and agrarian differentiation – had already been the bread and butter of “the agrarian question” for over a century (Kautsky 1988; Lenin 1964; Patnaik 1990). Further debates over whether land grabs constituted “primitive accumulation” (Marx 1977) or “accumulation by dispossession” (Harvey 2003) often created
玛德琳费尔贝恩。金矿:为全球土地热融资
在20世纪后期,跨国农业投资的激增成为土地剥夺和集中、土地抗议以及最终的学术研究的主要推动力。虽然地理学家和其他社会科学家已经研究了几十年各种形式的土地剥夺,但那些通过这波新的跨国农田投资浪潮进入这个话题的人很快提出了“全球土地掠夺”或“全球土地热潮”这样的术语,而警惕的非政府组织则试图根据投资者和东道国政府之间签署的“协议”来量化它。当然,由于土地掠夺并不是什么新鲜事,这样的结构提出了这样一个问题:这些跨国农田投资与其他长期存在的用于采矿、工业和城市房地产的农村土地剥夺形式之间存在什么关系?在新自由主义时期,所有这些形式在许多地区的性质上似乎都在增加和变化。还有一个问题是,所有这些跨国农田“交易”是否都涉及“掠夺”,这意味着强制剥夺。由于许多人显然没有这样做,农民继续以许多其他方式失去土地,另一种学术形式反对日益关注的强制性“土地掠夺”,发现剥夺可能是由市场驱动的(Li 2014;Vijayabaskar和Menon 2018),尽管这一过程的动力——土地集中和土地分化——已经成为一个多世纪以来“土地问题”的主要内容(考茨基1988;列宁1964;Patnaik 1990)。关于土地掠夺是构成“原始积累”(马克思,1977)还是“剥夺积累”(哈维,2003)的进一步争论经常产生
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
CiteScore
0.80
自引率
25.00%
发文量
28
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信