{"title":"Is the Most Unproductive Firm the Foundation of the Most Efficient Economy? Penrosian Learning Confronts the Neoclassical Fallacy","authors":"William Lazonick","doi":"10.36687/inetwp111","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Edith Penrose’s 1959 book The Theory of the Growth of the Firm [TGF] provides intellectual foundations for a theory of innovative enterprise, which is essential to any attempt to explain productivity growth, employment opportunity, and income distribution. Properly understood, Penrose’s theory of the firm is also an antidote to the deception that is foundational to neoclassical economics: The theory, taught by PhD economists to millions upon millions of college students for over seven decades, that the most unproductive firm is the foundation of the most efficient economy. The dissemination of this “neoclassical fallacy” to a mass audience of college students began with Paul A. Samuelson’s textbook, Economics: An Introductory Analysis, first published in 1948. Over the decades, the neoclassical fallacy has persisted through 18 revisions of Samuelson, Economics and in its countless “economics principles” clones. This essay challenges the intellectual hegemony of neoclassical economics by exposing the illogic of its foundational assumptions about how a modern economy functions and performs.\n\nThe neoclassical fallacy gained popularity in the 1950s, during which decade Samuelson revised Economics three times. Meanwhile, Penrose derived the logic of organizational learning that she lays out in TGF from the facts of firm growth, absorbing what was known in the 1950s about the large corporations that had come to dominate the U.S. economy. Also, during that decade, the knowledge base on the growth of firms on which economists could subsequently draw was undergoing an intellectual revolution, led by the business historian, Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. He was engaged in the first stage of a career that would span more than a half century, during which Chandler documented and analyzed the centrality to U.S economic development of what he would come to call “the managerial revolution in American business.”\n\nIn combination, the works of Penrose and Chandler form intellectual foundations for my own work on the Theory of Innovative Enterprise—an endeavor that has enabled me, as an economist, to recognize not only the profound importance of organizational learning for economic theory but also the illogic of the neoclassical theory of the firm for our understanding of the central institution of a modern economy, the business corporation. In this essay, I argue that the key characteristic of the innovative enterprise is fixed-cost investment in the productive capabilities of the company’s employees to engage in organizational learning. The purpose of this investment in organizational learning is to develop a higher-quality product than was previously available. When successful, the development of the higher-quality product enables the firm to capture a large extent of the market, transforming high fixed cost into low unit cost. The result is sustainable competitive advantage that enables the growth of the firm, contributing to the growth of the economy as a whole.\n\nI argue that to get beyond the neoclassical fallacy, economists have to stop relying on constrained-optimization methodology. Rather, they need to be trained in a “historical transformation” methodology that integrates history and theory. It is a methodology in which theory serves as both a distillation of what we have learned from the study of history and a guide to what we need to learn about reality as the “present as history” unfolds.","PeriodicalId":253619,"journal":{"name":"History of Economics eJournal","volume":"12 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2020-01-26","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"13","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"History of Economics eJournal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.36687/inetwp111","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 13
Abstract
Edith Penrose’s 1959 book The Theory of the Growth of the Firm [TGF] provides intellectual foundations for a theory of innovative enterprise, which is essential to any attempt to explain productivity growth, employment opportunity, and income distribution. Properly understood, Penrose’s theory of the firm is also an antidote to the deception that is foundational to neoclassical economics: The theory, taught by PhD economists to millions upon millions of college students for over seven decades, that the most unproductive firm is the foundation of the most efficient economy. The dissemination of this “neoclassical fallacy” to a mass audience of college students began with Paul A. Samuelson’s textbook, Economics: An Introductory Analysis, first published in 1948. Over the decades, the neoclassical fallacy has persisted through 18 revisions of Samuelson, Economics and in its countless “economics principles” clones. This essay challenges the intellectual hegemony of neoclassical economics by exposing the illogic of its foundational assumptions about how a modern economy functions and performs.
The neoclassical fallacy gained popularity in the 1950s, during which decade Samuelson revised Economics three times. Meanwhile, Penrose derived the logic of organizational learning that she lays out in TGF from the facts of firm growth, absorbing what was known in the 1950s about the large corporations that had come to dominate the U.S. economy. Also, during that decade, the knowledge base on the growth of firms on which economists could subsequently draw was undergoing an intellectual revolution, led by the business historian, Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. He was engaged in the first stage of a career that would span more than a half century, during which Chandler documented and analyzed the centrality to U.S economic development of what he would come to call “the managerial revolution in American business.”
In combination, the works of Penrose and Chandler form intellectual foundations for my own work on the Theory of Innovative Enterprise—an endeavor that has enabled me, as an economist, to recognize not only the profound importance of organizational learning for economic theory but also the illogic of the neoclassical theory of the firm for our understanding of the central institution of a modern economy, the business corporation. In this essay, I argue that the key characteristic of the innovative enterprise is fixed-cost investment in the productive capabilities of the company’s employees to engage in organizational learning. The purpose of this investment in organizational learning is to develop a higher-quality product than was previously available. When successful, the development of the higher-quality product enables the firm to capture a large extent of the market, transforming high fixed cost into low unit cost. The result is sustainable competitive advantage that enables the growth of the firm, contributing to the growth of the economy as a whole.
I argue that to get beyond the neoclassical fallacy, economists have to stop relying on constrained-optimization methodology. Rather, they need to be trained in a “historical transformation” methodology that integrates history and theory. It is a methodology in which theory serves as both a distillation of what we have learned from the study of history and a guide to what we need to learn about reality as the “present as history” unfolds.
Edith Penrose 1959年的著作《企业成长理论》(The Theory of The Growth of The Firm [TGF])为创新型企业理论提供了理论基础,这对于解释生产率增长、就业机会和收入分配的任何尝试都是至关重要的。如果理解得当,彭罗斯的企业理论也是新古典经济学基础欺骗的解药:70多年来,经济学博士们向数百万大学生传授的理论是,生产率最低的企业是效率最高的经济的基础。这种“新古典谬误”在大学生群体中的传播始于保罗·a·萨缪尔森(Paul a . Samuelson)于1948年首次出版的教科书《经济学:入门分析》(Economics: a介绍性分析)。几十年来,新古典主义谬论在萨缪尔森的《经济学》一书及其无数“经济学原理”克隆版的18次修订中持续存在。本文通过揭露新古典经济学关于现代经济如何运作和执行的基本假设的不逻辑,挑战了新古典经济学的知识霸权。新古典主义谬论在20世纪50年代开始流行,在此期间,萨缪尔森三次修订《经济学》。与此同时,彭罗斯从企业成长的事实中推导出了她在《TGF》中阐述的组织学习的逻辑,吸收了20世纪50年代关于大公司的知识,这些大公司已经主宰了美国经济。此外,在那个十年里,经济学家随后可以借鉴的关于公司成长的知识基础正在经历一场由商业历史学家阿尔弗雷德·d·钱德勒领导的知识革命。他的职业生涯进入了半个多世纪的第一阶段,在此期间,钱德勒记录并分析了他后来称之为“美国商业管理革命”的美国经济发展的中心地位。综上所述,彭罗斯和钱德勒的著作为我自己的创新企业理论奠定了思想基础——作为一名经济学家,这一努力使我不仅认识到组织学习对经济理论的深刻重要性,而且认识到新古典企业理论对我们理解现代经济的中心制度——商业公司——的非逻辑性。在本文中,我认为创新型企业的关键特征是公司员工从事组织学习的生产能力的固定成本投资。这种对组织学习的投资的目的是开发出比以前更高质量的产品。当成功时,高质量产品的开发使企业能够占领很大程度的市场,将高固定成本转化为低单位成本。其结果是可持续的竞争优势,使企业的增长,促进经济的增长作为一个整体。我认为,要摆脱新古典主义谬误,经济学家必须停止依赖约束优化方法。相反,他们需要接受一种整合历史和理论的“历史转型”方法论的培训。在这种方法论中,理论既是我们从历史研究中学到的东西的精华,也是我们在“作为历史的现在”展开时需要了解的现实的指南。