A Comparative Case Study: Memory, Law and Morality

Ilana Maymind
{"title":"A Comparative Case Study: Memory, Law and Morality","authors":"Ilana Maymind","doi":"10.5840/JIPR2013185","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Comparative analysis of two Salvadoran towns with similar patterns of international migration but different historical land-tenure patterns reveals the emergence of radically different development strategies. Whereas in one case, mostly landed households with a history of farming commercially have been selling land and abandoning agriculture, in the other case, previously landless households whose members worked as sharecroppers before the onset of migration have been acquiring land and farming as much as possible. The opposite processes at work in these two cases raise important theoretical questions for both migration and development studies. Using ethnographic, census, and historical data, I examine how and why land ownership, under particular historical circumstances, conditions the impact of migration on development. Extensive poverty in Central America is linked historically to landlessness among the majority of the region’s population (Ripton 2006; Dunkerley 1988; BulmerThomas 1987; World Bank 2007). In the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, oligarchs institutionalized inequality in ownership of productive farmland, access to which would have enabled many Central Americans to incorporate themselves into their national economies. Instead, states constructed agro-export economies and supported the expansion of large estates through the 1970s (Ripton 2006; Dunkerley 1988; Paige 1997). This entailed expelling more and more peasants from the arable land to develop large coffee, cotton, banana, and sugar farms on which landowners managed production for export (Dunkerley 1988). Even today, as Central American leaders deemphasize the agro-export sector to instead experiment with maquiladora-based economies, fi nanced in part by growing migrant remittances (Hausman and Rodrik 2005; Gammage 2006), scholars identify access to arable land as a signifi cant means of buffering families against the effects of all-too-frequent labor market crises (Conning, Olinto, and Trigueros 2001). Central Americans who have at least some access to arable land have been better able to diversify their economic activities to ensure a nominal income or subsistence, whereas those who have remained landless suffer the greatest indices of poverty (World Bank 2007). In contrast to Mexico, where early twentieth-century revolution stimulated The author would like to thank L. Frank Weyher, Adrian Favell, César Ayala, Edward Telles, Rubén Hernández León, Dana Britton, László Kulscár, Erynn Casanova, participants in the UCLA International Migration Workshop, and the three anonymous LARR reviewers for helpful comments on previous drafts of this article. The Latin American Studies Program at UCLA and the Mellon Foundation provided fi nancial support for the research. P6079.indb 133 3/6/13 11:33:06 AM 134 Latin American Research Review land reforms resulting in the redistribution of more than 50 percent of the country’s arable land (Kay 1995), land reform in Central America has been modest and late. Several scholars hold delayed and incomplete land reforms responsible for thwarting development in Central America (Kay 2002; Dunkerley 1988; Ripton 2006; Paige 1997). By contrast, state-led land reform and industrialization in Taiwan and South Korea stimulated greater production of agricultural surplus that was used to feed the urban proletariat inexpensively, thus enabling domestic industrial bourgeoisies to launch new industry locally (Kay 2002; Amsden 1979, 1994). Greater productivity in agriculture also created an internal market for urban industrial goods, as well as a platform for innovation under appropriate macro economic management (Wade 1993; Kay 2002, 2006; Amsden 1979, 1990, 2001). Wages in both sectors rose. Central American countries have largely failed to follow this trajectory. Instead, failed development in Central America has played an important role in stimulating mass migration. Vast inequities in land distribution unleashed peasant uprisings that resulted in civil and revolutionary war across the isthmus from the late 1960s to the 1990s. Hundreds of thousands of Central Americans fl ed poverty and sociopolitical violence, with more than 80 percent destined for the United States. However, rather than subsiding with the conclusion of these wars, Central American migration persists. El Salvador, Guatemala, Nicaragua, and Honduras are today among the largest and fastest-growing source countries for migration to the United States (US Citizenship and Immigration Services [USCIS] 2009). El Salvador’s signifi cant migratory history and internal variation make it an ideal candidate for studying how the explosion in migration during recent decades bears on actors’ efforts to generate development across different local contexts.1 During the past twelve years, El Salvador has ranked among the top ten global source countries for unauthorized migrants to the United States: from the year 2000 through 2006, it ranked second, behind Mexico (USCIS 2009). This is particularly remarkable given that Mexico’s population of 104 million is nearly fi fteen times the size of El Salvador’s population of 7 million. From 2004 through 2006, moreover, Salvadorans ranked eighth on the list of source countries for US legal permanent resident fl ows—fi ve ranks below China and three below India— and twelfth for naturalizations during the same time period (USCIS 2009). Nineteen percent of El Salvador’s population currently lives abroad, and 22 percent of households in El Salvador receive remittances.2 Annual national remittance receipts amount to approximately $2 billion, or the equivalent of more than 16 percent of El Salvador’s gross domestic product. From 1978 to 2004, the main source of El Salvador’s foreign exchange shifted from agro-exports to migrant remittances (Hecht et al. 2006; UN Development Program [UNDP] 2005). At national and household levels, migration affects how Salvadorans use land, manage their assets, and plan futures in El Salvador. 1. Development here refers to the ability of a society to organize its production and distribution of goods and services to maximize the welfare of as many people as possible (Block 1990). 2. However, whereas in some municipalities nearly 75 percent of households engage in migration, in others fewer than 10 percent do (Andrade-Eekhoff 2003; UNDP 2005). P6079.indb 134 3/6/13 11:33:06 AM LAND TENURE, MIGRATION, AND DEVELOPMENT 135 At the same time, migration occurs across communities with highly variable land-tenure patterns. In some municipalities, few households historically owned their own land, whereas in others, the majority did (Lardé y Larín 2000; Ripton 2006). How do preexisting land-tenure patterns affect the development strategies that local households in high-migration communities pursue? LAND TENURE, MIGRATION, AND DEVELOPMENT: MAKING CONNECTIONS The nature of the relationship between migration and development has long divided scholars. Some scholars draw on modernization theory and argue that development stimulates migration by disrupting peasants’ farming communities (Massey 1988; Durand and Massey 1992; Taylor et al. 1996). This migration, in turn, enables money and ideas to fl ow from more advanced developing countries to less developed ones, and itself becomes a force for development (Massey 1988, 282, 398; Sana and Massey 2005; Levitt and Nyberg-Sørensen 2004). However, once enough jobs are created through urbanization and industrialization, synonymous with development in this view, pressures to migrate will weaken (Massey 1988). In sharp contrast to this view, another set of scholars draws on dependency theories of development to argue that the reverse is true (e.g., Binford 2003; Weist 1984; Reichert 1981). Lack of employment, poor infrastructure, and poor-quality public services stimulate migration, which depletes sending communities of young and able workers, which in turn dampens development prospects. In this view, underdevelopment begets migration and further underdevelopment. Because several scholars have already documented the debate between so-called optimists and pessimists on the question of migration’s developmental impact per se (most recently, see Haas 2010), I focus on the extent to which those engaging in this debate address the issue of land tenure more specifi cally. I then turn briefl y to scholarship that suggests how state policy may affect the relationship between land tenure, migration, and development in El Salvador. From a modernization perspective, Massey (1988, 391–393) argues that capital investment and land consolidation are necessary to modernize agriculture and promote development. By the same token, these processes are labor saving rather than labor generating. Modernization of agriculture thus stimulates international migration among displaced peasant farmers, at least until cheap foodstuffs produced through modern agriculture create enough domestic industry to absorb displaced rural workers (Massey 1988; Durand and Massey 1992). Further, rural households receiving remittances are likely to expand the modernization of agriculture by acquiring larger landholdings and investing in new labor-saving technologies, thus perpetuating migration (Durand and Massey 1992, 18–19, 26; see also Massey et al. 1987; Massey 1988, 282, 398; Sana and Massey 2005). Although her work addresses the effects of land tenure on migration and not the effects of land tenure on development, Van Wey (2005) similarly found that members of households with large amounts of land (far above average) are likely to migrate in order to secure capital for investment in acquiring more land and improving production (see also Findley 1987). Although members of landless households also migrate to purchase land, they are less likely to continue to migrate to purP6079.indb 135 3/6/13 11:33:06 AM 136 Latin American Research Review chase more land once their household has acquired some, even small amounts (in ","PeriodicalId":292051,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Indian Philosophy and Religion","volume":"30 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2013-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"10","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of Indian Philosophy and Religion","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.5840/JIPR2013185","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 10

Abstract

Comparative analysis of two Salvadoran towns with similar patterns of international migration but different historical land-tenure patterns reveals the emergence of radically different development strategies. Whereas in one case, mostly landed households with a history of farming commercially have been selling land and abandoning agriculture, in the other case, previously landless households whose members worked as sharecroppers before the onset of migration have been acquiring land and farming as much as possible. The opposite processes at work in these two cases raise important theoretical questions for both migration and development studies. Using ethnographic, census, and historical data, I examine how and why land ownership, under particular historical circumstances, conditions the impact of migration on development. Extensive poverty in Central America is linked historically to landlessness among the majority of the region’s population (Ripton 2006; Dunkerley 1988; BulmerThomas 1987; World Bank 2007). In the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, oligarchs institutionalized inequality in ownership of productive farmland, access to which would have enabled many Central Americans to incorporate themselves into their national economies. Instead, states constructed agro-export economies and supported the expansion of large estates through the 1970s (Ripton 2006; Dunkerley 1988; Paige 1997). This entailed expelling more and more peasants from the arable land to develop large coffee, cotton, banana, and sugar farms on which landowners managed production for export (Dunkerley 1988). Even today, as Central American leaders deemphasize the agro-export sector to instead experiment with maquiladora-based economies, fi nanced in part by growing migrant remittances (Hausman and Rodrik 2005; Gammage 2006), scholars identify access to arable land as a signifi cant means of buffering families against the effects of all-too-frequent labor market crises (Conning, Olinto, and Trigueros 2001). Central Americans who have at least some access to arable land have been better able to diversify their economic activities to ensure a nominal income or subsistence, whereas those who have remained landless suffer the greatest indices of poverty (World Bank 2007). In contrast to Mexico, where early twentieth-century revolution stimulated The author would like to thank L. Frank Weyher, Adrian Favell, César Ayala, Edward Telles, Rubén Hernández León, Dana Britton, László Kulscár, Erynn Casanova, participants in the UCLA International Migration Workshop, and the three anonymous LARR reviewers for helpful comments on previous drafts of this article. The Latin American Studies Program at UCLA and the Mellon Foundation provided fi nancial support for the research. P6079.indb 133 3/6/13 11:33:06 AM 134 Latin American Research Review land reforms resulting in the redistribution of more than 50 percent of the country’s arable land (Kay 1995), land reform in Central America has been modest and late. Several scholars hold delayed and incomplete land reforms responsible for thwarting development in Central America (Kay 2002; Dunkerley 1988; Ripton 2006; Paige 1997). By contrast, state-led land reform and industrialization in Taiwan and South Korea stimulated greater production of agricultural surplus that was used to feed the urban proletariat inexpensively, thus enabling domestic industrial bourgeoisies to launch new industry locally (Kay 2002; Amsden 1979, 1994). Greater productivity in agriculture also created an internal market for urban industrial goods, as well as a platform for innovation under appropriate macro economic management (Wade 1993; Kay 2002, 2006; Amsden 1979, 1990, 2001). Wages in both sectors rose. Central American countries have largely failed to follow this trajectory. Instead, failed development in Central America has played an important role in stimulating mass migration. Vast inequities in land distribution unleashed peasant uprisings that resulted in civil and revolutionary war across the isthmus from the late 1960s to the 1990s. Hundreds of thousands of Central Americans fl ed poverty and sociopolitical violence, with more than 80 percent destined for the United States. However, rather than subsiding with the conclusion of these wars, Central American migration persists. El Salvador, Guatemala, Nicaragua, and Honduras are today among the largest and fastest-growing source countries for migration to the United States (US Citizenship and Immigration Services [USCIS] 2009). El Salvador’s signifi cant migratory history and internal variation make it an ideal candidate for studying how the explosion in migration during recent decades bears on actors’ efforts to generate development across different local contexts.1 During the past twelve years, El Salvador has ranked among the top ten global source countries for unauthorized migrants to the United States: from the year 2000 through 2006, it ranked second, behind Mexico (USCIS 2009). This is particularly remarkable given that Mexico’s population of 104 million is nearly fi fteen times the size of El Salvador’s population of 7 million. From 2004 through 2006, moreover, Salvadorans ranked eighth on the list of source countries for US legal permanent resident fl ows—fi ve ranks below China and three below India— and twelfth for naturalizations during the same time period (USCIS 2009). Nineteen percent of El Salvador’s population currently lives abroad, and 22 percent of households in El Salvador receive remittances.2 Annual national remittance receipts amount to approximately $2 billion, or the equivalent of more than 16 percent of El Salvador’s gross domestic product. From 1978 to 2004, the main source of El Salvador’s foreign exchange shifted from agro-exports to migrant remittances (Hecht et al. 2006; UN Development Program [UNDP] 2005). At national and household levels, migration affects how Salvadorans use land, manage their assets, and plan futures in El Salvador. 1. Development here refers to the ability of a society to organize its production and distribution of goods and services to maximize the welfare of as many people as possible (Block 1990). 2. However, whereas in some municipalities nearly 75 percent of households engage in migration, in others fewer than 10 percent do (Andrade-Eekhoff 2003; UNDP 2005). P6079.indb 134 3/6/13 11:33:06 AM LAND TENURE, MIGRATION, AND DEVELOPMENT 135 At the same time, migration occurs across communities with highly variable land-tenure patterns. In some municipalities, few households historically owned their own land, whereas in others, the majority did (Lardé y Larín 2000; Ripton 2006). How do preexisting land-tenure patterns affect the development strategies that local households in high-migration communities pursue? LAND TENURE, MIGRATION, AND DEVELOPMENT: MAKING CONNECTIONS The nature of the relationship between migration and development has long divided scholars. Some scholars draw on modernization theory and argue that development stimulates migration by disrupting peasants’ farming communities (Massey 1988; Durand and Massey 1992; Taylor et al. 1996). This migration, in turn, enables money and ideas to fl ow from more advanced developing countries to less developed ones, and itself becomes a force for development (Massey 1988, 282, 398; Sana and Massey 2005; Levitt and Nyberg-Sørensen 2004). However, once enough jobs are created through urbanization and industrialization, synonymous with development in this view, pressures to migrate will weaken (Massey 1988). In sharp contrast to this view, another set of scholars draws on dependency theories of development to argue that the reverse is true (e.g., Binford 2003; Weist 1984; Reichert 1981). Lack of employment, poor infrastructure, and poor-quality public services stimulate migration, which depletes sending communities of young and able workers, which in turn dampens development prospects. In this view, underdevelopment begets migration and further underdevelopment. Because several scholars have already documented the debate between so-called optimists and pessimists on the question of migration’s developmental impact per se (most recently, see Haas 2010), I focus on the extent to which those engaging in this debate address the issue of land tenure more specifi cally. I then turn briefl y to scholarship that suggests how state policy may affect the relationship between land tenure, migration, and development in El Salvador. From a modernization perspective, Massey (1988, 391–393) argues that capital investment and land consolidation are necessary to modernize agriculture and promote development. By the same token, these processes are labor saving rather than labor generating. Modernization of agriculture thus stimulates international migration among displaced peasant farmers, at least until cheap foodstuffs produced through modern agriculture create enough domestic industry to absorb displaced rural workers (Massey 1988; Durand and Massey 1992). Further, rural households receiving remittances are likely to expand the modernization of agriculture by acquiring larger landholdings and investing in new labor-saving technologies, thus perpetuating migration (Durand and Massey 1992, 18–19, 26; see also Massey et al. 1987; Massey 1988, 282, 398; Sana and Massey 2005). Although her work addresses the effects of land tenure on migration and not the effects of land tenure on development, Van Wey (2005) similarly found that members of households with large amounts of land (far above average) are likely to migrate in order to secure capital for investment in acquiring more land and improving production (see also Findley 1987). Although members of landless households also migrate to purchase land, they are less likely to continue to migrate to purP6079.indb 135 3/6/13 11:33:06 AM 136 Latin American Research Review chase more land once their household has acquired some, even small amounts (in
案例比较研究:记忆、法律与道德
在过去的12年里,萨尔瓦多一直是美国非法移民的全球十大来源国之一:从2000年到2006年,它排名第二,仅次于墨西哥(USCIS 2009)。考虑到墨西哥1.04亿人口几乎是萨尔瓦多700万人口的15倍,这一点尤其引人注目。此外,从2004年到2006年,萨尔瓦多人在美国合法永久居民流动的来源国名单上排名第八,比中国低5位,比印度低3位,在同一时期的入籍人数中排名第十二(美国公民及移民服务局2009年)。目前,萨尔瓦多有19%的人口居住在国外,22%的家庭接受汇款每年全国汇款收入约为20亿美元,相当于萨尔瓦多国内生产总值的16%以上。从1978年到2004年,萨尔瓦多外汇的主要来源从农产品出口转向移民汇款(Hecht et al. 2006;联合国开发计划署[UNDP] 2005)。在国家和家庭层面,移民影响着萨尔瓦多人如何使用土地、管理资产和规划萨尔瓦多的未来。这里的发展指的是一个社会组织其产品和服务的生产和分配,以使尽可能多的人的福利最大化的能力(Block 1990)。2. 然而,在一些城市,近75%的家庭从事移民,而在其他城市,这一比例不到10% (Andrade-Eekhoff 2003;联合国开发计划署2005)。P6079。与此同时,移徙发生在土地保有模式变化很大的社区之间。在一些城市,历史上很少有家庭拥有自己的土地,而在另一些城市,大多数家庭拥有自己的土地(lard<e:1> Larín 2000;雷谱敦2006)。先前存在的土地所有制模式如何影响高移徙社区当地家庭所追求的发展战略?长期以来,学者们对移民与发展之间关系的本质存在分歧。一些学者借鉴现代化理论,认为发展通过扰乱农民的农业社区来刺激移民(Massey 1988;Durand and Massey 1992;Taylor et al. 1996)。这种移徙,反过来,使资金和思想从更先进的发展中国家流向欠发达国家,并本身成为发展的力量(Massey 1988, 282, 398;Sana and Massey 2005;Levitt and nyberg - s - ørensen 2004)。然而,一旦通过城市化和工业化创造了足够的就业机会,移民的压力就会减弱(Massey 1988)。与这一观点形成鲜明对比的是,另一组学者利用发展的依赖理论,认为情况正好相反(例如,Binford 2003;怀斯特1984;Reichert 1981)。缺乏就业、基础设施落后和公共服务质量低下刺激了移民,这耗尽了移民社区的年轻和有能力的工人,反过来又抑制了发展前景。按照这种观点,不发达导致移徙和进一步的不发达。因为一些学者已经记录了所谓的乐观主义者和悲观主义者之间关于移民本身对发展影响问题的争论(最近,见Haas 2010),我关注的是参与这场辩论的人在多大程度上更具体地解决了土地所有权问题。然后,我简要地介绍了一些学术研究,这些研究表明,国家政策如何影响萨尔瓦多土地保有权、移民和发展之间的关系。从现代化的角度来看,Massey(1988,391 - 393)认为资本投资和土地整理是农业现代化和促进发展的必要条件。出于同样的原因,这些过程是节省劳动力而不是产生劳动力。因此,农业现代化刺激了流离失所的农民之间的国际移民,至少在通过现代农业生产的廉价食品创造足够的国内工业来吸收流离失所的农村工人之前(Massey 1988;Durand and Massey 1992)。此外,收到汇款的农村家庭可能会通过获得更大的土地所有权和投资新的节省劳动力的技术来扩大农业现代化,从而使移民永续化(Durand and Massey 1992,18 - 19,26;参见Massey et al. 1987;Massey 1988, 282, 398;Sana and Massey 2005)。尽管她的研究关注的是土地所有权对移民的影响,而不是土地所有权对发展的影响,Van Wey(2005)同样发现,拥有大量土地(远高于平均水平)的家庭成员可能会迁移,以确保获得更多土地和提高生产的投资资本(另见Findley 1987)。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信