{"title":"Comment on “The Sri Lankan Economy: From Optimism to Debt Trap”","authors":"Shantayanan Devarajan","doi":"10.1111/aepr.12491","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>Athukorala (<span>2025</span>) makes a convincing case that Sri Lanka's debt crisis of 2022 was not only due to recent, reckless economic policies—a massive tax cut, financing fiscal deficits by printing money, repaying foreign debt out of reserves—but the culmination of decades of an “anti-tradable” bias that left the economy unable to manage high levels of debt, especially in the wake of the COVID-19 crisis. The analysis is based on a sweeping tour of Sri Lankan economic history, starting before independence and ending with the current International Monetary Fund-supported program of 2023.</p><p>This <i>longue durée</i> helps resolve a puzzle about the country's policy direction. In the late 1970s, Sri Lanka was one of the first developing countries to liberalize trade. The economy boomed. Many people heralded Sri Lanka as a textbook case of successful trade reform (see, for example, Castro & Devarajan, <span>2006</span>). Nevertheless, the country soon began adopting anti-tradable policies, which accelerated in the 2000s leading to the collapse of 2022. Athukorala observes that the trade liberalization was accompanied by laxist macroeconomic policies, such as an overvalued exchange rate, which made the reform difficult to sustain. The early 1980s also saw a massive increase in public investment, which contributed to the real exchange rate appreciation, and to the economic boom.</p><p>My comments on Athukorala (<span>2025</span>) are aimed at broadening the set of policies that contributed to the debt crisis, and exploring why Sri Lankan policymakers chose these policies.</p><p>In addition to anti-tradable policies, Sri Lanka has followed at least two other policies that have undermined the economy's growth. Introduced in 1958, the Paddy Lands Act requires farmers who lease land from the state (which are most farmers) to grow only paddy. Atukorala mentions the Paddy Lands Act as part of the move toward a closed economy in the 1950s. The Act is still in force—70 years later. Paddy is the least productive and least lucrative crop (World Bank, <span>2021</span>). This policy has made agriculture the least productive sector in the economy and kept farmers poor.</p><p>Second, Sri Lanka has some of the most restrictive labor regulations in the world (Abidoye <i>et al</i>., <span>2009</span>). Workers with 20 years of service receive an average of 30 months of severance pay. Not surprisingly, employment growth in the formal, private sector has been sluggish. The situation became serious in the 1980s when the youth bulge was entering the labor market. To quell violent protests, the government expanded employment in the public sector, another low-productivity sector. In addition, the public sector pays higher wages, provides better benefits, and is a job for life (Hausmann <i>et al</i>., <span>2020</span>). This raises the reservation wage for working in the private sector, making it harder to compete in world markets.</p><p>In short, Athukorala's anti-tradable bias is part of an “anti-productivity bias,” one that has kept Sri Lanka from fulfilling its potential for decades and contributed to the perfect storm of 2022.</p><p>These policies have been pursued by left- and right-wing governments, so they could not be due to ideology. I suggest they stem from a lack of accountability. That Sri Lanka is a democracy indicates that the people of Sri Lanka could hold politicians accountable for economic policy decisions at elections. But in a country with deep ethnic cleavages (which resulted in a 26-year civil war), many people vote along linguistic or religious lines, rather than on the economic performance of the incumbent. Knowing this, politicians pursue populist policies during election times, enough to get them elected but at the cost of the economy's productivity.</p><p>Worse, policymakers have chosen directions that minimize their accountability to the people and maximize their ability to control the public. For instance, macroeconomic instability in Sri Lanka is caused, as Athukorala notes, by government financing fiscal deficits by borrowing from the central bank. While this causes inflation with a lag, the two other options for financing a fiscal deficit—borrowing from domestic capital markets and borrowing abroad—hold government accountable instantly by raising borrowing costs.</p><p>Trade liberalization makes producers accountable to world markets. Protectionism, the Paddy Lands Act, and labor market regulations enable governments to control who gets the benefits, that is, who is accountable to government.</p><p>In sum, Athukorala's valuable paper has triggered discussion on the multiple factors that led to Sri Lanka's debt crisis. In considering strategies for recovery, we should pursue policies that strengthen the public's ability to hold government accountable, rather than the other way around.</p>","PeriodicalId":45430,"journal":{"name":"Asian Economic Policy Review","volume":"20 1","pages":"172-173"},"PeriodicalIF":4.5000,"publicationDate":"2024-08-12","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/aepr.12491","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Asian Economic Policy Review","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/aepr.12491","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Abstract
Athukorala (2025) makes a convincing case that Sri Lanka's debt crisis of 2022 was not only due to recent, reckless economic policies—a massive tax cut, financing fiscal deficits by printing money, repaying foreign debt out of reserves—but the culmination of decades of an “anti-tradable” bias that left the economy unable to manage high levels of debt, especially in the wake of the COVID-19 crisis. The analysis is based on a sweeping tour of Sri Lankan economic history, starting before independence and ending with the current International Monetary Fund-supported program of 2023.
This longue durée helps resolve a puzzle about the country's policy direction. In the late 1970s, Sri Lanka was one of the first developing countries to liberalize trade. The economy boomed. Many people heralded Sri Lanka as a textbook case of successful trade reform (see, for example, Castro & Devarajan, 2006). Nevertheless, the country soon began adopting anti-tradable policies, which accelerated in the 2000s leading to the collapse of 2022. Athukorala observes that the trade liberalization was accompanied by laxist macroeconomic policies, such as an overvalued exchange rate, which made the reform difficult to sustain. The early 1980s also saw a massive increase in public investment, which contributed to the real exchange rate appreciation, and to the economic boom.
My comments on Athukorala (2025) are aimed at broadening the set of policies that contributed to the debt crisis, and exploring why Sri Lankan policymakers chose these policies.
In addition to anti-tradable policies, Sri Lanka has followed at least two other policies that have undermined the economy's growth. Introduced in 1958, the Paddy Lands Act requires farmers who lease land from the state (which are most farmers) to grow only paddy. Atukorala mentions the Paddy Lands Act as part of the move toward a closed economy in the 1950s. The Act is still in force—70 years later. Paddy is the least productive and least lucrative crop (World Bank, 2021). This policy has made agriculture the least productive sector in the economy and kept farmers poor.
Second, Sri Lanka has some of the most restrictive labor regulations in the world (Abidoye et al., 2009). Workers with 20 years of service receive an average of 30 months of severance pay. Not surprisingly, employment growth in the formal, private sector has been sluggish. The situation became serious in the 1980s when the youth bulge was entering the labor market. To quell violent protests, the government expanded employment in the public sector, another low-productivity sector. In addition, the public sector pays higher wages, provides better benefits, and is a job for life (Hausmann et al., 2020). This raises the reservation wage for working in the private sector, making it harder to compete in world markets.
In short, Athukorala's anti-tradable bias is part of an “anti-productivity bias,” one that has kept Sri Lanka from fulfilling its potential for decades and contributed to the perfect storm of 2022.
These policies have been pursued by left- and right-wing governments, so they could not be due to ideology. I suggest they stem from a lack of accountability. That Sri Lanka is a democracy indicates that the people of Sri Lanka could hold politicians accountable for economic policy decisions at elections. But in a country with deep ethnic cleavages (which resulted in a 26-year civil war), many people vote along linguistic or religious lines, rather than on the economic performance of the incumbent. Knowing this, politicians pursue populist policies during election times, enough to get them elected but at the cost of the economy's productivity.
Worse, policymakers have chosen directions that minimize their accountability to the people and maximize their ability to control the public. For instance, macroeconomic instability in Sri Lanka is caused, as Athukorala notes, by government financing fiscal deficits by borrowing from the central bank. While this causes inflation with a lag, the two other options for financing a fiscal deficit—borrowing from domestic capital markets and borrowing abroad—hold government accountable instantly by raising borrowing costs.
Trade liberalization makes producers accountable to world markets. Protectionism, the Paddy Lands Act, and labor market regulations enable governments to control who gets the benefits, that is, who is accountable to government.
In sum, Athukorala's valuable paper has triggered discussion on the multiple factors that led to Sri Lanka's debt crisis. In considering strategies for recovery, we should pursue policies that strengthen the public's ability to hold government accountable, rather than the other way around.
阿图科拉拉(2025)令人信服地指出,斯里兰卡2022年的债务危机不仅是由于最近鲁莽的经济政策——大规模减税、通过印钞融资财政赤字、用储备偿还外债——而且是数十年来“反贸易”偏见的高潮,这种偏见导致经济无法管理高水平的债务,特别是在2019冠状病毒病危机之后。这项分析是基于对斯里兰卡经济史的全面回顾,从独立之前开始,到目前国际货币基金组织(imf)支持的2023年项目结束。这一漫长的过渡期有助于解决该国政策方向的难题。上世纪70年代末,斯里兰卡是首批实现贸易自由化的发展中国家之一。经济蓬勃发展。许多人称赞斯里兰卡是成功的贸易改革的教科书案例(例如,参见卡斯特罗和;Devarajan, 2006)。然而,该国很快开始采取反贸易政策,这一政策在21世纪初加速,导致2022年的崩溃。阿图科拉拉观察到,贸易自由化伴随着宽松的宏观经济政策,例如高估的汇率,这使得改革难以维持。20世纪80年代初,公共投资也大幅增加,这促进了实际汇率的升值和经济的繁荣。我对Athukorala(2025)的评论旨在扩大导致债务危机的一系列政策,并探讨斯里兰卡政策制定者选择这些政策的原因。除了反贸易政策,斯里兰卡还实施了至少另外两项损害经济增长的政策。1958年出台的《水田法》要求从国家租赁土地的农民(大多数是农民)只能种植水田。阿图科拉拉提到,《稻田法》是20世纪50年代走向封闭经济的一部分。70年后,该法案仍然有效。水稻是产量最低、利润最低的作物(世界银行,2021年)。这一政策使农业成为经济中生产力最低的部门,使农民陷入贫困。其次,斯里兰卡拥有世界上最严格的劳动法规(Abidoye et al., 2009)。工龄达20年的员工平均可获得30个月的遣散费。毫不奇怪,正规私营部门的就业增长缓慢。这种情况在20世纪80年代青年人口进入劳动力市场时变得更加严重。为了平息暴力抗议,政府扩大了另一个低生产率部门——公共部门的就业。此外,公共部门支付更高的工资,提供更好的福利,是一份终身工作(Hausmann et al., 2020)。这提高了在私营部门工作的保留工资,使其更难在世界市场上竞争。简而言之,阿图科拉拉的反贸易偏见是“反生产力偏见”的一部分,这种偏见几十年来一直使斯里兰卡无法发挥其潜力,并促成了2022年的完美风暴。这些政策一直是左翼和右翼政府所追求的,因此它们不可能是由于意识形态。我认为它们源于缺乏问责制。斯里兰卡是一个民主国家,这表明斯里兰卡人民可以在选举中要求政治家对经济政策决策负责。但在一个有着深刻种族分裂(导致了长达26年的内战)的国家,许多人根据语言或宗教界线投票,而不是根据现任总统的经济表现投票。知道这一点后,政客们在选举期间推行民粹主义政策,这足以让他们当选,但却以牺牲经济生产力为代价。更糟糕的是,决策者选择的方向使他们对人民的责任最小化,而使他们控制公众的能力最大化。例如,正如阿苏科拉拉指出的那样,斯里兰卡的宏观经济不稳定是由政府通过向央行借款为财政赤字融资造成的。虽然这会导致滞后的通货膨胀,但为财政赤字融资的另外两种选择——从国内资本市场借款和从国外借款——通过提高借款成本,使政府立即承担责任。贸易自由化使生产者对世界市场负责。保护主义、《稻田法》和劳动力市场法规使政府能够控制谁获得利益,也就是说,谁对政府负责。总之,Athukorala这篇有价值的论文引发了对导致斯里兰卡债务危机的多重因素的讨论。在考虑复苏战略时,我们应该采取加强公众对政府问责能力的政策,而不是相反。
期刊介绍:
The goal of the Asian Economic Policy Review is to become an intellectual voice on the current issues of international economics and economic policy, based on comprehensive and in-depth analyses, with a primary focus on Asia. Emphasis is placed on identifying key issues at the time - spanning international trade, international finance, the environment, energy, the integration of regional economies and other issues - in order to furnish ideas and proposals to contribute positively to the policy debate in the region.