七国集团国家的总需求不确定性爆发和就业滞后

IF 0.6 3区 经济学 Q4 ECONOMICS
Paulo R. Mota
{"title":"七国集团国家的总需求不确定性爆发和就业滞后","authors":"Paulo R. Mota","doi":"10.1080/01603477.2023.2268090","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"AbstractThe slow recovery following the recent financial crisis in many developed countries, and the predictable long lasting economic effects of the Covid-19 pandemic have raised a new interest on the topic of employment hysteresis. In the presence of hysteresis there is no predetermined long-run equilibrium level of aggregate employment. As the economic system is not self-adjusting toward a unique equilibrium, timely, and sustained expansionary macroeconomic policies should be applied to mitigate the impact of negative shocks. The purpose of this paper is to uncover hysteresis effects in the macrodynamics of employment along with variations in its intensity that may result from outbreaks in aggregate demand uncertainty. We estimate a switching employment equation based on the play model of hysteresis, which describes a dynamic process whereby non-convex adjustment costs and uncertainty create intervals of weak reaction of employment to small changes in forcing variables, but spurts in the reaction to large demand shocks. As a novel feature, the estimation allows the presence of structural breaks in the value of the switching parameter of the employment equation due to aggregate demand uncertainty outbreaks. We have concluded that hysteresis effects increased in general in crisis periods associated to outbreaks of uncertainty in aggregate demand.Keywords: Employmenthysteresisuncertaintystructural breaksJEL CLASSIFICATION CODES: E24J23 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Local input extrema that are not followed by an absolute extrema (see, e.g., Cross et al. Citation2005).2 Therefore, hysteresis should not be confused with the presence of a unit root in a linear dynamic system, or zero root in continuous time difference equations (see Amable et al. Citation1993, Citation1994). The consequence is that non-stationary econometrics cannot be used to overcome the role of uncertainty and to make predictions about the future on the basis of past data. This issue has been put forward by Davidson (Citation1993) concerning the adequacy of the concept of hysteresis in the context of post Keynesian economics.3 For example, uncertainty about the course of technical progress, the future behavior of prices, the outcome of plan of investment, not to mention the effects of natural and political cataclysms with economic impact (Robinson Citation1974, 1).4 The possibility that the firms have to adjust labor input along the intensive margin, i.e., fluctuations in hours worked per employee, may also enhance the employment hysteresis effects (Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2012).5 The importance of the initial conditions and path dependence as drivers of the outcome of economic system was early recognized by Robinson (Citation1974).6 See also Rios, Rachinskii, and Cross (Citation2017).7 This is perfectly compatible with the concept of hysteresis. In fact “…hysteresis involves explicit structural change in the system that is determining long-run outcomes. Hence a hysteretic system may actively create its own set of final outcomes in the course of its evolution as a result of this structural change. With hysteresis, then, whilst definitive final outcomes – such as equilibria – are possible, it may only be within our powers to identify these outcomes ex post, after they have actually been established. They need not exist ex ante, independently of the actual history of adjustments in the system to which they pertain.” Setterfield (Citation1998, 294)8 See Benigno and Fornaro (Citation2018); Cerra, Saxena, and Panizza (Citation2013); Garga and Singh (Citation2021), Jordà, Singh, and Taylor (Citation2020); Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox (Citation2015), for recent evidence of permanent effects of monetary policy.9 As the wedge between private and public returns on investments in R&D increases typically during recessions, the State should subsidize particularly the investment in innovation (see Bianchi et al. Citation2019). Besides, monetary policy should be adequately expansionary to reduce the liquidity risk of long-term investments in innovation (see Aghion et al. Citation2012).10 A concept that was not familiar to Keynes.11 Keynes was part of a long tradition rejecting the view that the economic system is self-adjusting to a general equilibrium (see Kregel Citation2011, 271, for a survey of the literature).12 The switching parameter of the employment equation is interpreted as an ‘aggregate employment band on inaction,’ which summarizes the magnitude of the hysteretic effects (Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2015).13 Although originally applied in the physics of magnetics, the Preisach model should be viewed as a new mathematical idea that can be applied to describe a wide range of hysteretic phenomena in quite different areas, including aggregate employment dynamics (see, e.g., Amable et al. Citation1993, Citation1994; Cross Citation1994, Citation1997; Cross et al. Citation2005; Mayergoyz Citation2021.14 We assume that the exogenous component of aggregate demand, xt, determines the state of firm’s activity through its impact in the price level, which corresponds to the gross revenue under the assumptions of the model.15 Firm also incur in sunk costs for the acquisition of physical assets like firm specific equipment or intangible assets such as reputation, acquired by investments in marketing and advertising, or technical knowledge (see, e.g., Belke, Baudisch, and Göcke Citation2020; Dias and Shackleton Citation2011; Folta, Johnson, and O’Brien Citation2006; Pindyck Citation1988, Citation1991). Other non-firm specific investments like office equipment, cars, trucks and computers can have a resale value well below their purchase cost due to the ‘lemons’ problem (Pindyck Citation1991, 1111). Furthermore, to enter new markets, firms often have to incur irreversible costs, e.g., for gathering information on market revenues, creating distribution and servicing networks, and advertising or establishing a brand name (see, Adamonis and Göcke Citation2019).16 EquationEquation (1)(1) Rαj,βj(xt)={1, if Rαj,βj(xt−1)=0 and xt≥βj [entry in the market] orRαj,βj(xt−1)=1 and xt>αj [stay active in the market]0, if Rαj,βj(xt−1)=0 and xt<βj [stay inactive] or Rαj,βj(xt−1)=1 and xt≤αj [exit the market](1) is derived from a profit maximizing problem in discrete time with an infinite plan horizon, and a discount factor, δ=11+i, where i is the interest rate (see, e.g., Göcke Citation2002, 118, and Mota et al. Citation2012 for a complete description of the model).17 Within the assumptions of the model the trigger values for exit and entry are αj=wj−δFj and βj=wj+δHj respectively (see, e.g., Göcke Citation2002; Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2012).18 This stylized model can offer a good description of the employment dynamics if we consider a firm disaggregated into single production units, each of them represented by a non-ideal relay operator (see Belke and Göcke Citation1999; Cross Citation2014). Therefore, in this setting the decision to enter the market is similar to the hiring decision, and the decision to exit the market is analogous to the firing decision.19 This matches with the empirical observation of discontinuous and irregular adjustment of employment by firms, in which periods of inaction are punctuated by episodes of large adjustment (see e.g., Caballero, Engel, and Haltiwanger Citation1997; Hamermesh Citation1989; Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2012; Varejão and Portugal Citation2007).20 The heterogeneity in the way firms react to aggregate demand shocks arises from specific cost structures including non-convex adjustment costs (that may depend on firms’ age, size, ownership, average work skill level and innovation), and from the way firms deal with uncertainty (see, Gaëlle and Scarpetta Citation2006).21 See Cross et al. (Citation2005); Piscitelli et al. (Citation2000), for a more comprehensive description of the geometric description of the Preisach model of hysteresis.22 As we assume that firms are uniformly distributed in the Preisach triangle, the branches of the hysteresis loop are quadratic functions.23 At the firm level there are only two branches, and the transition between those branches only occurs when xt increases above βj or decreases below αj.24 This follows from the wiping-out property of the Preisach model (see, Mayergoyz Citation2003).25 For a complete description of the Preisach model of hysteresis see, e.g. Mayergoyz (Citation2003); Mota and Vasconcelos (Citation2012).26 See Cross et al. (Citation2010); Göcke and Werner (Citation2015); Piscitelli et al. (Citation1999) for theoretical models with feedback effects of the system on the equilibrium level of the hysteretic forcing variable.27 See also Amable et al (Citation1993, Citation1994).28 The linear play model of hysteresis (the term is used because of its analogy to play in mechanics) can be viewed as a piecewise-linear approximation of the Preisach hysteresis loop, where the slope of the linear functions change at extrema (see, Krasnosel’skii and Pokrovskii Citation1989; Visitin Citation1994).29 A general description of the model can be found in Visitin (Citation1994).30 This can be the result of an exogenous shock or endogenously caused by the decrease of demand. In fact, of a lack of aggregate demand and increasing unemployment can be viewed as the result of the malfunctioning of the economy and thus affects business confidence.31 The sequence xt1→xt2→xt3 originates as counter-clockwise oriented loop abcde.32 Although real wages could also be a source of hysteresis, our aim is to test the presence of hysteresis caused by aggregate demand shocks. Therefore, real wages enters as a non-hysteretic explanatory variable in the employment equation. For the joint influence of several inputs in an economic system with hysteresis see Göcke (Citation2019).33 We assume that the demand for employment results from consumers’ demand for final goods and services (that determines a scale effect), and the availability of employment that determines its price (input substitution effect). Therefore, we include in the employment equation the traditional explanatory variables (we follow Hamermesh, Citation1993, 30 and 64).34 See also Belke and Göcke (Citation2001a, Citation2001b); Göcke (Citation2001) for more detail.35 See Mota and Vasconcelos (Citation2021) for a detailed description of this new version of the play algorithm.36 Equation (4) is based on a piecewise linear relationship between Nt and xt where the play lines and the spurt lines are connected continuously by knots. In Figure 3 the knots are points a, b, c, d, e, and f when the input follows the sequence xt0→ xt1→xt2→xt3. The position of the knots are a priori unknown, because they depend on the width of the play interval, γ, which has to be estimated, and on the position of the play line that is determined by the past values of xt. Since the adjacent play and spurts lines are connected, the employment equation is a special case of a switching regression with an unknown splitting factor that in the context of the play model corresponds to the width γt (see Figure 3), and similar to a linear spline function (see Poirier Citation1973, Citation1976). In this case, the OLS estimator is asymptotically consistent and normal distributed under the standard regression model assumptions (see Hinkley Citation1969; Hudson Citation1966; Poirier Citation1976).37 Note that is this model there is a combination of structural changes of a non-temporal nature in the relationship between aggregate employment, Nt, and aggregate demand captured by xt that arises from reversals of xt, and from subsequently cumulated variations surpassing the play interval, and structural changes in the time domain due to changes in the play interval itself due to demand uncertainty outbreaks.38 For the variables in levels the augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic (with an intercept included in the test equation) is in general larger than the 1% critical value (−3.509), indicating that we do not reject the non-stationary of the series (Appendix 2). For the first difference of the series, we reject in general the hypothesis of the existence of a unit root (test statistic is smaller than the 1% critical value). We conclude that in general the variables are integrated of order one, I(1). The exceptions is xt that is stationary in levels for France, Germany and for the UK. Nt that is also stationary in levels for the UK. Nt for France and Wt for the United States are I(3).39 The Johansen Test Procedure was used for cointegration testing. Based on the trace test performed with four lags in the VAR representation, and with an intercept in the cointegrating employment EquationEquation (3)(3) Nt=β0+β1xt+β2St(γt)+β3Wt+εt(3) , have concluded that the variables in Equation (3) are cointegrated of rank one in the cases of Canada, Germany, and Italy; cointegrated of rank two in the cases of France, Japan, and USA; and cointegrated of rank four for the UK (the trace test statistic and the critical value for a 5% significance level for the rejection of the hypothesis of no cointegration is reported in Table 2).40 FM-OLS estimator modifies least squares with semiparametric corrections that account for serial correlation effects and for endogeneity in the regressors that result from the existence of cointegrating relationships (Phillips Citation1995; Phillips and Hansen Citation1990).41 For 1% significance level.42 The properties of the inference mentioned before are based on large sample theory and might not be accurate approximations in small size samples (See Hinkley Citation1969 ; Poirier Citation1976). In fact, the distribution of the estimator may converge slowly to normality. Nonetheless, the high value of the Wald test statistic (especially tat concerns the spurt variable) makes us confident of the significance of the estimates.Additional informationFundingThis research has been financed by Portuguese Public Funds through FCT (Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology) and by the European Regional Development Fund through COMPETE 2020 – Programa Operacional Competitividade e Internacionalização (POCI) – in the framework of the project POCI-01-0145-FEDER-006890.Notes on contributorsPaulo R. MotaPaulo R. Mota is at School of Economics and Business and CEF.UP, University of Porto.","PeriodicalId":47197,"journal":{"name":"Journal of Post Keynesian Economics","volume":"12 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.6000,"publicationDate":"2023-10-19","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Aggregate demand uncertainty outbreaks and employment hysteresis in G7 countries\",\"authors\":\"Paulo R. Mota\",\"doi\":\"10.1080/01603477.2023.2268090\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"AbstractThe slow recovery following the recent financial crisis in many developed countries, and the predictable long lasting economic effects of the Covid-19 pandemic have raised a new interest on the topic of employment hysteresis. In the presence of hysteresis there is no predetermined long-run equilibrium level of aggregate employment. As the economic system is not self-adjusting toward a unique equilibrium, timely, and sustained expansionary macroeconomic policies should be applied to mitigate the impact of negative shocks. The purpose of this paper is to uncover hysteresis effects in the macrodynamics of employment along with variations in its intensity that may result from outbreaks in aggregate demand uncertainty. We estimate a switching employment equation based on the play model of hysteresis, which describes a dynamic process whereby non-convex adjustment costs and uncertainty create intervals of weak reaction of employment to small changes in forcing variables, but spurts in the reaction to large demand shocks. As a novel feature, the estimation allows the presence of structural breaks in the value of the switching parameter of the employment equation due to aggregate demand uncertainty outbreaks. We have concluded that hysteresis effects increased in general in crisis periods associated to outbreaks of uncertainty in aggregate demand.Keywords: Employmenthysteresisuncertaintystructural breaksJEL CLASSIFICATION CODES: E24J23 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Local input extrema that are not followed by an absolute extrema (see, e.g., Cross et al. Citation2005).2 Therefore, hysteresis should not be confused with the presence of a unit root in a linear dynamic system, or zero root in continuous time difference equations (see Amable et al. Citation1993, Citation1994). The consequence is that non-stationary econometrics cannot be used to overcome the role of uncertainty and to make predictions about the future on the basis of past data. This issue has been put forward by Davidson (Citation1993) concerning the adequacy of the concept of hysteresis in the context of post Keynesian economics.3 For example, uncertainty about the course of technical progress, the future behavior of prices, the outcome of plan of investment, not to mention the effects of natural and political cataclysms with economic impact (Robinson Citation1974, 1).4 The possibility that the firms have to adjust labor input along the intensive margin, i.e., fluctuations in hours worked per employee, may also enhance the employment hysteresis effects (Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2012).5 The importance of the initial conditions and path dependence as drivers of the outcome of economic system was early recognized by Robinson (Citation1974).6 See also Rios, Rachinskii, and Cross (Citation2017).7 This is perfectly compatible with the concept of hysteresis. In fact “…hysteresis involves explicit structural change in the system that is determining long-run outcomes. Hence a hysteretic system may actively create its own set of final outcomes in the course of its evolution as a result of this structural change. With hysteresis, then, whilst definitive final outcomes – such as equilibria – are possible, it may only be within our powers to identify these outcomes ex post, after they have actually been established. They need not exist ex ante, independently of the actual history of adjustments in the system to which they pertain.” Setterfield (Citation1998, 294)8 See Benigno and Fornaro (Citation2018); Cerra, Saxena, and Panizza (Citation2013); Garga and Singh (Citation2021), Jordà, Singh, and Taylor (Citation2020); Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox (Citation2015), for recent evidence of permanent effects of monetary policy.9 As the wedge between private and public returns on investments in R&D increases typically during recessions, the State should subsidize particularly the investment in innovation (see Bianchi et al. Citation2019). Besides, monetary policy should be adequately expansionary to reduce the liquidity risk of long-term investments in innovation (see Aghion et al. Citation2012).10 A concept that was not familiar to Keynes.11 Keynes was part of a long tradition rejecting the view that the economic system is self-adjusting to a general equilibrium (see Kregel Citation2011, 271, for a survey of the literature).12 The switching parameter of the employment equation is interpreted as an ‘aggregate employment band on inaction,’ which summarizes the magnitude of the hysteretic effects (Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2015).13 Although originally applied in the physics of magnetics, the Preisach model should be viewed as a new mathematical idea that can be applied to describe a wide range of hysteretic phenomena in quite different areas, including aggregate employment dynamics (see, e.g., Amable et al. Citation1993, Citation1994; Cross Citation1994, Citation1997; Cross et al. Citation2005; Mayergoyz Citation2021.14 We assume that the exogenous component of aggregate demand, xt, determines the state of firm’s activity through its impact in the price level, which corresponds to the gross revenue under the assumptions of the model.15 Firm also incur in sunk costs for the acquisition of physical assets like firm specific equipment or intangible assets such as reputation, acquired by investments in marketing and advertising, or technical knowledge (see, e.g., Belke, Baudisch, and Göcke Citation2020; Dias and Shackleton Citation2011; Folta, Johnson, and O’Brien Citation2006; Pindyck Citation1988, Citation1991). Other non-firm specific investments like office equipment, cars, trucks and computers can have a resale value well below their purchase cost due to the ‘lemons’ problem (Pindyck Citation1991, 1111). Furthermore, to enter new markets, firms often have to incur irreversible costs, e.g., for gathering information on market revenues, creating distribution and servicing networks, and advertising or establishing a brand name (see, Adamonis and Göcke Citation2019).16 EquationEquation (1)(1) Rαj,βj(xt)={1, if Rαj,βj(xt−1)=0 and xt≥βj [entry in the market] orRαj,βj(xt−1)=1 and xt>αj [stay active in the market]0, if Rαj,βj(xt−1)=0 and xt<βj [stay inactive] or Rαj,βj(xt−1)=1 and xt≤αj [exit the market](1) is derived from a profit maximizing problem in discrete time with an infinite plan horizon, and a discount factor, δ=11+i, where i is the interest rate (see, e.g., Göcke Citation2002, 118, and Mota et al. Citation2012 for a complete description of the model).17 Within the assumptions of the model the trigger values for exit and entry are αj=wj−δFj and βj=wj+δHj respectively (see, e.g., Göcke Citation2002; Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2012).18 This stylized model can offer a good description of the employment dynamics if we consider a firm disaggregated into single production units, each of them represented by a non-ideal relay operator (see Belke and Göcke Citation1999; Cross Citation2014). Therefore, in this setting the decision to enter the market is similar to the hiring decision, and the decision to exit the market is analogous to the firing decision.19 This matches with the empirical observation of discontinuous and irregular adjustment of employment by firms, in which periods of inaction are punctuated by episodes of large adjustment (see e.g., Caballero, Engel, and Haltiwanger Citation1997; Hamermesh Citation1989; Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2012; Varejão and Portugal Citation2007).20 The heterogeneity in the way firms react to aggregate demand shocks arises from specific cost structures including non-convex adjustment costs (that may depend on firms’ age, size, ownership, average work skill level and innovation), and from the way firms deal with uncertainty (see, Gaëlle and Scarpetta Citation2006).21 See Cross et al. (Citation2005); Piscitelli et al. (Citation2000), for a more comprehensive description of the geometric description of the Preisach model of hysteresis.22 As we assume that firms are uniformly distributed in the Preisach triangle, the branches of the hysteresis loop are quadratic functions.23 At the firm level there are only two branches, and the transition between those branches only occurs when xt increases above βj or decreases below αj.24 This follows from the wiping-out property of the Preisach model (see, Mayergoyz Citation2003).25 For a complete description of the Preisach model of hysteresis see, e.g. Mayergoyz (Citation2003); Mota and Vasconcelos (Citation2012).26 See Cross et al. (Citation2010); Göcke and Werner (Citation2015); Piscitelli et al. (Citation1999) for theoretical models with feedback effects of the system on the equilibrium level of the hysteretic forcing variable.27 See also Amable et al (Citation1993, Citation1994).28 The linear play model of hysteresis (the term is used because of its analogy to play in mechanics) can be viewed as a piecewise-linear approximation of the Preisach hysteresis loop, where the slope of the linear functions change at extrema (see, Krasnosel’skii and Pokrovskii Citation1989; Visitin Citation1994).29 A general description of the model can be found in Visitin (Citation1994).30 This can be the result of an exogenous shock or endogenously caused by the decrease of demand. In fact, of a lack of aggregate demand and increasing unemployment can be viewed as the result of the malfunctioning of the economy and thus affects business confidence.31 The sequence xt1→xt2→xt3 originates as counter-clockwise oriented loop abcde.32 Although real wages could also be a source of hysteresis, our aim is to test the presence of hysteresis caused by aggregate demand shocks. Therefore, real wages enters as a non-hysteretic explanatory variable in the employment equation. For the joint influence of several inputs in an economic system with hysteresis see Göcke (Citation2019).33 We assume that the demand for employment results from consumers’ demand for final goods and services (that determines a scale effect), and the availability of employment that determines its price (input substitution effect). Therefore, we include in the employment equation the traditional explanatory variables (we follow Hamermesh, Citation1993, 30 and 64).34 See also Belke and Göcke (Citation2001a, Citation2001b); Göcke (Citation2001) for more detail.35 See Mota and Vasconcelos (Citation2021) for a detailed description of this new version of the play algorithm.36 Equation (4) is based on a piecewise linear relationship between Nt and xt where the play lines and the spurt lines are connected continuously by knots. In Figure 3 the knots are points a, b, c, d, e, and f when the input follows the sequence xt0→ xt1→xt2→xt3. The position of the knots are a priori unknown, because they depend on the width of the play interval, γ, which has to be estimated, and on the position of the play line that is determined by the past values of xt. Since the adjacent play and spurts lines are connected, the employment equation is a special case of a switching regression with an unknown splitting factor that in the context of the play model corresponds to the width γt (see Figure 3), and similar to a linear spline function (see Poirier Citation1973, Citation1976). In this case, the OLS estimator is asymptotically consistent and normal distributed under the standard regression model assumptions (see Hinkley Citation1969; Hudson Citation1966; Poirier Citation1976).37 Note that is this model there is a combination of structural changes of a non-temporal nature in the relationship between aggregate employment, Nt, and aggregate demand captured by xt that arises from reversals of xt, and from subsequently cumulated variations surpassing the play interval, and structural changes in the time domain due to changes in the play interval itself due to demand uncertainty outbreaks.38 For the variables in levels the augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic (with an intercept included in the test equation) is in general larger than the 1% critical value (−3.509), indicating that we do not reject the non-stationary of the series (Appendix 2). For the first difference of the series, we reject in general the hypothesis of the existence of a unit root (test statistic is smaller than the 1% critical value). We conclude that in general the variables are integrated of order one, I(1). The exceptions is xt that is stationary in levels for France, Germany and for the UK. Nt that is also stationary in levels for the UK. Nt for France and Wt for the United States are I(3).39 The Johansen Test Procedure was used for cointegration testing. Based on the trace test performed with four lags in the VAR representation, and with an intercept in the cointegrating employment EquationEquation (3)(3) Nt=β0+β1xt+β2St(γt)+β3Wt+εt(3) , have concluded that the variables in Equation (3) are cointegrated of rank one in the cases of Canada, Germany, and Italy; cointegrated of rank two in the cases of France, Japan, and USA; and cointegrated of rank four for the UK (the trace test statistic and the critical value for a 5% significance level for the rejection of the hypothesis of no cointegration is reported in Table 2).40 FM-OLS estimator modifies least squares with semiparametric corrections that account for serial correlation effects and for endogeneity in the regressors that result from the existence of cointegrating relationships (Phillips Citation1995; Phillips and Hansen Citation1990).41 For 1% significance level.42 The properties of the inference mentioned before are based on large sample theory and might not be accurate approximations in small size samples (See Hinkley Citation1969 ; Poirier Citation1976). In fact, the distribution of the estimator may converge slowly to normality. Nonetheless, the high value of the Wald test statistic (especially tat concerns the spurt variable) makes us confident of the significance of the estimates.Additional informationFundingThis research has been financed by Portuguese Public Funds through FCT (Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology) and by the European Regional Development Fund through COMPETE 2020 – Programa Operacional Competitividade e Internacionalização (POCI) – in the framework of the project POCI-01-0145-FEDER-006890.Notes on contributorsPaulo R. MotaPaulo R. Mota is at School of Economics and Business and CEF.UP, University of Porto.\",\"PeriodicalId\":47197,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Journal of Post Keynesian Economics\",\"volume\":\"12 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.6000,\"publicationDate\":\"2023-10-19\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Journal of Post Keynesian Economics\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1080/01603477.2023.2268090\",\"RegionNum\":3,\"RegionCategory\":\"经济学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q4\",\"JCRName\":\"ECONOMICS\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of Post Keynesian Economics","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/01603477.2023.2268090","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q4","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

Citation1993 Citation1994;Cross Citation1994, Citation1997;Cross等人。Citation2005;我们假设总需求的外生成分xt通过其对价格水平的影响来决定企业的活动状态,而价格水平对应于模型假设下的总收入企业还会因收购有形资产(如企业特定设备)或无形资产(如通过营销和广告投资获得的声誉)或技术知识(参见Belke、Baudisch和Göcke Citation2020)而产生沉没成本;Dias and Shackleton citation; 2011;Folta, Johnson, and O 'Brien Citation2006;Pindyck Citation1988, Citation1991)。由于“柠檬”问题(Pindyck citation1991,1111),其他非公司特定投资,如办公设备、汽车、卡车和计算机,其转售价值可能远低于其购买成本。此外,为了进入新市场,企业往往不得不承担不可逆转的成本,例如,收集市场收入信息、创建分销和服务网络、广告或建立品牌(见Adamonis和Göcke Citation2019)(1) Rαj,βj(xt−1)={1,如果Rαj,βj(xt−1)=0且xt≥βj[进入市场]或Rαj,βj(xt−1)=1且xt>αj[在市场中保持活跃]0,如果Rαj,βj(xt−1)=0且xt<βj[保持不活跃]或Rαj,βj(xt−1)=1且xt≤αj[退出市场](1),则推导出具有无限计划视界的离散时间利润最大化问题,贴现因子δ=11+i,其中i为利率(参见Göcke Citation2002, 118和Mota等)。17 .引用(citation) 2012,以获得该模型的完整描述在模型的假设范围内,出口和进入的触发值分别为αj=wj−δFj和βj=wj+δHj(参见,例如Göcke Citation2002;Mota, varej<e:1> o, and Vasconcelos引文2012).18如果我们考虑将一个公司分解为单个生产单位,每个生产单位由一个非理想的继电器操作员代表,那么这个程式化模型可以很好地描述就业动态(见Belke和Göcke Citation1999;交叉Citation2014)。因此,在这种情况下,进入市场的决定类似于雇佣的决定,而退出市场的决定类似于解雇的决定这与对企业就业的不连续和不规则调整的经验观察相吻合,在这种情况下,不作为的时期会被大规模调整的插曲所打断(参见例如,Caballero, Engel和Haltiwanger引文,1997;汉默麦希Citation1989;Mota, varej<e:1> o,和Vasconcelos引文2012;varej<e:1>和葡萄牙引文2007).20企业对总需求冲击的反应方式的异质性源于特定的成本结构,包括非凸调整成本(可能取决于企业的年龄、规模、所有权、平均工作技能水平和创新),以及企业应对不确定性的方式(见Gaëlle和Scarpetta Citation2006)参见Cross et al. (Citation2005);Piscitelli et al. (Citation2000),对Preisach迟滞模型的几何描述进行了更全面的描述由于我们假设公司均匀分布在Preisach三角形中,滞回回路的分支是二次函数在企业层面上只有两个分支,只有当xt在βj以上增加或在αj.24以下减少时才会发生分支间的过渡这源于Preisach模型的消去特性(见Mayergoyz Citation2003)关于Preisach滞回模型的完整描述,参见Mayergoyz (Citation2003);莫塔和瓦斯孔塞洛斯(citation) 2012 .26参见Cross et al. (Citation2010);Göcke和Werner (Citation2015);27 . Piscitelli et al. (Citation1999)关于系统在滞后强迫变量的平衡水平上具有反馈效应的理论模型另见Amable et al (Citation1993, Citation1994).28迟滞的线性游戏模型(使用该术语是因为它与力学中的游戏相似)可以被视为Preisach迟滞回路的分段线性近似,其中线性函数的斜率在极值处变化(参见Krasnosel’skii和Pokrovskii Citation1989;Visitin Citation1994) 29该模型的一般描述可在visittin (Citation1994)中找到这可能是外生冲击的结果,也可能是需求减少的内因。事实上,总需求的缺乏和失业的增加可以被看作是经济失灵的结果,从而影响到商业信心序列xt1→xt2→xt3起源于逆时针方向的abcde尽管实际工资也可能是滞后效应的一个来源,但我们的目的是检验总需求冲击造成的滞后效应是否存在。因此,实际工资作为一个非滞后的解释变量进入就业方程。 关于具有滞后的经济系统中几个输入的共同影响,参见Göcke (Citation2019)。33我们假设就业需求来源于消费者对最终产品和服务的需求(这决定了规模效应),而就业的可获得性决定了其价格(投入替代效应)。因此,我们在就业方程中加入了传统的解释变量(我们遵循Hamermesh, Citation1993, 30和64)参见Belke和Göcke (Citation2001a, Citation2001b);Göcke (Citation2001)获取更多详细信息参见Mota和Vasconcelos (Citation2021)对这个新版本游戏算法的详细描述式(4)基于Nt和xt之间的分段线性关系,其中游戏线和喷射线通过结点连续连接。在图3中,当输入顺序为xt0→xt1→xt2→xt3时,结点为点a、b、c、d、e和f。结点的位置是先验未知的,因为它们依赖于必须估计的玩法间隔的宽度γ,以及由过去的xt值决定的玩法线的位置。由于相邻的储层和喷流线是相连的,因此使用方程是一个带有未知分裂因子的开关回归的特殊情况,在储层模型的背景下,该分裂因子对应于宽度γt(见图3),类似于线性样条函数(见Poirier Citation1973, Citation1976)。在这种情况下,OLS估计量在标准回归模型假设下是渐近一致和正态分布的(见Hinkley Citation1969;哈德逊Citation1966;地方Citation1976) .37点请注意,在该模型中,总就业、Nt和由xt捕获的总需求之间的关系中存在非时间性质的结构变化,这种变化源于xt的反转,以及随后累积的超过游戏间隔的变化,以及由于需求不确定性爆发而导致游戏间隔本身变化而导致的时域结构变化对于水平中的变量,增宽的Dickey-Fuller检验统计量(在检验方程中包含一个截距)通常大于1%临界值(- 3.509),表明我们不拒绝序列的非平稳性(附录2)。对于序列的第一个差,我们通常拒绝存在单位根的假设(检验统计量小于1%临界值)。我们得出结论,通常变量是I(1)的积分。唯一的例外是法国、德国和英国的xt水平保持不变。英国的水平也保持不变。法国的Nt和美国的Wt是1 (3).39协整检验采用约翰森检验程序。基于在VAR表示中使用四个滞后进行的跟踪检验,并在协整就业方程(3)中进行截距(3),(3)Nt=β0+β1xt+β2St(γt)+β3Wt+εt(3),得出结论,在加拿大,德国和意大利的情况下,式(3)中的变量是一级协整的;在法国、日本和美国的情况下,排名第二的协整;英国排名第四的协整(表2中报告了拒绝无协整假设的痕量检验统计量和5%显著性水平的临界值)FM-OLS估计器用半参数修正修正最小二乘,该修正考虑了序列相关效应和因协整关系存在而导致的回归量的内质性(Phillips Citation1995;Phillips and Hansen Citation1990).41对于1%的显著性水平前面提到的推理的性质是基于大样本理论的,在小样本中可能不是准确的近似(参见欣克利引文1969;Poirier Citation1976)。事实上,估计量的分布可能缓慢地收敛到正态。尽管如此,Wald检验统计量的高值(特别是涉及到爆发变量)使我们对估计的重要性充满信心。本研究由葡萄牙公共基金通过FCT(葡萄牙科学和技术基金会)和欧洲区域发展基金在POCI-01-0145-联邦-006890项目框架内通过“竞争2020 -国际业务竞争方案”(POCI)资助。本文作者paulo R. Mota就职于经济与商业学院和CEF。波尔图大学。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Aggregate demand uncertainty outbreaks and employment hysteresis in G7 countries
AbstractThe slow recovery following the recent financial crisis in many developed countries, and the predictable long lasting economic effects of the Covid-19 pandemic have raised a new interest on the topic of employment hysteresis. In the presence of hysteresis there is no predetermined long-run equilibrium level of aggregate employment. As the economic system is not self-adjusting toward a unique equilibrium, timely, and sustained expansionary macroeconomic policies should be applied to mitigate the impact of negative shocks. The purpose of this paper is to uncover hysteresis effects in the macrodynamics of employment along with variations in its intensity that may result from outbreaks in aggregate demand uncertainty. We estimate a switching employment equation based on the play model of hysteresis, which describes a dynamic process whereby non-convex adjustment costs and uncertainty create intervals of weak reaction of employment to small changes in forcing variables, but spurts in the reaction to large demand shocks. As a novel feature, the estimation allows the presence of structural breaks in the value of the switching parameter of the employment equation due to aggregate demand uncertainty outbreaks. We have concluded that hysteresis effects increased in general in crisis periods associated to outbreaks of uncertainty in aggregate demand.Keywords: Employmenthysteresisuncertaintystructural breaksJEL CLASSIFICATION CODES: E24J23 Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 Local input extrema that are not followed by an absolute extrema (see, e.g., Cross et al. Citation2005).2 Therefore, hysteresis should not be confused with the presence of a unit root in a linear dynamic system, or zero root in continuous time difference equations (see Amable et al. Citation1993, Citation1994). The consequence is that non-stationary econometrics cannot be used to overcome the role of uncertainty and to make predictions about the future on the basis of past data. This issue has been put forward by Davidson (Citation1993) concerning the adequacy of the concept of hysteresis in the context of post Keynesian economics.3 For example, uncertainty about the course of technical progress, the future behavior of prices, the outcome of plan of investment, not to mention the effects of natural and political cataclysms with economic impact (Robinson Citation1974, 1).4 The possibility that the firms have to adjust labor input along the intensive margin, i.e., fluctuations in hours worked per employee, may also enhance the employment hysteresis effects (Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2012).5 The importance of the initial conditions and path dependence as drivers of the outcome of economic system was early recognized by Robinson (Citation1974).6 See also Rios, Rachinskii, and Cross (Citation2017).7 This is perfectly compatible with the concept of hysteresis. In fact “…hysteresis involves explicit structural change in the system that is determining long-run outcomes. Hence a hysteretic system may actively create its own set of final outcomes in the course of its evolution as a result of this structural change. With hysteresis, then, whilst definitive final outcomes – such as equilibria – are possible, it may only be within our powers to identify these outcomes ex post, after they have actually been established. They need not exist ex ante, independently of the actual history of adjustments in the system to which they pertain.” Setterfield (Citation1998, 294)8 See Benigno and Fornaro (Citation2018); Cerra, Saxena, and Panizza (Citation2013); Garga and Singh (Citation2021), Jordà, Singh, and Taylor (Citation2020); Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox (Citation2015), for recent evidence of permanent effects of monetary policy.9 As the wedge between private and public returns on investments in R&D increases typically during recessions, the State should subsidize particularly the investment in innovation (see Bianchi et al. Citation2019). Besides, monetary policy should be adequately expansionary to reduce the liquidity risk of long-term investments in innovation (see Aghion et al. Citation2012).10 A concept that was not familiar to Keynes.11 Keynes was part of a long tradition rejecting the view that the economic system is self-adjusting to a general equilibrium (see Kregel Citation2011, 271, for a survey of the literature).12 The switching parameter of the employment equation is interpreted as an ‘aggregate employment band on inaction,’ which summarizes the magnitude of the hysteretic effects (Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2015).13 Although originally applied in the physics of magnetics, the Preisach model should be viewed as a new mathematical idea that can be applied to describe a wide range of hysteretic phenomena in quite different areas, including aggregate employment dynamics (see, e.g., Amable et al. Citation1993, Citation1994; Cross Citation1994, Citation1997; Cross et al. Citation2005; Mayergoyz Citation2021.14 We assume that the exogenous component of aggregate demand, xt, determines the state of firm’s activity through its impact in the price level, which corresponds to the gross revenue under the assumptions of the model.15 Firm also incur in sunk costs for the acquisition of physical assets like firm specific equipment or intangible assets such as reputation, acquired by investments in marketing and advertising, or technical knowledge (see, e.g., Belke, Baudisch, and Göcke Citation2020; Dias and Shackleton Citation2011; Folta, Johnson, and O’Brien Citation2006; Pindyck Citation1988, Citation1991). Other non-firm specific investments like office equipment, cars, trucks and computers can have a resale value well below their purchase cost due to the ‘lemons’ problem (Pindyck Citation1991, 1111). Furthermore, to enter new markets, firms often have to incur irreversible costs, e.g., for gathering information on market revenues, creating distribution and servicing networks, and advertising or establishing a brand name (see, Adamonis and Göcke Citation2019).16 EquationEquation (1)(1) Rαj,βj(xt)={1, if Rαj,βj(xt−1)=0 and xt≥βj [entry in the market] orRαj,βj(xt−1)=1 and xt>αj [stay active in the market]0, if Rαj,βj(xt−1)=0 and xt<βj [stay inactive] or Rαj,βj(xt−1)=1 and xt≤αj [exit the market](1) is derived from a profit maximizing problem in discrete time with an infinite plan horizon, and a discount factor, δ=11+i, where i is the interest rate (see, e.g., Göcke Citation2002, 118, and Mota et al. Citation2012 for a complete description of the model).17 Within the assumptions of the model the trigger values for exit and entry are αj=wj−δFj and βj=wj+δHj respectively (see, e.g., Göcke Citation2002; Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2012).18 This stylized model can offer a good description of the employment dynamics if we consider a firm disaggregated into single production units, each of them represented by a non-ideal relay operator (see Belke and Göcke Citation1999; Cross Citation2014). Therefore, in this setting the decision to enter the market is similar to the hiring decision, and the decision to exit the market is analogous to the firing decision.19 This matches with the empirical observation of discontinuous and irregular adjustment of employment by firms, in which periods of inaction are punctuated by episodes of large adjustment (see e.g., Caballero, Engel, and Haltiwanger Citation1997; Hamermesh Citation1989; Mota, Varejão, and Vasconcelos Citation2012; Varejão and Portugal Citation2007).20 The heterogeneity in the way firms react to aggregate demand shocks arises from specific cost structures including non-convex adjustment costs (that may depend on firms’ age, size, ownership, average work skill level and innovation), and from the way firms deal with uncertainty (see, Gaëlle and Scarpetta Citation2006).21 See Cross et al. (Citation2005); Piscitelli et al. (Citation2000), for a more comprehensive description of the geometric description of the Preisach model of hysteresis.22 As we assume that firms are uniformly distributed in the Preisach triangle, the branches of the hysteresis loop are quadratic functions.23 At the firm level there are only two branches, and the transition between those branches only occurs when xt increases above βj or decreases below αj.24 This follows from the wiping-out property of the Preisach model (see, Mayergoyz Citation2003).25 For a complete description of the Preisach model of hysteresis see, e.g. Mayergoyz (Citation2003); Mota and Vasconcelos (Citation2012).26 See Cross et al. (Citation2010); Göcke and Werner (Citation2015); Piscitelli et al. (Citation1999) for theoretical models with feedback effects of the system on the equilibrium level of the hysteretic forcing variable.27 See also Amable et al (Citation1993, Citation1994).28 The linear play model of hysteresis (the term is used because of its analogy to play in mechanics) can be viewed as a piecewise-linear approximation of the Preisach hysteresis loop, where the slope of the linear functions change at extrema (see, Krasnosel’skii and Pokrovskii Citation1989; Visitin Citation1994).29 A general description of the model can be found in Visitin (Citation1994).30 This can be the result of an exogenous shock or endogenously caused by the decrease of demand. In fact, of a lack of aggregate demand and increasing unemployment can be viewed as the result of the malfunctioning of the economy and thus affects business confidence.31 The sequence xt1→xt2→xt3 originates as counter-clockwise oriented loop abcde.32 Although real wages could also be a source of hysteresis, our aim is to test the presence of hysteresis caused by aggregate demand shocks. Therefore, real wages enters as a non-hysteretic explanatory variable in the employment equation. For the joint influence of several inputs in an economic system with hysteresis see Göcke (Citation2019).33 We assume that the demand for employment results from consumers’ demand for final goods and services (that determines a scale effect), and the availability of employment that determines its price (input substitution effect). Therefore, we include in the employment equation the traditional explanatory variables (we follow Hamermesh, Citation1993, 30 and 64).34 See also Belke and Göcke (Citation2001a, Citation2001b); Göcke (Citation2001) for more detail.35 See Mota and Vasconcelos (Citation2021) for a detailed description of this new version of the play algorithm.36 Equation (4) is based on a piecewise linear relationship between Nt and xt where the play lines and the spurt lines are connected continuously by knots. In Figure 3 the knots are points a, b, c, d, e, and f when the input follows the sequence xt0→ xt1→xt2→xt3. The position of the knots are a priori unknown, because they depend on the width of the play interval, γ, which has to be estimated, and on the position of the play line that is determined by the past values of xt. Since the adjacent play and spurts lines are connected, the employment equation is a special case of a switching regression with an unknown splitting factor that in the context of the play model corresponds to the width γt (see Figure 3), and similar to a linear spline function (see Poirier Citation1973, Citation1976). In this case, the OLS estimator is asymptotically consistent and normal distributed under the standard regression model assumptions (see Hinkley Citation1969; Hudson Citation1966; Poirier Citation1976).37 Note that is this model there is a combination of structural changes of a non-temporal nature in the relationship between aggregate employment, Nt, and aggregate demand captured by xt that arises from reversals of xt, and from subsequently cumulated variations surpassing the play interval, and structural changes in the time domain due to changes in the play interval itself due to demand uncertainty outbreaks.38 For the variables in levels the augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic (with an intercept included in the test equation) is in general larger than the 1% critical value (−3.509), indicating that we do not reject the non-stationary of the series (Appendix 2). For the first difference of the series, we reject in general the hypothesis of the existence of a unit root (test statistic is smaller than the 1% critical value). We conclude that in general the variables are integrated of order one, I(1). The exceptions is xt that is stationary in levels for France, Germany and for the UK. Nt that is also stationary in levels for the UK. Nt for France and Wt for the United States are I(3).39 The Johansen Test Procedure was used for cointegration testing. Based on the trace test performed with four lags in the VAR representation, and with an intercept in the cointegrating employment EquationEquation (3)(3) Nt=β0+β1xt+β2St(γt)+β3Wt+εt(3) , have concluded that the variables in Equation (3) are cointegrated of rank one in the cases of Canada, Germany, and Italy; cointegrated of rank two in the cases of France, Japan, and USA; and cointegrated of rank four for the UK (the trace test statistic and the critical value for a 5% significance level for the rejection of the hypothesis of no cointegration is reported in Table 2).40 FM-OLS estimator modifies least squares with semiparametric corrections that account for serial correlation effects and for endogeneity in the regressors that result from the existence of cointegrating relationships (Phillips Citation1995; Phillips and Hansen Citation1990).41 For 1% significance level.42 The properties of the inference mentioned before are based on large sample theory and might not be accurate approximations in small size samples (See Hinkley Citation1969 ; Poirier Citation1976). In fact, the distribution of the estimator may converge slowly to normality. Nonetheless, the high value of the Wald test statistic (especially tat concerns the spurt variable) makes us confident of the significance of the estimates.Additional informationFundingThis research has been financed by Portuguese Public Funds through FCT (Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology) and by the European Regional Development Fund through COMPETE 2020 – Programa Operacional Competitividade e Internacionalização (POCI) – in the framework of the project POCI-01-0145-FEDER-006890.Notes on contributorsPaulo R. MotaPaulo R. Mota is at School of Economics and Business and CEF.UP, University of Porto.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
1.70
自引率
10.00%
发文量
23
期刊介绍: The Journal of Post Keynesian Economics is a scholarly journal of innovative theoretical and empirical work that sheds fresh light on contemporary economic problems. It is committed to the principle that cumulative development of economic theory is only possible when the theory is continuously subjected to scrutiny in terms of its ability both to explain the real world and to provide a reliable guide to public policy.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信