对政治经济学现状的思考

Q3 Economics, Econometrics and Finance
R. Vedder
{"title":"对政治经济学现状的思考","authors":"R. Vedder","doi":"10.1163/2210-7975_hrd-0164-2016003","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Like most economics professors, I have spent my academic lifetime examining the economic and public policy effects of issues involving the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services--political economy, if you will. There is, however, a \"political economy\" to die very act of producing and disseminating economic knowledge and examining public policies. And that political economy and my assessment of it has changed over a career spanning more than half a century. In this brief article, I will confine my attention mostly to the research dimension and look at five issues, most relating to the political economy of the study of political economy. Diminishing Returns to Research I have long been bemused by economists who profess to understand the principle of scarcity and the importance of opportunity costs, yet write so much trivia of little interest to anyone. They do so because of the nonmarket nature of most academic endeavors and the utter lack of incentives to be efficient. The fifteenth paper on a topic is not very likely to add as much to our stock of knowledge as the first or second. I think the nation as a whole has probably overinvested in higher education because of vast governmental subsidies (an argument best made by retired professors like me whose potential acquisition of economic rents by extolling higher education is minimal). That manifests itself in such phenomena as the overeducated Starbucks barista or in the more than 115,000 janitors with bachelor s degrees. It also means roughly 1,000 academic papers are being written on William Shakespeare annually--three per day (Bauerlein 2009: 6). Who reads them? How much does a typical paper add at the margin to the insights that Shakespeare gave us 400 years ago? The problem extends to the inputs as the well as the outputs of higher education, and too many professors are writing too many words (and equations) that, to borrow from the Bard (Shakespeare to college graduates after 1990), \"signify nothing.\" What if professors wrote only one-third or one-half the number of papers they currently write, but taught one more class per year? My guess is that the net effects would be at least mildly positive, maybe even leading to smaller tuition increases and delaying a bit the demise of die current medieval way we do business. Belated to all that, the U.S. Department of Education can probably tell you how many anthropology professors of Hispanic origin there are in South Dakota, but cannot tell you what the average teaching load of American professors is. But I am pretty sure it is minimally 25 percent less than it was when I began fulltime teaching in tire year the Higher Education Act passed, 1965. Doing less (teaching) with more describes modern higher education. Pseudo-Science and Ideology Modern economics may be less ideologically driven dian, say, sociology, but the notion that economists are scientists who objectively observe phenomenon and derive conclusions solely on the basis of empirical evidence is largely a myth, despite pretenses to the contrary. Nobel Prize winners like Paul Krugman and Joseph Stiglitz sometimes morph into almost pure ideologues, doing little or no truly serious work after receiving superstar academic recognition. And, as is oft-observed, the predominant ideological orientation is leftish, despite overwhelming evidence that many leftish policy prescriptions are failures or at least highly inefficient. Leftish intellectuals helped created the European welfare state that has been accompanied by declining growth rates for six decades, from around 5 percent annually in the 1950s to under 2 percent today. Yet, only a minority of economists uses this overwhelming evidence to suggest the nonmarket statist solutions of the welfare state are highly flawed. Why is this? I think a big reason for this is that modern academic economics is funded predominantly by the state, even at so-called private schools like Harvard. …","PeriodicalId":38832,"journal":{"name":"Cato Journal","volume":"56 1","pages":"7-15"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2016-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"2","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Reflections on the Current State of Political Economy\",\"authors\":\"R. Vedder\",\"doi\":\"10.1163/2210-7975_hrd-0164-2016003\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"Like most economics professors, I have spent my academic lifetime examining the economic and public policy effects of issues involving the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services--political economy, if you will. There is, however, a \\\"political economy\\\" to die very act of producing and disseminating economic knowledge and examining public policies. And that political economy and my assessment of it has changed over a career spanning more than half a century. In this brief article, I will confine my attention mostly to the research dimension and look at five issues, most relating to the political economy of the study of political economy. Diminishing Returns to Research I have long been bemused by economists who profess to understand the principle of scarcity and the importance of opportunity costs, yet write so much trivia of little interest to anyone. They do so because of the nonmarket nature of most academic endeavors and the utter lack of incentives to be efficient. The fifteenth paper on a topic is not very likely to add as much to our stock of knowledge as the first or second. I think the nation as a whole has probably overinvested in higher education because of vast governmental subsidies (an argument best made by retired professors like me whose potential acquisition of economic rents by extolling higher education is minimal). That manifests itself in such phenomena as the overeducated Starbucks barista or in the more than 115,000 janitors with bachelor s degrees. It also means roughly 1,000 academic papers are being written on William Shakespeare annually--three per day (Bauerlein 2009: 6). Who reads them? How much does a typical paper add at the margin to the insights that Shakespeare gave us 400 years ago? The problem extends to the inputs as the well as the outputs of higher education, and too many professors are writing too many words (and equations) that, to borrow from the Bard (Shakespeare to college graduates after 1990), \\\"signify nothing.\\\" What if professors wrote only one-third or one-half the number of papers they currently write, but taught one more class per year? My guess is that the net effects would be at least mildly positive, maybe even leading to smaller tuition increases and delaying a bit the demise of die current medieval way we do business. Belated to all that, the U.S. Department of Education can probably tell you how many anthropology professors of Hispanic origin there are in South Dakota, but cannot tell you what the average teaching load of American professors is. But I am pretty sure it is minimally 25 percent less than it was when I began fulltime teaching in tire year the Higher Education Act passed, 1965. Doing less (teaching) with more describes modern higher education. Pseudo-Science and Ideology Modern economics may be less ideologically driven dian, say, sociology, but the notion that economists are scientists who objectively observe phenomenon and derive conclusions solely on the basis of empirical evidence is largely a myth, despite pretenses to the contrary. Nobel Prize winners like Paul Krugman and Joseph Stiglitz sometimes morph into almost pure ideologues, doing little or no truly serious work after receiving superstar academic recognition. And, as is oft-observed, the predominant ideological orientation is leftish, despite overwhelming evidence that many leftish policy prescriptions are failures or at least highly inefficient. Leftish intellectuals helped created the European welfare state that has been accompanied by declining growth rates for six decades, from around 5 percent annually in the 1950s to under 2 percent today. Yet, only a minority of economists uses this overwhelming evidence to suggest the nonmarket statist solutions of the welfare state are highly flawed. Why is this? I think a big reason for this is that modern academic economics is funded predominantly by the state, even at so-called private schools like Harvard. …\",\"PeriodicalId\":38832,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Cato Journal\",\"volume\":\"56 1\",\"pages\":\"7-15\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2016-01-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"2\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Cato Journal\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1163/2210-7975_hrd-0164-2016003\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q3\",\"JCRName\":\"Economics, Econometrics and Finance\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Cato Journal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1163/2210-7975_hrd-0164-2016003","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"Economics, Econometrics and Finance","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2

摘要

像大多数经济学教授一样,我的学术生涯都在研究涉及商品和服务的生产、分配和消费的问题对经济和公共政策的影响——如果你愿意,可以称之为政治经济学。然而,在生产和传播经济知识以及审查公共政策的过程中,存在一种“政治经济学”。在半个多世纪的职业生涯中,这种政治经济学和我对它的评估发生了变化。在这篇简短的文章中,我将把我的注意力主要集中在研究维度上,并关注五个问题,这些问题与政治经济学研究中的政治经济学最相关。长期以来,我一直对一些经济学家感到困惑,他们自称理解稀缺性原理和机会成本的重要性,但却写了那么多没人感兴趣的琐事。他们之所以这样做,是因为大多数学术努力的非市场性质,以及完全缺乏提高效率的激励。关于一个主题的第十五篇论文不太可能像第一篇或第二篇那样增加我们的知识储备。我认为,由于政府的巨额补贴,整个国家在高等教育方面的投资可能已经过度了(这个论点最好由像我这样的退休教授提出,他们通过赞美高等教育获得经济租金的可能性很小)。这体现在诸如教育程度过高的星巴克咖啡师或超过11.5万名拥有学士学位的门卫等现象上。这也意味着每年大约有1000篇关于威廉·莎士比亚的学术论文——每天三篇(Bauerlein 2009: 6)。一篇典型的论文在空白处为400年前莎士比亚带给我们的真知灼见增添了多少?这个问题不仅延伸到高等教育的投入,也延伸到产出,太多的教授写了太多的话(和公式),借用诗人(莎士比亚对1990年后大学毕业生的称谓)的话来说,这些话“毫无意义”。如果教授们每年只写三分之一或一半的论文,却多教一节课,会怎么样?我的猜测是,净影响至少是温和的积极影响,甚至可能导致学费的小幅上涨,并稍微推迟我们目前中世纪做生意方式的消亡。迟来的是,美国教育部也许能告诉你南达科他州有多少西班牙裔人类学教授,但无法告诉你美国教授的平均教学负荷是多少。但我很确定,比起1965年《高等教育法》通过那年我开始全职教学的时候,我的收入至少减少了25%。现代高等教育就是“少教多教”。现代经济学可能不像社会学那样受意识形态的驱动,但经济学家是客观观察现象并完全根据经验证据得出结论的科学家的概念在很大程度上是一个神话,尽管有相反的伪装。像保罗·克鲁格曼(Paul Krugman)和约瑟夫·斯蒂格利茨(Joseph Stiglitz)这样的诺贝尔奖得主有时会变成几乎纯粹的空谈家,在获得超级巨星的学术认可后,很少或根本不做真正严肃的工作。而且,正如人们经常观察到的那样,主流的意识形态取向是左倾的,尽管有大量证据表明,许多左倾的政策处方是失败的,或者至少是效率极低的。左翼知识分子帮助建立了欧洲的福利国家。60年来,欧洲的经济增长率一直在下降,从上世纪50年代的每年5%左右下降到今天的不到2%。然而,只有少数经济学家利用这一压倒性的证据表明,福利国家的非市场统计主义解决方案存在严重缺陷。为什么会这样?我认为造成这种情况的一个重要原因是,现代学术经济学主要是由国家资助的,即使在哈佛这样的所谓私立学校也是如此。...
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Reflections on the Current State of Political Economy
Like most economics professors, I have spent my academic lifetime examining the economic and public policy effects of issues involving the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services--political economy, if you will. There is, however, a "political economy" to die very act of producing and disseminating economic knowledge and examining public policies. And that political economy and my assessment of it has changed over a career spanning more than half a century. In this brief article, I will confine my attention mostly to the research dimension and look at five issues, most relating to the political economy of the study of political economy. Diminishing Returns to Research I have long been bemused by economists who profess to understand the principle of scarcity and the importance of opportunity costs, yet write so much trivia of little interest to anyone. They do so because of the nonmarket nature of most academic endeavors and the utter lack of incentives to be efficient. The fifteenth paper on a topic is not very likely to add as much to our stock of knowledge as the first or second. I think the nation as a whole has probably overinvested in higher education because of vast governmental subsidies (an argument best made by retired professors like me whose potential acquisition of economic rents by extolling higher education is minimal). That manifests itself in such phenomena as the overeducated Starbucks barista or in the more than 115,000 janitors with bachelor s degrees. It also means roughly 1,000 academic papers are being written on William Shakespeare annually--three per day (Bauerlein 2009: 6). Who reads them? How much does a typical paper add at the margin to the insights that Shakespeare gave us 400 years ago? The problem extends to the inputs as the well as the outputs of higher education, and too many professors are writing too many words (and equations) that, to borrow from the Bard (Shakespeare to college graduates after 1990), "signify nothing." What if professors wrote only one-third or one-half the number of papers they currently write, but taught one more class per year? My guess is that the net effects would be at least mildly positive, maybe even leading to smaller tuition increases and delaying a bit the demise of die current medieval way we do business. Belated to all that, the U.S. Department of Education can probably tell you how many anthropology professors of Hispanic origin there are in South Dakota, but cannot tell you what the average teaching load of American professors is. But I am pretty sure it is minimally 25 percent less than it was when I began fulltime teaching in tire year the Higher Education Act passed, 1965. Doing less (teaching) with more describes modern higher education. Pseudo-Science and Ideology Modern economics may be less ideologically driven dian, say, sociology, but the notion that economists are scientists who objectively observe phenomenon and derive conclusions solely on the basis of empirical evidence is largely a myth, despite pretenses to the contrary. Nobel Prize winners like Paul Krugman and Joseph Stiglitz sometimes morph into almost pure ideologues, doing little or no truly serious work after receiving superstar academic recognition. And, as is oft-observed, the predominant ideological orientation is leftish, despite overwhelming evidence that many leftish policy prescriptions are failures or at least highly inefficient. Leftish intellectuals helped created the European welfare state that has been accompanied by declining growth rates for six decades, from around 5 percent annually in the 1950s to under 2 percent today. Yet, only a minority of economists uses this overwhelming evidence to suggest the nonmarket statist solutions of the welfare state are highly flawed. Why is this? I think a big reason for this is that modern academic economics is funded predominantly by the state, even at so-called private schools like Harvard. …
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
Cato Journal
Cato Journal Economics, Econometrics and Finance-Economics, Econometrics and Finance (miscellaneous)
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信