所有权投资与出口政策的集中决策策略

IF 2.2 3区 经济学 Q2 ECONOMICS
Ku-Chu Tsao, Yan-Shu Lin, Yen-Ju Lin
{"title":"所有权投资与出口政策的集中决策策略","authors":"Ku-Chu Tsao, Yan-Shu Lin, Yen-Ju Lin","doi":"10.1080/09638199.2023.2271083","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"AbstractThis research explores the optimal export policy of a domestic industry characterized by numerous multinational enterprises (MNEs) co-existing with cross-border ownership investments in foreign firms and exports to a foreign country. We demonstrate that the optimal export policy depends on whether MNEs make centralized or decentralized decisions in ownership investments. With decentralized decision-making, the optimal export policy can be either a subsidy or a tax, while with centralized decision-making, it is a tax. Furthermore, we examine how the optimal trade policy responds to the optimal strategy of centralized decision-making by MNEs. Our results show that under certain circumstances, the optimal trade policy is an export subsidy, and MNEs prefer to voluntarily relinquish centralized decision-making, even when they have the option to control the production levels of foreign partner firms.KEYWORDS: Centralized decisiondecentralized decisioncross-border ownershipstrategic trade policyJEL classifications: F12F13F23 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).FundingWe are grateful to seminar participants at NTU TradeWorkshop for their valuable comments, leading to substantial improvements of this paper. The usual disclaimer applies.Notes1 Please see the website for the more details: https://asia.nikkei.com/NAR/Articles/China-s-Geely-Group-Acquires-9.7-Stake-In-Daimler-Via-Open-Market-Purchases.2 Farrell and Shapiro (Citation1990) analyze horizontal mergers in a Cournot oligopoly, Gilo, Moshe, and Spiegel (Citation2006) spotlight the importance of asymmetric costs, Ishikawa, Sugita, and Zhao (Citation2009) take technology transfer into account, and Cho, Kim, and Lee (Citation2022) consider a free licensing strategy with passive ownership and investigate the interaction with an ex-post privatization policy.3 Please refer to Kawabata (Citation2010), Ghosh and Saha (Citation2015), Fanti and Buccella (Citation2016), Choi, Lee, and Lim (Citation2017), Tsao et al. (Citation2019), etc.4 There are several papers that employ a similar definition of financial interest, referring to the right to receive the stream of profits generated by the firm from its operations and investments, such as Das (Citation1997), Wang and Wang (Citation2011), and Cho, Kim, and Lee (Citation2022).5 Spencer and Jones (Citation1991; Citation1992) look at trade policies in a vertically-related market from the viewpoint of importing and exporting countries, respectively, noting that the policy implication may not be the same.6 If the two goods are homogeneous, then a domestic MNE will stop either exports or CBO investment.7 We have xh∗=−(1−r)(m+n)−(1−rk)−s(m+n+1)−n[(2−r2k)+(m+n)(1−r2)]−(m+1)>0 and yh∗=yf∗=rn(1+s)−(n+1)−n[(2−r2k)+(m+n)(1−r2)]−(m+1),where yh∗>0 if r≤r¯≡n+1n(1+s) for any s.8 The first two terms of the foreign ownership effect in (6) also imply the cannibalization between the good produced by an MNE and the good produced by its partner firm. However, such internal cannibalization is fuelled by shareholding. Therefore, we define these two terms as the components of the foreign ownership effect.9 We define ds/dk=G(r,k,m,n). We have G = 0 when r = 0 or r = 1 for any (k, n, m). Since (dG/dr)|r = 0 > 0 and (dG/dr)|r = 1 < 0 for any n and m, this shows that G is always positive when r ∈ [0,1). Therefore, we have ds∗/dk > 0.10 We are very grateful to a reviewer for raising this point.11 For more details, please refer to the on-line appendix.","PeriodicalId":51656,"journal":{"name":"Journal of International Trade & Economic Development","volume":"46 12","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2000,"publicationDate":"2023-10-27","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Centralized decision strategy in ownership investments and export policy\",\"authors\":\"Ku-Chu Tsao, Yan-Shu Lin, Yen-Ju Lin\",\"doi\":\"10.1080/09638199.2023.2271083\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"AbstractThis research explores the optimal export policy of a domestic industry characterized by numerous multinational enterprises (MNEs) co-existing with cross-border ownership investments in foreign firms and exports to a foreign country. We demonstrate that the optimal export policy depends on whether MNEs make centralized or decentralized decisions in ownership investments. With decentralized decision-making, the optimal export policy can be either a subsidy or a tax, while with centralized decision-making, it is a tax. Furthermore, we examine how the optimal trade policy responds to the optimal strategy of centralized decision-making by MNEs. Our results show that under certain circumstances, the optimal trade policy is an export subsidy, and MNEs prefer to voluntarily relinquish centralized decision-making, even when they have the option to control the production levels of foreign partner firms.KEYWORDS: Centralized decisiondecentralized decisioncross-border ownershipstrategic trade policyJEL classifications: F12F13F23 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).FundingWe are grateful to seminar participants at NTU TradeWorkshop for their valuable comments, leading to substantial improvements of this paper. The usual disclaimer applies.Notes1 Please see the website for the more details: https://asia.nikkei.com/NAR/Articles/China-s-Geely-Group-Acquires-9.7-Stake-In-Daimler-Via-Open-Market-Purchases.2 Farrell and Shapiro (Citation1990) analyze horizontal mergers in a Cournot oligopoly, Gilo, Moshe, and Spiegel (Citation2006) spotlight the importance of asymmetric costs, Ishikawa, Sugita, and Zhao (Citation2009) take technology transfer into account, and Cho, Kim, and Lee (Citation2022) consider a free licensing strategy with passive ownership and investigate the interaction with an ex-post privatization policy.3 Please refer to Kawabata (Citation2010), Ghosh and Saha (Citation2015), Fanti and Buccella (Citation2016), Choi, Lee, and Lim (Citation2017), Tsao et al. (Citation2019), etc.4 There are several papers that employ a similar definition of financial interest, referring to the right to receive the stream of profits generated by the firm from its operations and investments, such as Das (Citation1997), Wang and Wang (Citation2011), and Cho, Kim, and Lee (Citation2022).5 Spencer and Jones (Citation1991; Citation1992) look at trade policies in a vertically-related market from the viewpoint of importing and exporting countries, respectively, noting that the policy implication may not be the same.6 If the two goods are homogeneous, then a domestic MNE will stop either exports or CBO investment.7 We have xh∗=−(1−r)(m+n)−(1−rk)−s(m+n+1)−n[(2−r2k)+(m+n)(1−r2)]−(m+1)>0 and yh∗=yf∗=rn(1+s)−(n+1)−n[(2−r2k)+(m+n)(1−r2)]−(m+1),where yh∗>0 if r≤r¯≡n+1n(1+s) for any s.8 The first two terms of the foreign ownership effect in (6) also imply the cannibalization between the good produced by an MNE and the good produced by its partner firm. However, such internal cannibalization is fuelled by shareholding. Therefore, we define these two terms as the components of the foreign ownership effect.9 We define ds/dk=G(r,k,m,n). We have G = 0 when r = 0 or r = 1 for any (k, n, m). Since (dG/dr)|r = 0 > 0 and (dG/dr)|r = 1 < 0 for any n and m, this shows that G is always positive when r ∈ [0,1). Therefore, we have ds∗/dk > 0.10 We are very grateful to a reviewer for raising this point.11 For more details, please refer to the on-line appendix.\",\"PeriodicalId\":51656,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Journal of International Trade & Economic Development\",\"volume\":\"46 12\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":2.2000,\"publicationDate\":\"2023-10-27\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Journal of International Trade & Economic Development\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2023.2271083\",\"RegionNum\":3,\"RegionCategory\":\"经济学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q2\",\"JCRName\":\"ECONOMICS\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of International Trade & Economic Development","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2023.2271083","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

摘要本研究探讨了以众多跨国企业(MNEs)共存为特征的国内产业的最优出口政策,这些跨国企业在外国公司进行跨境所有权投资并向外国出口。我们证明了最优的出口政策取决于跨国公司在所有权投资方面是采取集中决策还是分散决策。在分权决策下,最优出口政策可以是补贴或税收,而在集中决策下,最优出口政策是税收。此外,我们考察了最优贸易政策如何响应跨国公司集中决策的最优策略。研究结果表明,在特定情况下,最优贸易政策是出口补贴,即使跨国公司可以选择控制外国合作伙伴公司的生产水平,它们也更愿意自愿放弃集中决策。关键词:集中式决策、分散式决策、跨境所有权、战略性贸易政策jel分类:F12F13F23披露声明作者未报告潜在利益冲突。我们非常感谢南洋理工大学贸易研讨会的与会者提供的宝贵意见,使本文得到了实质性的改进。通常的免责声明适用。注1详情请浏览网站:https://asia.nikkei.com/NAR/Articles/China-s-Geely-Group-Acquires-9.7-Stake-In-Daimler-Via-Open-Market-Purchases.2 Farrell和Shapiro (Citation1990)分析了古诺寡头垄断中的横向合并,Gilo, Moshe和Spiegel (Citation2006)强调了不对称成本的重要性,Ishikawa, Sugita和Zhao (Citation2009)考虑了技术转移,Cho, Kim,和Lee (Citation2022)考虑了被动所有权的免费许可策略,并调查了与前后私有化政策的相互作用请参阅川端康成(Citation2010), Ghosh和萨哈(Citation2015),范蒂和Buccella (Citation2016),崔Lee和Lim (Citation2017),陶et al。(Citation2019) etc.4有几个论文采用类似的经济利益的定义,指的是对获得的利润产生的运作和投资的公司,如Das (Citation1997)、王、王(Citation2011),和赵,金姆,李(Citation2022)。5斯宾塞和琼斯(Citation1991;引文(1992)分别从进口国和出口国的角度考察垂直相关市场的贸易政策,并指出政策含义可能不一样如果两种商品是同质的,那么国内跨国公司将停止出口或CBO投资我们有xh∗=−(1−r) (m + n)−1−rk) (m + n + 1)−−s n[(2−r2k) + (m + n)(1−r2)]−(m + 1) > 0和yh∗rn = yf∗= (1 + s)−−(n + 1) n[(2−r2k) + (m + n)(1−r2)]−(m + 1),在yh∗如果≤r > 0¯≡n + 1 n s.8 (1 + s)(6)中外资所有权效应的前两个术语也意味着跨国公司生产的产品与其合作伙伴公司生产的产品之间的相互蚕食。然而,这种内部自相残杀是由持股推动的。因此,我们将这两个术语定义为外资所有权效应的组成部分定义ds/dk=G(r,k,m,n)对于任意(k, n, m),当r = 0或r = 1时,我们有G = 0。由于(dG/dr)|r = 0 > 0, (dG/dr)|r = 1 < 0,对于任意n和m,这表明当r∈[0,1]时,G总是正的。因此,我们有ds * /dk > 0.10。我们非常感谢审稿人提出这一点有关详情,请参阅网上附录。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Centralized decision strategy in ownership investments and export policy
AbstractThis research explores the optimal export policy of a domestic industry characterized by numerous multinational enterprises (MNEs) co-existing with cross-border ownership investments in foreign firms and exports to a foreign country. We demonstrate that the optimal export policy depends on whether MNEs make centralized or decentralized decisions in ownership investments. With decentralized decision-making, the optimal export policy can be either a subsidy or a tax, while with centralized decision-making, it is a tax. Furthermore, we examine how the optimal trade policy responds to the optimal strategy of centralized decision-making by MNEs. Our results show that under certain circumstances, the optimal trade policy is an export subsidy, and MNEs prefer to voluntarily relinquish centralized decision-making, even when they have the option to control the production levels of foreign partner firms.KEYWORDS: Centralized decisiondecentralized decisioncross-border ownershipstrategic trade policyJEL classifications: F12F13F23 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).FundingWe are grateful to seminar participants at NTU TradeWorkshop for their valuable comments, leading to substantial improvements of this paper. The usual disclaimer applies.Notes1 Please see the website for the more details: https://asia.nikkei.com/NAR/Articles/China-s-Geely-Group-Acquires-9.7-Stake-In-Daimler-Via-Open-Market-Purchases.2 Farrell and Shapiro (Citation1990) analyze horizontal mergers in a Cournot oligopoly, Gilo, Moshe, and Spiegel (Citation2006) spotlight the importance of asymmetric costs, Ishikawa, Sugita, and Zhao (Citation2009) take technology transfer into account, and Cho, Kim, and Lee (Citation2022) consider a free licensing strategy with passive ownership and investigate the interaction with an ex-post privatization policy.3 Please refer to Kawabata (Citation2010), Ghosh and Saha (Citation2015), Fanti and Buccella (Citation2016), Choi, Lee, and Lim (Citation2017), Tsao et al. (Citation2019), etc.4 There are several papers that employ a similar definition of financial interest, referring to the right to receive the stream of profits generated by the firm from its operations and investments, such as Das (Citation1997), Wang and Wang (Citation2011), and Cho, Kim, and Lee (Citation2022).5 Spencer and Jones (Citation1991; Citation1992) look at trade policies in a vertically-related market from the viewpoint of importing and exporting countries, respectively, noting that the policy implication may not be the same.6 If the two goods are homogeneous, then a domestic MNE will stop either exports or CBO investment.7 We have xh∗=−(1−r)(m+n)−(1−rk)−s(m+n+1)−n[(2−r2k)+(m+n)(1−r2)]−(m+1)>0 and yh∗=yf∗=rn(1+s)−(n+1)−n[(2−r2k)+(m+n)(1−r2)]−(m+1),where yh∗>0 if r≤r¯≡n+1n(1+s) for any s.8 The first two terms of the foreign ownership effect in (6) also imply the cannibalization between the good produced by an MNE and the good produced by its partner firm. However, such internal cannibalization is fuelled by shareholding. Therefore, we define these two terms as the components of the foreign ownership effect.9 We define ds/dk=G(r,k,m,n). We have G = 0 when r = 0 or r = 1 for any (k, n, m). Since (dG/dr)|r = 0 > 0 and (dG/dr)|r = 1 < 0 for any n and m, this shows that G is always positive when r ∈ [0,1). Therefore, we have ds∗/dk > 0.10 We are very grateful to a reviewer for raising this point.11 For more details, please refer to the on-line appendix.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
4.00
自引率
19.00%
发文量
66
期刊介绍: The Journal of International Trade and Economic Development ( JITED) focuses on international economics, economic development, and the interface between trade and development. The links between trade and development economics are critical at a time when fluctuating commodity prices, ongoing production fragmentation, and trade liberalisation can radically affect the economies of advanced and developing countries. Our aim is to keep in touch with the latest developments in research as well as setting the agenda for future analysis. Publication of high quality articles covering; theoretical and applied issues in international and development economics; econometric applications of trade and/or development issues based on sound theoretical economic models or testing fundamental economic hypotheses; models of structural change; trade and development issues of economies in Eastern Europe, Asia and the Pacific area; papers on specific topics which are policy-relevant; review articles on important branches of the literature including controversial and innovative ideas are also welcome. JITED is designed to meet the needs of international and development economists, economic historians, applied economists, and policy makers. The international experts who make up the journal’s Editorial Board encourage contributions from economists world-wide.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信