CEO bonus plans—And how to fix them

IF 0.7 Q4 BUSINESS, FINANCE
Kevin J. Murphy, Michael C. Jensen
{"title":"CEO bonus plans—And how to fix them","authors":"Kevin J. Murphy,&nbsp;Michael C. Jensen","doi":"10.1111/jacf.12629","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>Our research and consulting experience leads us to conclude that almost all CEO and executive bonus plans are deeply flawed and contribute to highly counterproductive incentives and actions that end up reducing the long-run value of most companies.</p><p>Ultimately, however, the advantages of bonus-based reward plans are only going to be as good and as effective as the designers of those plans make them. While bonus plans can be structured to provide incentives focused on specific operational objectives that will lead to value creation, poorly designed plans can provide strong incentives to destroy rather than create value. For example, annual bonus plans can destroy value by providing incentives to withhold effort, shift earnings and cash flow unproductively from one period to another, and to manipulate earnings counterproductively in other ways. Bonus plans also often create incentives for the organization to destroy information critical to the effective coordination of disparate parts of large complex firms. More importantly, bonus plans too often reward participants for misrepresenting—or “lying about”—the profit potential of their business units. All of these diminish the opportunity for performance in an organization, thereby leading to the destruction of firm value.</p><p>In this paper, we describe many of the problems associated with traditional executive bonus plans and offer our suggestions for how these plans can be vastly improved. We proceed as follows. In the section “How Executive Bonus Plans Cause Problems: Overview,” we describe typical bonus plans and provide an overview of the potential problems. In the next three sections, we then discuss problems (and solutions) associated with “Using the Wrong Pay-Performance Relations,” “Using the Wrong Targets, Benchmarks, or Standards,” and “Using the Wrong Performance Measures.” In the section “Failure to Make Ex Post Adjustments to Performance Measures and Compensation,” we discuss ex post adjustments to bonuses (including subjective assessments and claw backs). In the section “Bankers' Bonuses and the Financial Crisis,” we discuss the role of banking bonuses and the 2007-2008 financial crisis. The Conclusion section summarizes our recommendations.</p><p>Figure 1 illustrates these basic components of a “typical” annual bonus plan. Under the typical plan, no bonus is paid until a lower performance threshold or hurdle is achieved, and a “hurdle bonus” is paid at this lower performance threshold. The bonus is usually capped at an upper performance threshold; after this point increased performance is not associated with an increase in the bonus. The thresholds are routinely determined by the firm's annual budgeting process. The range between the lower and upper-performance thresholds (labeled the “incentive zone” in the figure), is drawn as linear but could be convex (bowl-shaped) or concave (upside-down bowl-shaped). The “pay-performance relation” (denoted by the heavy line) is the function that shows how the bonus varies throughout the entire range of possible performance outcomes.</p><p>The bonus plan illustrated in Figure 1 is replete with incentive problems that destroy value. We talked with a CEO who participated in a bonus plan similar to that depicted in Figure 1. His performance measure was returned on equity (ROE), the upper-performance threshold was set at 15%, and he discovered that his firm could easily surpass this upper threshold. He told us, half seriously: “I'd have to be the stupidest CEO in the world to report an ROE of 18%. First, I wouldn't get any bonus for any results above the cap. Second, I could have saved some of our earnings for next year. And third, [the board of directors] would increase my target performance for next year.” This CEO's comments reflect not only his frustration with his bonus plan but also reveal that he well understands how to game the compensation system to get higher bonuses.</p><p>Improving executive bonus plans requires not only choosing the right performance measure, but also determining how performance thresholds, targets, and benchmarks are set, how the pay-performance relation is defined, and how the relation changes over time. Our discussion and recommendations will focus on details, wherein lies the devil.</p><p>In the aftermath of the 2008–2009 financial crisis, attention focused on whether bonus plans (especially those on Wall Street) create incentives to engage in excessive risk-taking. There are two ways that bonuses—or incentive compensation more broadly—can create incentives for risk-taking. The first way (to which we will return in the sections “Using the Wrong Performance Measures” and “Bankers’ Bonuses and the Financial Crisis”) is rewarding people using performance metrics that implicitly (or explicitly) reward risky behavior, such as paying mortgage brokers based on the number of loans they write, rather than for writing loans that borrowers might actually pay back. The second way is through non-linear pay-performance plans: in particular, asymmetries in rewards for good performance and penalties for failure. When CEOs (or traders or brokers, etc.) receive rewards for upside risk, but are not penalized for downside risk, they will naturally take greater risks than if they faced symmetric consequences in both directions.</p><p>Consider, for example, an investment opportunity with a 50% chance of making $100 million in profit, and a 50% chance of losing $200 million. This investment opportunity has an expected value of −$50 million and should be rejected. However, suppose that the CEO (or trader or broker, etc.) has an incentive plan that gives him a share of any positive profit, but is set at zero if profit is negative. From the perspective of this CEO (or trader or broker, etc.) with the asymmetric bonus plan, the investment opportunity has a positive expected value.</p><p>More generally, all “non-linearities” in the pay-performance relation affect incentives to take risks. When the pay-performance relation is convex (or bowl-shaped) executives can increase their total bonus payouts by increasing the variability of their performance. On the other hand, in situations where the pay-performance relation is concave (or upside-down bowl-shaped) in the relevant range, the opposite is true — CEOs have incentives to smooth the variability in performance over time by withholding high performance this period and saving as much of it as possible for next period.</p><p>The problems associated with non-linear pay-performance relations can be partially solved by making the relation linear. First, the upper performance threshold (and bonus cap) can be eliminated, so that superior performance continues to be rewarded by higher bonuses. Second, the lower performance threshold can be dropped, thus eliminating the problematic discontinuous “jump” in the pay-performance relation. Finally, the plan can be made linear by ensuring that the slope of the pay-performance relation (that is, the incremental bonus associated with a given increase in performance) is constant regardless of the level of performance.</p><p>Successfully implemented (in conjunction with recommendations on performance measures and standards discussed later in this paper), linearity takes “timing” out of the equation.2 For example, a CEO paid 5% of profit year after year will have no incentives to play accounting or other “games” with profit in the fourth quarter, since any increase in fourth quarter bonuses will be met with an equal but opposite decrease in bonuses in the following quarter. The CEO paid under a linear pay-performance plan also has no incentive to engage in excess risk-taking, since the rewards for positive profits are the same as the penalties for losses. Finally, another advantage of linear plans is that they are simple: non-linear bonus plans are typically needlessly complicated to implement (and often difficult to communicate to the participants). The simpler the plan, the more likely the incentive outcome.</p><p>Truncating otherwise-negative bonuses at zero seems like a practical solution to the messy problem of imposing or enforcing negative bonuses on CEOs. However, protecting the CEO from negative bonuses (through “upside-only bonuses” set to zero when profit is negative) puts a non-linearity or “kink” or in the pay-performance relation at zero profit, which creates many of the problems discussed above. In particular, CEOs paid under this plan will have no incentives to improve profit this year when they see no way to generate positive profit. In addition, they will predictably attempt to shift profit from the current year to next year in this situation so that they can more be profitable next year. Finally, truncating bonuses at zero can also lead to excessive risk-taking, since such plans reward CEOs for positive profit but do not penalize them for losses.</p><p>Solving the problems with upside-only bonuses involves designing (and enforcing) plans with negative bonuses. It is our experience (and perhaps common sense) that executives are loathe to write end-of-the-year “negative bonus” checks back to the company for sub-par performance. Fortunately, there are alternative and palatable ways to introduce effective negative bonuses into executive bonus contracts that do not involve writing checks back to the company.</p><p>Bonuses are typically based on performance compared to something the company might call a performance standard, bogey, target, hurdle, or benchmark. Henceforth, we use the term “benchmark” to refer to any or all of these commonly used terms. Examples include net income measured against budgeted net income, earnings-per-share (EPS) versus last year's EPS, sales growth (i.e., this year's sales vs. last year's sales), cash flow versus a charge for capital, performance measured relative to peer-group performance, or performance measured against financial or nonfinancial strategic “milestones.” It is useful to think of these benchmark alternatives as determining how the pay-performance relation depicted in Figure 1 is initially set, and how it shifts to the right or the leftover time.</p><p>First let us recognize that when performance in a bonus plan is measured relative to a benchmark, there are two ways to achieve higher bonuses: increase the performance measure, or decrease the benchmark. Suppose that the performance measure is X and that the benchmark is B and bonuses are based on the difference between them (X—B). The benchmark B might be budgeted performance, prior-year performance, strategic milestones, or the performance of other executives or an industry peer group. Because bonuses are increased either by increasing X or by decreasing B, the integrity of the plan is reduced whenever the people eligible to receive bonuses under the plan (“plan participants”) can take actions that reduce B. And in most bonus systems plan participants in one way or another can and do influence the benchmark B.</p><p>Business history is littered with companies that “got what they paid for.” Paying salespeople commissions based on revenues, for example, provides incentives to increase revenues regardless of the costs or relative margins of different products. Likewise, paying rank-and-file workers “piece rates” based on units produced provides incentives to maximize quantity irrespective of quality, and paying a division head based solely on divisional profit leads the division head to ignore the effects of his decisions on the profits of other divisions. Similarly, paying CEOs based on short-run accounting profits provides incentives to increase short-run profits (by, e.g., cutting R&amp;D) even if doing so reduces value in the long run. In each of these cases, employees will predictably take actions to increase their compensation, even if these actions are at the expense of long-run firm value. Indeed, many examples of dysfunctional compensation and incentive systems can be traced to inappropriate performance measures.</p><p>The problem of inappropriate performance measures is illustrated succinctly by the title of Steven Kerr's famous 1975 article, “On the folly of rewarding A, while hoping for B.”5 For CEOs, well-intentioned compensation committees hope to increase firm value (“B”) by rewarding the executive on a variety of performance measures (“A”) that induce actions not perfectly correlated (or even inversely correlated) with the actions that increase firm value. Conceptually, the “perfect” performance measure for a CEO is the CEO's personal contribution to the value of the firm. This contribution includes the effect that the CEO has on the performance of others in the organization, and also the effects that the CEO's actions this year have on performance in future periods. Unfortunately, the CEO's contribution to firm value is never directly measurable; the available measures will inevitably fail to capture ways that the CEO creates value and will capture the effects of factors not due to the efforts of the CEO or fail to capture ways that the CEO destroys value. The challenge in designing incentive plans is to select performance measures that capture important aspects of the CEO's contributions to firm value, while recognizing that all performance measures are imperfect and therefore create unintended side effects.</p><p>We start this discussion by considering the counterproductive effects associated with using accounting performance measures, and the even worse problems that are created when these measures are expressed as ratios or rates of return (such as EPS or ROE). We then move on to discuss the advantages and challenges associated with incorporating charges for the cost of capital into incentive plans and conclude by outlining simple steps that can dramatically improve almost any existing bonus plan.</p><p>It is generally impossible to create fool-proof objective and accurate measures of the contribution to firm value by an individual, department, or division. And this also applies to the performance measurement and compensation of the CEO. Therefore, every bonus system should allow for denial or adjustment of a bonus that is not earned by the CEO or is earned from actions that do not benefit the firm or even damage the firm. In addition, it is important to include contributions of the CEO that do not show up in his or her objective performance measure. While explicitly allowing for such <i>ex post</i> adjustments creates its own problems and challenges we believe failing to confront these subjective issues results in greater mistakes than dealing with them directly.</p><p>Thus, we believe it is important for compensation committees to make after-the-fact ex post adjustments to both the measure of CEO performance and the compensation actually paid to the CEO. The three most important and common failings in this domain are: (a) failing to make subjective assessments of CEO performance, (b) protecting CEOs too much from factors beyond their control, and (c) failing to claw back inappropriate rewards to the CEO.</p><p>No discussion of executive bonus plans is complete without an analysis of the Wall Street “bonus culture” that has routinely been blamed for causing the 2007–2009 financial crisis and the continuing problems in the economy. Public anger over banking bonuses surfaced in January 2009 amid reports that Wall Street bankers were set to receive nearly $20 billion in bonuses for 2008 performance,13 and heightened with revelations that bailout-recipient Merrill Lynch paid nearly $4 billion in year-end bonuses just prior to the completion of its acquisition by Bank of America.14 Outrage further intensified following the March 2009 revelation that American International Group (AIG) was in the process of paying $168 million in “retention bonuses” to its executives. These revelations—coupled with suspicions that the bonus culture facilitated excessive risk-taking—led to an effective prohibition on cash bonuses for participants in the government's Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) and to more sweeping regulation of executive compensation as part of the July 2010 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform Act. While most of the regulations focus on senior executive officers, the banking-specific provisions in Dodd-Frank were applicable to any employee that could expose the institution to substantial losses.</p><p>In this section, we analyze the bonus culture as it applies to three groups of banking employees: top-level executives, mortgage brokers, and traders. Ultimately, we find little evidence that the bonus culture provided incentives for excessive risk-taking for top-level executives; indeed, the general structure of low base salaries and high bonus opportunities paid in a combination of cash, stock, and options not only mitigates risk-taking but fulfills many of the “guiding principles” for bonus design espoused in this paper. However, we also identify design flaws in the performance measures used for mortgage brokers and loan officers, who were too often paid to write loans with little regard for the borrowers’ ability to repay.</p>","PeriodicalId":46789,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Applied Corporate Finance","volume":"36 3","pages":"95-110"},"PeriodicalIF":0.7000,"publicationDate":"2024-11-21","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/jacf.12629","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of Applied Corporate Finance","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/jacf.12629","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q4","JCRName":"BUSINESS, FINANCE","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

Our research and consulting experience leads us to conclude that almost all CEO and executive bonus plans are deeply flawed and contribute to highly counterproductive incentives and actions that end up reducing the long-run value of most companies.

Ultimately, however, the advantages of bonus-based reward plans are only going to be as good and as effective as the designers of those plans make them. While bonus plans can be structured to provide incentives focused on specific operational objectives that will lead to value creation, poorly designed plans can provide strong incentives to destroy rather than create value. For example, annual bonus plans can destroy value by providing incentives to withhold effort, shift earnings and cash flow unproductively from one period to another, and to manipulate earnings counterproductively in other ways. Bonus plans also often create incentives for the organization to destroy information critical to the effective coordination of disparate parts of large complex firms. More importantly, bonus plans too often reward participants for misrepresenting—or “lying about”—the profit potential of their business units. All of these diminish the opportunity for performance in an organization, thereby leading to the destruction of firm value.

In this paper, we describe many of the problems associated with traditional executive bonus plans and offer our suggestions for how these plans can be vastly improved. We proceed as follows. In the section “How Executive Bonus Plans Cause Problems: Overview,” we describe typical bonus plans and provide an overview of the potential problems. In the next three sections, we then discuss problems (and solutions) associated with “Using the Wrong Pay-Performance Relations,” “Using the Wrong Targets, Benchmarks, or Standards,” and “Using the Wrong Performance Measures.” In the section “Failure to Make Ex Post Adjustments to Performance Measures and Compensation,” we discuss ex post adjustments to bonuses (including subjective assessments and claw backs). In the section “Bankers' Bonuses and the Financial Crisis,” we discuss the role of banking bonuses and the 2007-2008 financial crisis. The Conclusion section summarizes our recommendations.

Figure 1 illustrates these basic components of a “typical” annual bonus plan. Under the typical plan, no bonus is paid until a lower performance threshold or hurdle is achieved, and a “hurdle bonus” is paid at this lower performance threshold. The bonus is usually capped at an upper performance threshold; after this point increased performance is not associated with an increase in the bonus. The thresholds are routinely determined by the firm's annual budgeting process. The range between the lower and upper-performance thresholds (labeled the “incentive zone” in the figure), is drawn as linear but could be convex (bowl-shaped) or concave (upside-down bowl-shaped). The “pay-performance relation” (denoted by the heavy line) is the function that shows how the bonus varies throughout the entire range of possible performance outcomes.

The bonus plan illustrated in Figure 1 is replete with incentive problems that destroy value. We talked with a CEO who participated in a bonus plan similar to that depicted in Figure 1. His performance measure was returned on equity (ROE), the upper-performance threshold was set at 15%, and he discovered that his firm could easily surpass this upper threshold. He told us, half seriously: “I'd have to be the stupidest CEO in the world to report an ROE of 18%. First, I wouldn't get any bonus for any results above the cap. Second, I could have saved some of our earnings for next year. And third, [the board of directors] would increase my target performance for next year.” This CEO's comments reflect not only his frustration with his bonus plan but also reveal that he well understands how to game the compensation system to get higher bonuses.

Improving executive bonus plans requires not only choosing the right performance measure, but also determining how performance thresholds, targets, and benchmarks are set, how the pay-performance relation is defined, and how the relation changes over time. Our discussion and recommendations will focus on details, wherein lies the devil.

In the aftermath of the 2008–2009 financial crisis, attention focused on whether bonus plans (especially those on Wall Street) create incentives to engage in excessive risk-taking. There are two ways that bonuses—or incentive compensation more broadly—can create incentives for risk-taking. The first way (to which we will return in the sections “Using the Wrong Performance Measures” and “Bankers’ Bonuses and the Financial Crisis”) is rewarding people using performance metrics that implicitly (or explicitly) reward risky behavior, such as paying mortgage brokers based on the number of loans they write, rather than for writing loans that borrowers might actually pay back. The second way is through non-linear pay-performance plans: in particular, asymmetries in rewards for good performance and penalties for failure. When CEOs (or traders or brokers, etc.) receive rewards for upside risk, but are not penalized for downside risk, they will naturally take greater risks than if they faced symmetric consequences in both directions.

Consider, for example, an investment opportunity with a 50% chance of making $100 million in profit, and a 50% chance of losing $200 million. This investment opportunity has an expected value of −$50 million and should be rejected. However, suppose that the CEO (or trader or broker, etc.) has an incentive plan that gives him a share of any positive profit, but is set at zero if profit is negative. From the perspective of this CEO (or trader or broker, etc.) with the asymmetric bonus plan, the investment opportunity has a positive expected value.

More generally, all “non-linearities” in the pay-performance relation affect incentives to take risks. When the pay-performance relation is convex (or bowl-shaped) executives can increase their total bonus payouts by increasing the variability of their performance. On the other hand, in situations where the pay-performance relation is concave (or upside-down bowl-shaped) in the relevant range, the opposite is true — CEOs have incentives to smooth the variability in performance over time by withholding high performance this period and saving as much of it as possible for next period.

The problems associated with non-linear pay-performance relations can be partially solved by making the relation linear. First, the upper performance threshold (and bonus cap) can be eliminated, so that superior performance continues to be rewarded by higher bonuses. Second, the lower performance threshold can be dropped, thus eliminating the problematic discontinuous “jump” in the pay-performance relation. Finally, the plan can be made linear by ensuring that the slope of the pay-performance relation (that is, the incremental bonus associated with a given increase in performance) is constant regardless of the level of performance.

Successfully implemented (in conjunction with recommendations on performance measures and standards discussed later in this paper), linearity takes “timing” out of the equation.2 For example, a CEO paid 5% of profit year after year will have no incentives to play accounting or other “games” with profit in the fourth quarter, since any increase in fourth quarter bonuses will be met with an equal but opposite decrease in bonuses in the following quarter. The CEO paid under a linear pay-performance plan also has no incentive to engage in excess risk-taking, since the rewards for positive profits are the same as the penalties for losses. Finally, another advantage of linear plans is that they are simple: non-linear bonus plans are typically needlessly complicated to implement (and often difficult to communicate to the participants). The simpler the plan, the more likely the incentive outcome.

Truncating otherwise-negative bonuses at zero seems like a practical solution to the messy problem of imposing or enforcing negative bonuses on CEOs. However, protecting the CEO from negative bonuses (through “upside-only bonuses” set to zero when profit is negative) puts a non-linearity or “kink” or in the pay-performance relation at zero profit, which creates many of the problems discussed above. In particular, CEOs paid under this plan will have no incentives to improve profit this year when they see no way to generate positive profit. In addition, they will predictably attempt to shift profit from the current year to next year in this situation so that they can more be profitable next year. Finally, truncating bonuses at zero can also lead to excessive risk-taking, since such plans reward CEOs for positive profit but do not penalize them for losses.

Solving the problems with upside-only bonuses involves designing (and enforcing) plans with negative bonuses. It is our experience (and perhaps common sense) that executives are loathe to write end-of-the-year “negative bonus” checks back to the company for sub-par performance. Fortunately, there are alternative and palatable ways to introduce effective negative bonuses into executive bonus contracts that do not involve writing checks back to the company.

Bonuses are typically based on performance compared to something the company might call a performance standard, bogey, target, hurdle, or benchmark. Henceforth, we use the term “benchmark” to refer to any or all of these commonly used terms. Examples include net income measured against budgeted net income, earnings-per-share (EPS) versus last year's EPS, sales growth (i.e., this year's sales vs. last year's sales), cash flow versus a charge for capital, performance measured relative to peer-group performance, or performance measured against financial or nonfinancial strategic “milestones.” It is useful to think of these benchmark alternatives as determining how the pay-performance relation depicted in Figure 1 is initially set, and how it shifts to the right or the leftover time.

First let us recognize that when performance in a bonus plan is measured relative to a benchmark, there are two ways to achieve higher bonuses: increase the performance measure, or decrease the benchmark. Suppose that the performance measure is X and that the benchmark is B and bonuses are based on the difference between them (X—B). The benchmark B might be budgeted performance, prior-year performance, strategic milestones, or the performance of other executives or an industry peer group. Because bonuses are increased either by increasing X or by decreasing B, the integrity of the plan is reduced whenever the people eligible to receive bonuses under the plan (“plan participants”) can take actions that reduce B. And in most bonus systems plan participants in one way or another can and do influence the benchmark B.

Business history is littered with companies that “got what they paid for.” Paying salespeople commissions based on revenues, for example, provides incentives to increase revenues regardless of the costs or relative margins of different products. Likewise, paying rank-and-file workers “piece rates” based on units produced provides incentives to maximize quantity irrespective of quality, and paying a division head based solely on divisional profit leads the division head to ignore the effects of his decisions on the profits of other divisions. Similarly, paying CEOs based on short-run accounting profits provides incentives to increase short-run profits (by, e.g., cutting R&D) even if doing so reduces value in the long run. In each of these cases, employees will predictably take actions to increase their compensation, even if these actions are at the expense of long-run firm value. Indeed, many examples of dysfunctional compensation and incentive systems can be traced to inappropriate performance measures.

The problem of inappropriate performance measures is illustrated succinctly by the title of Steven Kerr's famous 1975 article, “On the folly of rewarding A, while hoping for B.”5 For CEOs, well-intentioned compensation committees hope to increase firm value (“B”) by rewarding the executive on a variety of performance measures (“A”) that induce actions not perfectly correlated (or even inversely correlated) with the actions that increase firm value. Conceptually, the “perfect” performance measure for a CEO is the CEO's personal contribution to the value of the firm. This contribution includes the effect that the CEO has on the performance of others in the organization, and also the effects that the CEO's actions this year have on performance in future periods. Unfortunately, the CEO's contribution to firm value is never directly measurable; the available measures will inevitably fail to capture ways that the CEO creates value and will capture the effects of factors not due to the efforts of the CEO or fail to capture ways that the CEO destroys value. The challenge in designing incentive plans is to select performance measures that capture important aspects of the CEO's contributions to firm value, while recognizing that all performance measures are imperfect and therefore create unintended side effects.

We start this discussion by considering the counterproductive effects associated with using accounting performance measures, and the even worse problems that are created when these measures are expressed as ratios or rates of return (such as EPS or ROE). We then move on to discuss the advantages and challenges associated with incorporating charges for the cost of capital into incentive plans and conclude by outlining simple steps that can dramatically improve almost any existing bonus plan.

It is generally impossible to create fool-proof objective and accurate measures of the contribution to firm value by an individual, department, or division. And this also applies to the performance measurement and compensation of the CEO. Therefore, every bonus system should allow for denial or adjustment of a bonus that is not earned by the CEO or is earned from actions that do not benefit the firm or even damage the firm. In addition, it is important to include contributions of the CEO that do not show up in his or her objective performance measure. While explicitly allowing for such ex post adjustments creates its own problems and challenges we believe failing to confront these subjective issues results in greater mistakes than dealing with them directly.

Thus, we believe it is important for compensation committees to make after-the-fact ex post adjustments to both the measure of CEO performance and the compensation actually paid to the CEO. The three most important and common failings in this domain are: (a) failing to make subjective assessments of CEO performance, (b) protecting CEOs too much from factors beyond their control, and (c) failing to claw back inappropriate rewards to the CEO.

No discussion of executive bonus plans is complete without an analysis of the Wall Street “bonus culture” that has routinely been blamed for causing the 2007–2009 financial crisis and the continuing problems in the economy. Public anger over banking bonuses surfaced in January 2009 amid reports that Wall Street bankers were set to receive nearly $20 billion in bonuses for 2008 performance,13 and heightened with revelations that bailout-recipient Merrill Lynch paid nearly $4 billion in year-end bonuses just prior to the completion of its acquisition by Bank of America.14 Outrage further intensified following the March 2009 revelation that American International Group (AIG) was in the process of paying $168 million in “retention bonuses” to its executives. These revelations—coupled with suspicions that the bonus culture facilitated excessive risk-taking—led to an effective prohibition on cash bonuses for participants in the government's Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP) and to more sweeping regulation of executive compensation as part of the July 2010 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform Act. While most of the regulations focus on senior executive officers, the banking-specific provisions in Dodd-Frank were applicable to any employee that could expose the institution to substantial losses.

In this section, we analyze the bonus culture as it applies to three groups of banking employees: top-level executives, mortgage brokers, and traders. Ultimately, we find little evidence that the bonus culture provided incentives for excessive risk-taking for top-level executives; indeed, the general structure of low base salaries and high bonus opportunities paid in a combination of cash, stock, and options not only mitigates risk-taking but fulfills many of the “guiding principles” for bonus design espoused in this paper. However, we also identify design flaws in the performance measures used for mortgage brokers and loan officers, who were too often paid to write loans with little regard for the borrowers’ ability to repay.

Abstract Image

首席执行官奖金计划--以及如何解决这些问题
根据我们的研究和咨询经验,我们得出结论:几乎所有的首席执行官和高管奖金计划都存在严重缺陷,会助长适得其反的激励措施和行为,最终降低大多数公司的长期价值。虽然奖金计划的结构可以提供以具体运营目标为重点的激励,从而创造价值,但设计不当的计划可能会提供破坏而非创造价值的强烈激励。例如,年度奖金计划可能会破坏价值,因为它激励员工不付出努力,将收益和现金流从一个时期无效益地转移到另一个时期,并以其他方式无效益地操纵收益。奖金计划还常常激励组织破坏对有效协调大型复杂企业不同部门至关重要的信息。更重要的是,奖金计划经常奖励虚报--或 "谎报"--其业务部门利润潜力的参与者。在本文中,我们阐述了与传统高管奖金计划相关的许多问题,并就如何大幅改进这些计划提出了我们的建议。我们的论述过程如下。在 "高管奖金计划如何导致问题:概述 "一节中,我们介绍了典型的奖金计划,并概述了潜在的问题。在接下来的三节中,我们将讨论与 "使用错误的薪酬-绩效关系"、"使用错误的目标、基准或标准 "以及 "使用错误的绩效衡量标准 "相关的问题(和解决方案)。在 "未能对绩效衡量标准和薪酬进行事后调整 "一节中,我们讨论了对奖金的事后调整(包括主观评估和回拨)。在 "银行家的奖金和金融危机 "一节中,我们讨论了银行业奖金的作用和 2007-2008 年的金融危机。图 1 展示了 "典型 "年度奖金计划的基本组成部分。根据典型的计划,在达到较低的业绩阈值或关卡之前不支付奖金,并在达到较低的业绩阈值时支付 "关卡奖金"。奖金的上限通常是一个较高的业绩阈值;在此阈值之后,业绩的提高与奖金的增加无关。这些临界值通常由公司的年度预算程序确定。业绩下限和上限之间的范围(图中标注为 "激励区")是线性的,但也可能是凸形(碗形)或凹形(倒置的碗形)。薪酬-绩效关系"(用粗线表示)是显示奖金在整个可能的绩效结果范围内如何变化的函数。我们曾与一位首席执行官交谈过,他参加的奖金计划与图 1 所示类似。他的业绩衡量标准是净资产收益率(ROE),业绩上限设定为 15%,但他发现他的公司可以轻松超过这个上限。他半认真地告诉我们他半真半假地告诉我们:"我必须是世界上最愚蠢的首席执行官,才能报告出 18% 的 ROE。首先,如果业绩超过上限,我就拿不到任何奖金。其次,我本可以把部分收益留到明年。第三,[董事会]会提高我明年的目标业绩"。这位首席执行官的评论不仅反映了他对奖金计划的不满,而且还揭示了他非常了解如何玩弄薪酬制度以获得更高的奖金。改进高管奖金计划不仅需要选择正确的绩效衡量标准,还需要确定如何设定绩效门槛、目标和基准,如何定义薪酬与绩效的关系,以及这种关系如何随时间而变化。在 2008-2009 年金融危机之后,人们开始关注奖金计划(尤其是华尔街的奖金计划)是否会刺激人们过度冒险。奖金或更广泛意义上的奖励性报酬会通过两种方式刺激冒险行为。第一种方式(我们将在 "使用错误的绩效衡量标准 "和 "银行家的奖金与金融危机 "两节中再次讨论)是使用隐含(或明确)奖励高风险行为的绩效衡量标准来奖励员工,例如根据抵押贷款经纪人所发放贷款的数量向他们支付报酬,而不是根据他们所发放贷款的借款人实际偿还贷款的情况向他们支付报酬。 在这一领域,三个最重要和最常见的失误是(如果不对华尔街的 "奖金文化 "进行分析,那么对高管奖金计划的讨论就是不完整的,华尔街的 "奖金文化 "一直被指责为导致 2007-2009 年金融危机和持续的经济问题的罪魁祸首。2009 年 1 月,有报道称华尔街的银行家们将因 2008 年的业绩而获得近 200 亿美元的奖金,13 公众对银行业奖金的愤怒由此浮出水面;2009 年 3 月,美国国际集团(AIG)被揭露正在向其高管支付 1.68 亿美元的 "留任奖金",公众的愤怒进一步加剧。这些揭露--加上对奖金文化助长过度冒险的怀疑--导致政府的 "问题资产救助计划"(Troubled Asset Relief Program,TARP)参与者的现金奖金被有效禁止,并导致 2010 年 7 月《多德-弗兰克华尔街改革法案》(Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform Act)对高管薪酬进行更全面的监管。虽然大部分规定都针对高级管理人员,但多德-弗兰克法案中针对银行业的规定适用于任何可能使机构蒙受重大损失的员工。在本节中,我们分析了适用于三类银行业员工的奖金文化:高层管理人员、抵押贷款经纪人和交易员。最终,我们发现几乎没有证据表明奖金文化会激励高层管理人员过度冒险;事实上,以现金、股票和期权相结合的方式支付的低底薪和高奖金机会的总体结构不仅减轻了风险承担,而且满足了本文所倡导的奖金设计的许多 "指导原则"。然而,我们也发现了用于抵押贷款经纪人和贷款官员的绩效衡量标准存在设计缺陷,他们往往只负责发放贷款,而很少考虑借款人的还款能力。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
11.10%
发文量
44
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信