{"title":"Battlers and Billionaires: The Updated Story of Inequality in Australia by Leigh, Andrew 2024","authors":"Roger Wilkins","doi":"10.1111/1467-8462.70000","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>Economic inequality is an important issue deserving of the considerable attention it now receives among applied economics researchers, reflecting the reality that the distribution of economic output is almost as important to community wellbeing as the total quantity of output. While many questions remain unanswered, there is now a substantial body of Australian research on the topic and a correspondingly improved understanding of the nature, causes and consequences of inequality in Australia.</p><p>However, the translation of this body of knowledge to the general public was somewhat lacking until Leigh's <span>2013</span> book, Battlers and Billionaires (Leigh <span>2013</span>), which provided an accessible overview of the evolution of inequality in Australia, its drivers and consequences, and proposals for ways to reduce it. It therefore provided a valuable resource for informing public discourse on this important subject.</p><p>In Leigh (<span>2024</span>), the author provides an update to Leigh (<span>2013</span>). As would be expected of an “update,” much of the material in this book is the same as in the original book. The main differences are the addition of more recent data and a few extra graphs, discussion of new research published since the first book was published, a few tweaks to the stories told and the way the material is explained, and the addition of two recommendations for “what is to be done.” The general story and the key messages have not changed and therefore the book is probably targeted at people who have not read the first book.</p><p>As with Leigh (<span>2013</span>), this is a highly enjoyable read, with Leigh complementing the well-researched empirical facts with engaging and often entertaining historical facts, stories and anecdotes. The book is written for a general audience, with technical details and sources consigned to endnotes. It succeeds in being accessible to non-experts, although I suspect much of it will nonetheless be somewhat heavy going for many readers.</p><p>The book contains eight chapters, the first three of which describe the evolution of inequality in Australia from pre-colonization to the present day. Chapter 4 then examines the drivers of inequality, mainly focusing on recent decades. Chapter 5 discusses the consequences of inequality; Chapter 6 addresses the issue of intergenerational economic mobility and Chapter 7 discusses community attitudes to inequality. He concludes in Chapter 8 with a list of recommendations for addressing inequality.</p><p>In broad terms, the story told in the first three chapters of the evolution of inequality in Australia is correct: inequality levels and trends pre-federation are uncertain, but inequality was probably very high over most of the nineteenth century. Inequality then decreased between federation and the 1970s, and then subsequently increased.</p><p>The description of inequality trends is most balanced over the period to the early 1980s, when data availability is limited and the evidence is patchy. However, for the last 40 years, when considerably more data is available, which Leigh labels “The Great Divergence,” he offers a somewhat selective coverage of inequality trends, ignoring the many nuances and deviations from the “inequality is ever rising” narrative that he prosecutes for this period. While there is little doubt that inequality today is higher than in the early 1980s, much of the increase occurred in the 1980s and 1990s. The changes that have occurred this century are more mixed and complicated. On some metrics, such as top income share estimates based on tax data, there has been some increase in inequality; on others, such as HILDA Survey measures of overall inequality, there has been little change (Wilkins, Vera-Toscano, and Botha <span>2023</span>). While Leigh might be defended as not wanting to unnecessarily muddy the waters, the fact is the waters are muddy and his is not a disinterested treatment of the topic.</p><p>Here I also cannot resist the (self-serving) observation that he makes insufficient use of the HILDA Survey for describing and explaining the post-2000 environment (despite being a user of the unit record data himself). The HILDA Survey is the only source providing annual household income data, as well as providing rich information on intra- and intergenerational mobility and a multitude of other economic and social phenomena. For example, Leigh speculates whether US evidence on the greater instability of de facto relationships compared with legal marriages translates to Australia. But there is no need to speculate! We have evidence from HILDA that this is indeed the case (Wilkins et al. <span>2022</span>). And while he does discuss research on intergenerational mobility drawing on HILDA, the evidence HILDA has provided on poverty persistence and intergenerational “transmission” of disadvantage is ignored (e.g., Rodgers <span>2010</span>, Vera-Toscano and Wilkins <span>2020</span>, Parolin et al. <span>2024</span>).</p><p>Which leads me to the general observation that Leigh's discussion of inequality has a disproportionate focus on the top of the income and wealth distributions—too much attention on the billionaires and not enough on the battlers. This is more defensible for the pre-1980s period, when the available data is skewed towards the rich. And perhaps the fortunes of the rich produce better stories and provide reasons for concern about inequality that are more compelling to lay readers. Certainly, I can appreciate that it is difficult to convey that inequalities in the “middle 80%” matter. However, this does not excuse the light treatment of the poor and what being poor means for day-to-day life, at least in present-day Australia. For example, in discussing the period since the 1980s, fully four pages of the chapter are devoted to how the rich find ways to spend their money, while the plight of the poor is given only one paragraph. It is entertaining to read about the consumption possibilities of the extremely rich, but this adds little of substance to the story.</p><p>In examining drivers of inequality change, Leigh canvasses factors considered by the literature and presents a good summary of the findings, highlighting the roles of technology and globalization, taxation and education. He is, however, probably more enthusiastic about the inequality-reducing potential of education than warranted. There are good reasons to support education expansion, but its history in reducing inequality is somewhat mixed. More controversial is the important role he assigns to unions. While there is international evidence that unions tend to decrease <i>earnings</i> inequality, the evidence that this translates to lower <i>income</i> inequality is less clear—indeed, the only references cited by Leigh here examine the relationship between union density and earnings inequality, not income inequality.</p><p>The fact that earnings inequality does not directly translate to income inequality is a point more broadly missed in Leigh's treatment of the drivers of changes in inequality in Australia over the last 40 years. The key reason for the disconnect between earnings and income inequality is the role of the distribution of employment across households. Most notably, there has been a dramatic increase in labor force participation of women over the last 40 years, and this has evolved in a non-neutral manner with respect to income inequality. In the 1980s and 1990s, much of the growth in female employment was in households containing relatively high-earning males, acting to increase income inequality (Johnson and Wilkins <span>2004</span>). In the early 2000s, by contrast, much of the growth was in households containing relatively low-earning males or previously jobless households (Greenville, Pobke, and Rogers <span>2013</span>, Sula and Dugain <span>2019</span>). This is part of the reason why inequality patterns over the 2000s and 2010s have been more nuanced: despite rising earnings inequality, measures of overall income inequality such as the Gini coefficient have changed little, and this is because of the nature of the changes in employment participation, particularly of women.</p><p>Also under-discussed for its role in affecting inequality is welfare policy. The design of the Australian income support system is a key influence on income inequality, and indeed it has done less to reduce inequality in recent years than it did in the 1990s. Measures such as tightening eligibility for Parenting Payment Single and the Disability Support Pension in the 2000s and 2010s had substantial negative impacts on single parents and people with disability. Also of note is the increase in family benefits between the late 1980s and the early 2000s, which positively impacted the incomes of low- and middle-income families with children and resulted in declines in child poverty (Redmond <span>2012</span>). When it comes to welfare and other government cash and in-kind benefits, Leigh's main observation is that all benefits should be targeted via means tests. This is not self-evidently true, and many universal (or near-universal) schemes have substantial inequality-reducing effects.</p><p>Leigh's discussion of the drivers of inequality (and also what to do about it) focuses on income inequality and is largely silent on the drivers of <i>wealth</i> inequality. Indeed, his excessive focus on the <i>very</i> wealthy means he does not even mention the generational lines along which wealth inequality has grown and the important failures of housing policy in exacerbating this trend. Similarly not mentioned is that the expansion of superannuation since the early 1990s has acted to increased wealth inequality, with policy changes over the last decade only slightly moderating its worst excesses.</p><p>In the chapter on economic mobility, Leigh's focus is on intergenerational mobility. Here he addresses what he considers the delicate issue of the role of family structure in perpetuating disadvantage. While he correctly identifies growing up in a single-parent family as a strong predictor of disadvantage in adulthood, the inferences he draws from this are questionable. In essence, he ends up advocating for more parents to be legally married, citing US evidence that de facto marriages are less stable, and noting that single-parent families tend to be short on both money and parental time to invest in their children. Not considered by Leigh is the role that family poverty may itself play in precipitating family breakdown, as well as the fact that parents living apart need not reduce the parental resources available to the children (e.g., via “shared-care” arrangements).</p><p>Leigh is quite restrained in the consequences he is prepared to attribute to greater inequality. He first addresses so-called “instrumental” effects, whereby inequality affects other outcomes we care about. His assessment of the evidence is that inequality is positively associated with economic growth and may be negatively associated with social mobility and democratic functioning, while there is no relationship with other outcomes often hypothesized to be affected, such as crime rates and public health (although that does not stop him citing, in the Introduction, adverse health outcomes of the poor and longer life expectancies of the rich as reasons to be concerned about inequality). While I agree the evidence is generally not strong for instrumental effects, it is also true that there are few opportunities for credible empirical identification of these effects. I therefore lean more towards the view that we don't have strong evidence one way or the other, noting that absence of evidence does not necessarily imply evidence of absence of these effects.</p><p>Leigh then turns to “intrinsic” arguments, and here is where he thinks the main argument for concern about inequality lies: people do not like it. His chapter on Australians’ attitudes to inequality, therefore, takes on importance for his argument that it is desirable to reduce inequality. Leigh presents evidence that a majority of Australians believe inequality is too high, although one must be left to wonder why policies to reduce inequality have not met with more electoral success. Perhaps when the rubber hits the road in terms of specific measures that would reduce inequality, people find they are not so keen. Leigh goes further, to suggest that Australians have always been egalitarian in spirit. But the examples given are far from convincing and often reflect a highly conditional notion of egalitarianism, for example, based on sex, race or employment status. Leigh also appeals to salary caps (among other measures) in Australian professional sporting codes as evidence of an egalitarian spirit. However, salary caps are common in other countries, including the US, and are much more about attracting fans than a concern for fairness.</p><p>In the last chapter of the book, Leigh puts forward ten recommendations for reducing inequality. These are generally sound and reasonable, but one cannot but help think that he is constrained by his position in the Labor Party and more particularly his roles in the Labor Government ministry. Most recommendations are sorely lacking in specific policy actions, instead coming across as “areas we should direct attention”; moreover, there are glaring omissions.</p><p>Most strikingly, his recommendations on both welfare and tax policy are best described as tepid. His only recommendation for welfare policy is that we continue to ensure it is targeted to those most in need. There is no acknowledgment that the <i>level</i> of welfare benefits might matter, nor that an excessive focus on targeting can be detrimental to their capacity to reduce inequality. His only recommendation on tax policy is that we maintain a progressive income tax. There is no mention of eliminating or reducing concessional (or zero) taxation of certain income sources (such as from superannuation), increasing taxes on economic rents, or introducing taxes on wealth or inheritances.</p><p>One also suspects that political considerations play a role in Leigh's argument for the role of unions. The case made is weak—indeed, in responding to the critique that unions look after insiders (their members) at the expense of outsiders (including the unemployed), the best defence he can mount is that other interest groups do the same thing. This is, of course, true, but then I'm not aware that anyone is arguing these other interest groups reduce inequality.</p><p>Leigh is more convincing in his advocacy for maintaining policy expertise that delivers economic growth, improving the evaluation of social policies, improving our education system, keeping a check on monopoly power and reducing social isolation. These are goals that most Labor Party members, and probably most members of the Australian community, would regard as uncontroversial, albeit with no clear roadmap provided for achieving them.</p><p>Perhaps where Leigh is on the most dangerous political ground is in his advocacy for (largely unspecified) policies to reduce single-parenthood. Leigh treads very carefully, suggesting “light-touch programs that encourage relationship stability.” Here, however, he neglects the important potential role of policy in both addressing the adverse economic circumstances that often contribute to family breakdown and reducing the strength of the association between single-parent families and poverty. Policies that increase the economic resources of families, and especially single-parent families, combined with policies to promote the involvement of both parents in raising their children, irrespective of whether the parents live together, are more likely to meet with success than what Leigh proposes.</p><p>Leigh (<span>2024</span>) shows an admirable commitment to drawing on peer-reviewed research for a book targeting a nonacademic audience, doing so in a way that mostly does not drown the reader in detail (noting that I would be one of the few readers who enjoyed reading the endnotes as much as the text). I found the book illuminating and a very helpful tool for reflecting on the current state of our knowledge about inequality in Australia. While I have my quibbles, I fully commend the book to anyone seeking to understanding the evolution of economic inequality in Australia and who would like to enrich their thinking about what it means for Australian society and what, if anything, policy makers should do about it.</p>","PeriodicalId":46348,"journal":{"name":"Australian Economic Review","volume":"58 2","pages":"173-176"},"PeriodicalIF":1.0000,"publicationDate":"2025-02-04","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/1467-8462.70000","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Australian Economic Review","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/1467-8462.70000","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Abstract
Economic inequality is an important issue deserving of the considerable attention it now receives among applied economics researchers, reflecting the reality that the distribution of economic output is almost as important to community wellbeing as the total quantity of output. While many questions remain unanswered, there is now a substantial body of Australian research on the topic and a correspondingly improved understanding of the nature, causes and consequences of inequality in Australia.
However, the translation of this body of knowledge to the general public was somewhat lacking until Leigh's 2013 book, Battlers and Billionaires (Leigh 2013), which provided an accessible overview of the evolution of inequality in Australia, its drivers and consequences, and proposals for ways to reduce it. It therefore provided a valuable resource for informing public discourse on this important subject.
In Leigh (2024), the author provides an update to Leigh (2013). As would be expected of an “update,” much of the material in this book is the same as in the original book. The main differences are the addition of more recent data and a few extra graphs, discussion of new research published since the first book was published, a few tweaks to the stories told and the way the material is explained, and the addition of two recommendations for “what is to be done.” The general story and the key messages have not changed and therefore the book is probably targeted at people who have not read the first book.
As with Leigh (2013), this is a highly enjoyable read, with Leigh complementing the well-researched empirical facts with engaging and often entertaining historical facts, stories and anecdotes. The book is written for a general audience, with technical details and sources consigned to endnotes. It succeeds in being accessible to non-experts, although I suspect much of it will nonetheless be somewhat heavy going for many readers.
The book contains eight chapters, the first three of which describe the evolution of inequality in Australia from pre-colonization to the present day. Chapter 4 then examines the drivers of inequality, mainly focusing on recent decades. Chapter 5 discusses the consequences of inequality; Chapter 6 addresses the issue of intergenerational economic mobility and Chapter 7 discusses community attitudes to inequality. He concludes in Chapter 8 with a list of recommendations for addressing inequality.
In broad terms, the story told in the first three chapters of the evolution of inequality in Australia is correct: inequality levels and trends pre-federation are uncertain, but inequality was probably very high over most of the nineteenth century. Inequality then decreased between federation and the 1970s, and then subsequently increased.
The description of inequality trends is most balanced over the period to the early 1980s, when data availability is limited and the evidence is patchy. However, for the last 40 years, when considerably more data is available, which Leigh labels “The Great Divergence,” he offers a somewhat selective coverage of inequality trends, ignoring the many nuances and deviations from the “inequality is ever rising” narrative that he prosecutes for this period. While there is little doubt that inequality today is higher than in the early 1980s, much of the increase occurred in the 1980s and 1990s. The changes that have occurred this century are more mixed and complicated. On some metrics, such as top income share estimates based on tax data, there has been some increase in inequality; on others, such as HILDA Survey measures of overall inequality, there has been little change (Wilkins, Vera-Toscano, and Botha 2023). While Leigh might be defended as not wanting to unnecessarily muddy the waters, the fact is the waters are muddy and his is not a disinterested treatment of the topic.
Here I also cannot resist the (self-serving) observation that he makes insufficient use of the HILDA Survey for describing and explaining the post-2000 environment (despite being a user of the unit record data himself). The HILDA Survey is the only source providing annual household income data, as well as providing rich information on intra- and intergenerational mobility and a multitude of other economic and social phenomena. For example, Leigh speculates whether US evidence on the greater instability of de facto relationships compared with legal marriages translates to Australia. But there is no need to speculate! We have evidence from HILDA that this is indeed the case (Wilkins et al. 2022). And while he does discuss research on intergenerational mobility drawing on HILDA, the evidence HILDA has provided on poverty persistence and intergenerational “transmission” of disadvantage is ignored (e.g., Rodgers 2010, Vera-Toscano and Wilkins 2020, Parolin et al. 2024).
Which leads me to the general observation that Leigh's discussion of inequality has a disproportionate focus on the top of the income and wealth distributions—too much attention on the billionaires and not enough on the battlers. This is more defensible for the pre-1980s period, when the available data is skewed towards the rich. And perhaps the fortunes of the rich produce better stories and provide reasons for concern about inequality that are more compelling to lay readers. Certainly, I can appreciate that it is difficult to convey that inequalities in the “middle 80%” matter. However, this does not excuse the light treatment of the poor and what being poor means for day-to-day life, at least in present-day Australia. For example, in discussing the period since the 1980s, fully four pages of the chapter are devoted to how the rich find ways to spend their money, while the plight of the poor is given only one paragraph. It is entertaining to read about the consumption possibilities of the extremely rich, but this adds little of substance to the story.
In examining drivers of inequality change, Leigh canvasses factors considered by the literature and presents a good summary of the findings, highlighting the roles of technology and globalization, taxation and education. He is, however, probably more enthusiastic about the inequality-reducing potential of education than warranted. There are good reasons to support education expansion, but its history in reducing inequality is somewhat mixed. More controversial is the important role he assigns to unions. While there is international evidence that unions tend to decrease earnings inequality, the evidence that this translates to lower income inequality is less clear—indeed, the only references cited by Leigh here examine the relationship between union density and earnings inequality, not income inequality.
The fact that earnings inequality does not directly translate to income inequality is a point more broadly missed in Leigh's treatment of the drivers of changes in inequality in Australia over the last 40 years. The key reason for the disconnect between earnings and income inequality is the role of the distribution of employment across households. Most notably, there has been a dramatic increase in labor force participation of women over the last 40 years, and this has evolved in a non-neutral manner with respect to income inequality. In the 1980s and 1990s, much of the growth in female employment was in households containing relatively high-earning males, acting to increase income inequality (Johnson and Wilkins 2004). In the early 2000s, by contrast, much of the growth was in households containing relatively low-earning males or previously jobless households (Greenville, Pobke, and Rogers 2013, Sula and Dugain 2019). This is part of the reason why inequality patterns over the 2000s and 2010s have been more nuanced: despite rising earnings inequality, measures of overall income inequality such as the Gini coefficient have changed little, and this is because of the nature of the changes in employment participation, particularly of women.
Also under-discussed for its role in affecting inequality is welfare policy. The design of the Australian income support system is a key influence on income inequality, and indeed it has done less to reduce inequality in recent years than it did in the 1990s. Measures such as tightening eligibility for Parenting Payment Single and the Disability Support Pension in the 2000s and 2010s had substantial negative impacts on single parents and people with disability. Also of note is the increase in family benefits between the late 1980s and the early 2000s, which positively impacted the incomes of low- and middle-income families with children and resulted in declines in child poverty (Redmond 2012). When it comes to welfare and other government cash and in-kind benefits, Leigh's main observation is that all benefits should be targeted via means tests. This is not self-evidently true, and many universal (or near-universal) schemes have substantial inequality-reducing effects.
Leigh's discussion of the drivers of inequality (and also what to do about it) focuses on income inequality and is largely silent on the drivers of wealth inequality. Indeed, his excessive focus on the very wealthy means he does not even mention the generational lines along which wealth inequality has grown and the important failures of housing policy in exacerbating this trend. Similarly not mentioned is that the expansion of superannuation since the early 1990s has acted to increased wealth inequality, with policy changes over the last decade only slightly moderating its worst excesses.
In the chapter on economic mobility, Leigh's focus is on intergenerational mobility. Here he addresses what he considers the delicate issue of the role of family structure in perpetuating disadvantage. While he correctly identifies growing up in a single-parent family as a strong predictor of disadvantage in adulthood, the inferences he draws from this are questionable. In essence, he ends up advocating for more parents to be legally married, citing US evidence that de facto marriages are less stable, and noting that single-parent families tend to be short on both money and parental time to invest in their children. Not considered by Leigh is the role that family poverty may itself play in precipitating family breakdown, as well as the fact that parents living apart need not reduce the parental resources available to the children (e.g., via “shared-care” arrangements).
Leigh is quite restrained in the consequences he is prepared to attribute to greater inequality. He first addresses so-called “instrumental” effects, whereby inequality affects other outcomes we care about. His assessment of the evidence is that inequality is positively associated with economic growth and may be negatively associated with social mobility and democratic functioning, while there is no relationship with other outcomes often hypothesized to be affected, such as crime rates and public health (although that does not stop him citing, in the Introduction, adverse health outcomes of the poor and longer life expectancies of the rich as reasons to be concerned about inequality). While I agree the evidence is generally not strong for instrumental effects, it is also true that there are few opportunities for credible empirical identification of these effects. I therefore lean more towards the view that we don't have strong evidence one way or the other, noting that absence of evidence does not necessarily imply evidence of absence of these effects.
Leigh then turns to “intrinsic” arguments, and here is where he thinks the main argument for concern about inequality lies: people do not like it. His chapter on Australians’ attitudes to inequality, therefore, takes on importance for his argument that it is desirable to reduce inequality. Leigh presents evidence that a majority of Australians believe inequality is too high, although one must be left to wonder why policies to reduce inequality have not met with more electoral success. Perhaps when the rubber hits the road in terms of specific measures that would reduce inequality, people find they are not so keen. Leigh goes further, to suggest that Australians have always been egalitarian in spirit. But the examples given are far from convincing and often reflect a highly conditional notion of egalitarianism, for example, based on sex, race or employment status. Leigh also appeals to salary caps (among other measures) in Australian professional sporting codes as evidence of an egalitarian spirit. However, salary caps are common in other countries, including the US, and are much more about attracting fans than a concern for fairness.
In the last chapter of the book, Leigh puts forward ten recommendations for reducing inequality. These are generally sound and reasonable, but one cannot but help think that he is constrained by his position in the Labor Party and more particularly his roles in the Labor Government ministry. Most recommendations are sorely lacking in specific policy actions, instead coming across as “areas we should direct attention”; moreover, there are glaring omissions.
Most strikingly, his recommendations on both welfare and tax policy are best described as tepid. His only recommendation for welfare policy is that we continue to ensure it is targeted to those most in need. There is no acknowledgment that the level of welfare benefits might matter, nor that an excessive focus on targeting can be detrimental to their capacity to reduce inequality. His only recommendation on tax policy is that we maintain a progressive income tax. There is no mention of eliminating or reducing concessional (or zero) taxation of certain income sources (such as from superannuation), increasing taxes on economic rents, or introducing taxes on wealth or inheritances.
One also suspects that political considerations play a role in Leigh's argument for the role of unions. The case made is weak—indeed, in responding to the critique that unions look after insiders (their members) at the expense of outsiders (including the unemployed), the best defence he can mount is that other interest groups do the same thing. This is, of course, true, but then I'm not aware that anyone is arguing these other interest groups reduce inequality.
Leigh is more convincing in his advocacy for maintaining policy expertise that delivers economic growth, improving the evaluation of social policies, improving our education system, keeping a check on monopoly power and reducing social isolation. These are goals that most Labor Party members, and probably most members of the Australian community, would regard as uncontroversial, albeit with no clear roadmap provided for achieving them.
Perhaps where Leigh is on the most dangerous political ground is in his advocacy for (largely unspecified) policies to reduce single-parenthood. Leigh treads very carefully, suggesting “light-touch programs that encourage relationship stability.” Here, however, he neglects the important potential role of policy in both addressing the adverse economic circumstances that often contribute to family breakdown and reducing the strength of the association between single-parent families and poverty. Policies that increase the economic resources of families, and especially single-parent families, combined with policies to promote the involvement of both parents in raising their children, irrespective of whether the parents live together, are more likely to meet with success than what Leigh proposes.
Leigh (2024) shows an admirable commitment to drawing on peer-reviewed research for a book targeting a nonacademic audience, doing so in a way that mostly does not drown the reader in detail (noting that I would be one of the few readers who enjoyed reading the endnotes as much as the text). I found the book illuminating and a very helpful tool for reflecting on the current state of our knowledge about inequality in Australia. While I have my quibbles, I fully commend the book to anyone seeking to understanding the evolution of economic inequality in Australia and who would like to enrich their thinking about what it means for Australian society and what, if anything, policy makers should do about it.
经济不平等是一个重要的问题,值得应用经济学研究人员给予相当大的关注,它反映了这样一个现实,即经济产出的分配对社区福祉几乎与产出总量一样重要。虽然许多问题仍未得到解答,但现在澳大利亚对这一主题进行了大量研究,并相应地提高了对澳大利亚不平等的性质、原因和后果的理解。然而,在Leigh 2013年出版的《斗士和亿万富翁》(Battlers and Billionaires, Leigh 2013)一书之前,这一知识体系的翻译在某种程度上是缺乏的,该书对澳大利亚不平等的演变、其驱动因素和后果进行了概览,并提出了减少不平等的方法。因此,它为关于这一重要问题的公共论述提供了宝贵的资料。在Leigh(2024)中,作者对Leigh(2013)进行了更新。正如人们所期望的“更新”一样,本书中的许多材料与原书中的相同。主要的不同之处在于增加了最新的数据和一些额外的图表,讨论了自第一本书出版以来发表的新研究,对讲述的故事和材料解释的方式进行了一些调整,并增加了两条“应该做什么”的建议。总的故事和关键信息没有改变,因此这本书可能是针对那些没有读过第一本书的人。与Leigh(2013)一样,这是一本非常有趣的读物,Leigh用引人入胜且经常有趣的历史事实、故事和轶事补充了经过充分研究的经验事实。这本书是为普通读者写的,技术细节和来源放在尾注中。它成功地让非专业人士也能读懂,尽管我怀疑它的大部分内容对许多读者来说还是有些沉重。这本书有八章,前三章描述了从殖民前到现在澳大利亚不平等的演变。第四章考察了不平等的驱动因素,主要集中在最近几十年。第5章讨论了不平等的后果;第6章讨论了代际经济流动性问题,第7章讨论了社区对不平等的态度。他在第八章中总结了一系列解决不平等问题的建议。从广义上讲,澳大利亚不平等演变的前三章讲述的故事是正确的:联邦之前的不平等水平和趋势是不确定的,但在19世纪的大部分时间里,不平等可能非常高。从联邦到20世纪70年代,不平等程度有所下降,随后又有所加剧。对不平等趋势的描述在20世纪80年代早期最为平衡,当时数据有限,证据也不完整。然而,在过去的40年里,当有更多的数据可用时,Leigh将其称为“大分化”,他对不平等趋势进行了一些选择性的报道,忽略了他在这一时期所提出的“不平等正在加剧”的叙述中的许多细微差别和偏差。虽然毫无疑问,今天的不平等程度高于20世纪80年代初,但这种不平等的增加主要发生在20世纪80年代和90年代。本世纪发生的变化更加复杂和复杂。从某些指标来看,比如根据税收数据估算的最高收入占比,不平等程度有所加剧;在其他方面,如HILDA调查对整体不平等的衡量,几乎没有变化(Wilkins, Vera-Toscano, and Botha 2023)。虽然Leigh可能会辩解说他不想不必要地把水搅浑,但事实是水是浑的,他对这个话题的处理也不是无私的。在这里,我也无法抗拒(自私的)观察,他没有充分利用HILDA调查来描述和解释2000年后的环境(尽管他自己也是单位记录数据的用户)。HILDA调查是提供年度家庭收入数据的唯一来源,并提供了关于代际和代际流动性以及许多其他经济和社会现象的丰富信息。例如,Leigh推测美国关于事实婚姻比合法婚姻更不稳定的证据是否适用于澳大利亚。但是没有必要猜测!我们有来自HILDA的证据表明情况确实如此(Wilkins et al. 2022)。虽然他确实讨论了基于HILDA的代际流动性研究,但HILDA提供的关于贫困持久性和劣势代际“传递”的证据被忽视了(例如,Rodgers 2010, Vera-Toscano And Wilkins 2020, Parolin et al. 2024)。 这让我得出了一个普遍的观察,即李对不平等的讨论过多地关注了收入和财富分配的顶层——对亿万富翁的关注太多,而对战斗者的关注不够。这种说法在20世纪80年代之前更为站得住,因为当时可用的数据更倾向于富人。或许,富人的财富能写出更好的故事,为关注不平等提供更有吸引力的理由,让外行读者更感兴趣。当然,我可以理解,很难传达“中间80%”的不平等问题。然而,这并不能成为轻视穷人的借口,也不能成为贫穷对日常生活的影响的借口,至少在今天的澳大利亚是这样。例如,在讨论20世纪80年代以来的时期时,本章整整用了四页来讨论富人如何找到花钱的方法,而穷人的困境只用了一段。读到极富之人的消费可能性很有趣,但这给故事增加的内容很少。在研究不平等变化的驱动因素时,Leigh仔细研究了文献中考虑的因素,并对研究结果进行了很好的总结,突出了技术和全球化、税收和教育的作用。然而,他可能对教育减少不平等的潜力更有热情。支持教育扩张有很好的理由,但它在减少不平等方面的历史有些好坏参半。更有争议的是他赋予工会的重要角色。虽然有国际证据表明工会倾向于减少收入不平等,但这转化为收入不平等程度降低的证据不太清楚——事实上,利在这里引用的唯一参考文献研究的是工会密度与收入不平等之间的关系,而不是收入不平等。事实上,收入不平等并不直接转化为收入不平等,这一点在Leigh对过去40年澳大利亚不平等变化的驱动因素的处理中被广泛忽视。收入和收入不平等之间脱节的关键原因是就业在家庭间分配的作用。最值得注意的是,在过去40年里,妇女参与劳动力的人数急剧增加,而这在收入不平等方面的发展是非中性的。在20世纪80年代和90年代,女性就业的大部分增长发生在男性收入相对较高的家庭,这加剧了收入不平等(Johnson and Wilkins 2004)。相比之下,在21世纪初,大部分增长发生在男性收入相对较低或以前失业的家庭(Greenville, Pobke, and Rogers, 2013年,Sula和Dugain, 2019年)。这就是为什么2000年代和2010年代的不平等模式更加微妙的部分原因:尽管收入不平等加剧,但基尼系数等整体收入不平等指标变化不大,这是因为就业参与(尤其是女性)变化的本质。福利政策在影响不平等方面的作用也未得到充分讨论。澳大利亚收入支持体系的设计是影响收入不平等的关键因素,事实上,近年来,它在减少不平等方面所做的工作不如上世纪90年代。2000年代和2010年代收紧单亲父母抚养费和残疾支持养老金资格等措施对单亲父母和残疾人产生了实质性的负面影响。同样值得注意的是,从20世纪80年代末到21世纪初,家庭福利的增加对有孩子的中低收入家庭的收入产生了积极影响,并导致儿童贫困的下降(Redmond 2012)。当谈到福利和其他政府现金和实物福利时,利的主要观点是,所有的福利都应该通过经济状况调查来确定目标。这并非不言自明的事实,而且许多普遍(或近乎普遍)的计划具有显著的减少不平等的效果。利对不平等的驱动因素(以及如何应对)的讨论侧重于收入不平等,而对财富不平等的驱动因素基本保持沉默。事实上,他过分关注非常富有的人,这意味着他甚至没有提到财富不平等加剧的代际线,以及住房政策在加剧这一趋势方面的重大失败。同样没有提及的是,自上世纪90年代初以来,养老金的扩张加剧了财富不平等,过去10年的政策变化只是略微缓和了最严重的过度现象。在经济流动性这一章中,李的重点是代际流动性。在这里,他谈到了他认为家庭结构在使劣势持续存在方面所起作用的微妙问题。 虽然他正确地指出,在单亲家庭中长大是成年后劣势的一个强有力的预测因素,但他从中得出的推论是值得怀疑的。从本质上讲,他最终主张让更多的父母合法结婚,并引用美国的证据表明,事实上的婚姻不太稳定,并指出单亲家庭往往缺乏金钱和育儿时间来投资于孩子。利没有考虑到的是,家庭贫困本身可能在加速家庭破裂中所起的作用,以及父母分居不需要减少子女可用的父母资源(例如,通过“共同照顾”安排)这一事实。对于更大的不平等所带来的后果,李相当克制。他首先论述了所谓的“工具”效应,即不平等影响我们关心的其他结果。他对证据的评估是,不平等与经济增长呈正相关,可能与社会流动性和民主功能负相关,而与通常假设受到影响的其他结果(如犯罪率和公共卫生)没有关系(尽管这并不妨碍他在引言中引用穷人的不良健康结果和富人的预期寿命延长作为关注不平等的理由)。虽然我同意工具效应的证据通常不强,但对这些效应进行可信的经验鉴定的机会也很少,这也是事实。因此,我更倾向于这样一种观点,即我们无论如何都没有强有力的证据,注意到证据的缺乏并不一定意味着这些影响的缺乏。然后,利转向了“内在”论点,他认为关注不平等的主要论点在于:人们不喜欢不平等。因此,他关于澳大利亚人对不平等的态度的那一章,对于他认为减少不平等是可取的这一论点具有重要意义。利提出的证据表明,大多数澳大利亚人认为不平等程度太高,尽管人们一定会想知道为什么减少不平等的政策没有在选举中获得更多的成功。也许,当有关减少不平等的具体措施开始实施时,人们会发现他们并不那么热衷。利进一步指出,澳大利亚人在精神上一直是平等的。但是给出的例子远不能令人信服,而且往往反映了一种高度有条件的平等主义概念,例如,基于性别、种族或就业状况。利还呼吁在澳大利亚职业体育法规中设置工资上限(以及其他措施),以证明平等主义精神。然而,工资上限在包括美国在内的其他国家很常见,更多的是为了吸引球迷,而不是为了公平。在书的最后一章,利提出了减少不平等的十条建议。这些大体上都是合理的,但人们不禁会认为,他在工党中的地位,尤其是他在工党政府部门中的角色,限制了他的言论。大多数建议严重缺乏具体的政策行动,而是给人以“我们应该直接关注的领域”的印象;此外,还有一些明显的遗漏。最引人注目的是,他对福利和税收政策的建议被形容为不温不火。他对福利政策的唯一建议是,我们要继续确保它针对那些最需要帮助的人。没有人承认福利水平可能很重要,也没有人承认过度关注目标可能会损害他们减少不平等的能力。他对税收政策的唯一建议是维持累进所得税。没有提到消除或减少对某些收入来源(如养老金)的优惠(或零)税,增加经济租金税,或对财富或遗产征税。人们还怀疑,政治考虑在李关于工会作用的论证中发挥了作用。这个理由是站不了脚的——事实上,在回应工会以牺牲局外人(包括失业者)为代价照顾局内人(他们的成员)的批评时,他能找到的最好的辩护是,其他利益集团也在做同样的事情。当然,这是对的,但我不知道有人在争论这些其他利益集团减少了不平等。李的主张更有说服力,他主张保持政策专业知识,促进经济增长,改善社会政策的评估,改善我们的教育体系,对垄断力量进行检查,减少社会孤立。尽管没有明确的路线图来实现这些目标,但大多数工党成员,可能还有澳大利亚社会的大多数成员,都认为这些目标是没有争议的。 也许,利最危险的政治立场是他倡导减少单亲家庭的政策(基本上没有具体说明)。Leigh非常谨慎地建议“轻度接触的项目可以促进关系的稳定。”然而,在这里,他忽略了政策在解决往往导致家庭破裂的不利经济环境和减少单亲家庭与贫困之间联系的强度方面的重要潜在作用。增加家庭经济资源的政策,特别是单亲家庭,加上促进父母双方参与抚养孩子的政策,不管父母是否住在一起,比利提出的更有可能取得成功。Leigh(2024)表现出了一种令人钦佩的承诺,即为一本针对非学术读者的书借鉴同行评议的研究,这样做的方式在很大程度上不会淹没读者的细节(注意,我将是为数不多的喜欢阅读尾注和正文一样多的读者之一)。我发现这本书很有启发性,是一个非常有用的工具,可以反思我们对澳大利亚不平等的认识现状。虽然我有自己的吹毛求疵,但我完全推荐这本书给任何想要了解澳大利亚经济不平等演变的人,以及那些想要丰富自己思考这对澳大利亚社会意味着什么的人,以及政策制定者应该为此做些什么的人。
期刊介绍:
An applied economics journal with a strong policy orientation, The Australian Economic Review publishes high-quality articles applying economic analysis to a wide range of macroeconomic and microeconomic topics relevant to both economic and social policy issues. Produced by the Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, it is the leading journal of its kind in Australia and the Asia-Pacific region. While it is of special interest to Australian academics, students, policy makers, and others interested in the Australian economy, the journal also considers matters of international interest.