Structural mechanisms affecting policy subsystems activity: beyond individual and group behavioral propensities in policy design and policy change

Michael Howlett
{"title":"Structural mechanisms affecting policy subsystems activity: beyond individual and group behavioral propensities in policy design and policy change","authors":"Michael Howlett","doi":"10.4337/9781788118194.00011","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Policy sectors constitute distinct policy regimes consisting of the current collectively accepted definition of an issue, the current relevant policies (laws, regulations, fiscal instruments, government programs and relationships), and the actors and institutions (both inside and outside government) actively engaged in implementing and modifying them (Harris and Milkis, 1989; Eisner, 1994a, 1994b). These regimes are constructed at the “subsystem” level (McCool, 1998), that is, as subsets of political, social and economic systems and the various actors and activities of which those are comprised. According to Sabatier (1998, p. 99), “[a] subsystem consists of actors from a variety of public and private organizations who are actively concerned with a policy problem or issue, such as agriculture, and who regularly seek to influence public policy in that domain.” Such subsystems, he argued, provide “the most useful unit of analysis for understanding the overall policy process,” superior to the use of other units such as government organizations or programs. How these subsystems operate and what impact they have on policies and vice versa is a long-standing question in the policy sciences (Cater, 1964). Often these subsystems are viewed as examples of a general class of stable “homeostatic” systems that are self-adjusting or self-equilibrating in routine circumstances and often thought of as changing only under the pressure of external shocks or “jolts” that introduce new extraneous elements into the system, throwing them out of equilibrium (Sabatier, 1988; Aminzade, 1992). This notion of the exogenous nature of subsystem change focuses analytical attention on the various types of external crises that could provoke changes in","PeriodicalId":120146,"journal":{"name":"Making Policies Work","volume":"18 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2019-03-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Making Policies Work","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.4337/9781788118194.00011","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

Policy sectors constitute distinct policy regimes consisting of the current collectively accepted definition of an issue, the current relevant policies (laws, regulations, fiscal instruments, government programs and relationships), and the actors and institutions (both inside and outside government) actively engaged in implementing and modifying them (Harris and Milkis, 1989; Eisner, 1994a, 1994b). These regimes are constructed at the “subsystem” level (McCool, 1998), that is, as subsets of political, social and economic systems and the various actors and activities of which those are comprised. According to Sabatier (1998, p. 99), “[a] subsystem consists of actors from a variety of public and private organizations who are actively concerned with a policy problem or issue, such as agriculture, and who regularly seek to influence public policy in that domain.” Such subsystems, he argued, provide “the most useful unit of analysis for understanding the overall policy process,” superior to the use of other units such as government organizations or programs. How these subsystems operate and what impact they have on policies and vice versa is a long-standing question in the policy sciences (Cater, 1964). Often these subsystems are viewed as examples of a general class of stable “homeostatic” systems that are self-adjusting or self-equilibrating in routine circumstances and often thought of as changing only under the pressure of external shocks or “jolts” that introduce new extraneous elements into the system, throwing them out of equilibrium (Sabatier, 1988; Aminzade, 1992). This notion of the exogenous nature of subsystem change focuses analytical attention on the various types of external crises that could provoke changes in
影响政策子系统活动的结构机制:超越政策设计和政策变化中的个人和群体行为倾向
政策部门构成了不同的政策体系,包括当前集体接受的问题定义、当前相关政策(法律、法规、财政工具、政府计划和关系),以及积极参与实施和修改这些政策的行为者和机构(政府内外)(Harris and Milkis, 1989;Eisner, 1994a, 1994b)。这些制度是在“子系统”层面构建的(McCool, 1998),也就是说,作为政治、社会和经济系统的子集,以及组成这些系统的各种行动者和活动。根据Sabatier (1998, p. 99)的说法,“[a]子系统由来自各种公共和私人组织的行动者组成,他们积极关注政策问题或议题,如农业,并定期寻求影响该领域的公共政策。”他认为,这些子系统提供了“理解整体政策过程最有用的分析单元”,优于使用其他单元,如政府组织或项目。这些子系统是如何运作的,它们对政策有什么影响,反之亦然,这是政策科学中一个长期存在的问题(卡特,1964)。这些子系统通常被视为一类稳定的“内稳态”系统的例子,这些系统在日常环境中自我调节或自我平衡,通常被认为只有在外部冲击或“颠簸”的压力下才会发生变化,这些冲击或“颠簸”将新的外来元素引入系统,使其失去平衡(Sabatier, 1988;Aminzade, 1992)。子系统变化的外生性质的概念将分析的注意力集中在可能引起变化的各种类型的外部危机上
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信