{"title":"合格的法律合规委员会:运用律师行为规则重组董事会","authors":"Jill E. Fisch, C. M. Gentile","doi":"10.2139/SSRN.471302","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"With the adoption of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Congress vested the Securities and Exchange Commission with the authority to promulgate professional standards of conduct for attorneys. The Commission, however, went beyond requiring that attorneys report corporate misconduct \"up the ladder\" by introducing a new corporate governance structure - the qualified legal compliance committee or QLCC. The QLCC reduces the statutory emphasis on lawyers as gatekeepers in favor of increasing the focus on board structure and director independence. Although increasing reliance on the board of directors rather than outside gatekeepers to prevent and address corporate misconduct may well be desirable, several components of QLCCs are problematic. The Commission appears to have given little consideration to the potential costs of establishing QLCCs. At the same time, the potential benefits of QLCCs may be overstated. These facts are particularly troubling, because the Commission's rules provide incentives for attorneys to pressure issuers to create QLCCs as a means of reducing the attorney's own liability. Accordingly, issuer decisions to create QLCCs could be influenced more by the market for legal services than the benefits and costs of QLCCs themselves. Finally, the Commission's conception of the ideal corporate governance model is open to question. QLCCs are part of a continuing effort to reduce corporate misconduct by enhancing the monitoring role of the board of directors through a rule-based approach to board structure and director independence. As recent governance scandals demonstrate, this approach is unlikely to produce radical changes in the effectiveness of directors, primarily because rules specifying board structure and director independence do not create adequate incentives for directors to take a more active role in monitoring corporate management. We conclude by considering ways to address the incentives of directors, including increased director liability, changes to director compensation, and alternative mechanisms for director selection. Although each of these methods is imperfect, collectively they illustrate the limitations of the Commission's approach, which emphasizes board structure without adequately addressing director passivity. The range of options available to improve director incentives and accountability highlights the shortcomings of the Commission's current rulemaking efforts.","PeriodicalId":47625,"journal":{"name":"Duke Law Journal","volume":"53 1","pages":"517-584"},"PeriodicalIF":1.8000,"publicationDate":"2003-11-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"9","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"The Qualified Legal Compliance Committee: Using the Attorney Conduct Rules to Restructure the Board of Directors\",\"authors\":\"Jill E. Fisch, C. M. Gentile\",\"doi\":\"10.2139/SSRN.471302\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"With the adoption of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Congress vested the Securities and Exchange Commission with the authority to promulgate professional standards of conduct for attorneys. The Commission, however, went beyond requiring that attorneys report corporate misconduct \\\"up the ladder\\\" by introducing a new corporate governance structure - the qualified legal compliance committee or QLCC. The QLCC reduces the statutory emphasis on lawyers as gatekeepers in favor of increasing the focus on board structure and director independence. Although increasing reliance on the board of directors rather than outside gatekeepers to prevent and address corporate misconduct may well be desirable, several components of QLCCs are problematic. The Commission appears to have given little consideration to the potential costs of establishing QLCCs. At the same time, the potential benefits of QLCCs may be overstated. These facts are particularly troubling, because the Commission's rules provide incentives for attorneys to pressure issuers to create QLCCs as a means of reducing the attorney's own liability. Accordingly, issuer decisions to create QLCCs could be influenced more by the market for legal services than the benefits and costs of QLCCs themselves. Finally, the Commission's conception of the ideal corporate governance model is open to question. QLCCs are part of a continuing effort to reduce corporate misconduct by enhancing the monitoring role of the board of directors through a rule-based approach to board structure and director independence. As recent governance scandals demonstrate, this approach is unlikely to produce radical changes in the effectiveness of directors, primarily because rules specifying board structure and director independence do not create adequate incentives for directors to take a more active role in monitoring corporate management. We conclude by considering ways to address the incentives of directors, including increased director liability, changes to director compensation, and alternative mechanisms for director selection. Although each of these methods is imperfect, collectively they illustrate the limitations of the Commission's approach, which emphasizes board structure without adequately addressing director passivity. The range of options available to improve director incentives and accountability highlights the shortcomings of the Commission's current rulemaking efforts.\",\"PeriodicalId\":47625,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Duke Law Journal\",\"volume\":\"53 1\",\"pages\":\"517-584\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":1.8000,\"publicationDate\":\"2003-11-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"9\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Duke Law Journal\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"90\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.471302\",\"RegionNum\":2,\"RegionCategory\":\"社会学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q1\",\"JCRName\":\"LAW\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Duke Law Journal","FirstCategoryId":"90","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/SSRN.471302","RegionNum":2,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"LAW","Score":null,"Total":0}
The Qualified Legal Compliance Committee: Using the Attorney Conduct Rules to Restructure the Board of Directors
With the adoption of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, Congress vested the Securities and Exchange Commission with the authority to promulgate professional standards of conduct for attorneys. The Commission, however, went beyond requiring that attorneys report corporate misconduct "up the ladder" by introducing a new corporate governance structure - the qualified legal compliance committee or QLCC. The QLCC reduces the statutory emphasis on lawyers as gatekeepers in favor of increasing the focus on board structure and director independence. Although increasing reliance on the board of directors rather than outside gatekeepers to prevent and address corporate misconduct may well be desirable, several components of QLCCs are problematic. The Commission appears to have given little consideration to the potential costs of establishing QLCCs. At the same time, the potential benefits of QLCCs may be overstated. These facts are particularly troubling, because the Commission's rules provide incentives for attorneys to pressure issuers to create QLCCs as a means of reducing the attorney's own liability. Accordingly, issuer decisions to create QLCCs could be influenced more by the market for legal services than the benefits and costs of QLCCs themselves. Finally, the Commission's conception of the ideal corporate governance model is open to question. QLCCs are part of a continuing effort to reduce corporate misconduct by enhancing the monitoring role of the board of directors through a rule-based approach to board structure and director independence. As recent governance scandals demonstrate, this approach is unlikely to produce radical changes in the effectiveness of directors, primarily because rules specifying board structure and director independence do not create adequate incentives for directors to take a more active role in monitoring corporate management. We conclude by considering ways to address the incentives of directors, including increased director liability, changes to director compensation, and alternative mechanisms for director selection. Although each of these methods is imperfect, collectively they illustrate the limitations of the Commission's approach, which emphasizes board structure without adequately addressing director passivity. The range of options available to improve director incentives and accountability highlights the shortcomings of the Commission's current rulemaking efforts.
期刊介绍:
The first issue of what was to become the Duke Law Journal was published in March 1951 as the Duke Bar Journal. Created to provide a medium for student expression, the Duke Bar Journal consisted entirely of student-written and student-edited work until 1953, when it began publishing faculty contributions. To reflect the inclusion of faculty scholarship, the Duke Bar Journal became the Duke Law Journal in 1957. In 1969, the Journal published its inaugural Administrative Law Symposium issue, a tradition that continues today. Volume 1 of the Duke Bar Journal spanned two issues and 259 pages. In 1959, the Journal grew to four issues and 649 pages, growing again in 1970 to six issues and 1263 pages. Today, the Duke Law Journal publishes eight issues per volume. Our staff is committed to the purpose set forth in our constitution: to publish legal writing of superior quality. We seek to publish a collection of outstanding scholarship from established legal writers, up-and-coming authors, and our own student editors.