重力税率

IF 2.2 3区 经济学 Q2 ECONOMICS
Kazunobu Hayakawa, Taiyo Yoshimi
{"title":"重力税率","authors":"Kazunobu Hayakawa, Taiyo Yoshimi","doi":"10.1080/09638199.2023.2277779","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"AbstractThis paper considers the case where multiple tariff schemes (e.g. general and preferential schemes) are available between trading countries. We incorporate these tariffs into gravity equations and estimate them by the Pseudo-Poisson maximum likelihood technique. The results show that omitting either tariff type leads to significant estimates biases. If fixed effects to control other tariffs are not included in the model, both preferential and general tariffs are to be introduced in the gravity equation. Indeed, some estimation results for precision metals show that reducing both types of tariffs contributes to significantly increasing trade values. However, reducing general tariffs does not always have a trade-enhancing effect. In leather products, for example, its impact was insignificant. Nevertheless, the reduction of preferential tariffs was again found to increase trade values significantly.KEYWORDS: Gravitytariffsregional trade agreementsJEL Classifications: F15F53 AcknowledgementWe would like to thank Kyoji Fukao, Norikatsu Hiraide, Naoto Jinji, Fukunari Kimura, Yoshimasa Komoriya, Hitoshi Sato, Kenta Yamanouchi, and the seminar participants at Keio University, Kangwon National University, the Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA), the Nagoya International Economics Study Group (NIESG), the Japan Society of International Economics, the Japanese Economic Association, the Western Economic Association International (WEAI), and the Institute of Developing Economies (IDE-JETRO).Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 The earlier studies focused on trade by a single country. The examples include Trefler (Citation2004), Romalis (Citation2007), and Debaere and Mostashari (Citation2010). Also, the recent US-China trade disputes increased the number of studies on the trade effects of tariffs in the US or China (Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein Citation2019; Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein Citation2020; Fajgelbaum et al. Citation2020; Ma, Ning, and Xu Citation2021).2 Specifically, imports in Australia from the United States or Canada are approximately 50%. The share of European Union imports from Mexico is about 80%. A similar share can be found in the case of U.S. imports from Australia.3 In the empirical part, we define products at the tariff-section level, i.e., the industry level.4 Following Helpman, Melitz, and Rubinstein (Citation2008) and Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (Citation2004), we assume exporters pay fixed costs for products to every destination while dealing with multiple destinations simultaneously. Hence, they cannot save the total fixed costs based on economies of scale. A similar situation is assumed for the fixed cost for RTA usage. These cases are not examined to ensure the model's tractability and help develop an explicit gravity equation.5 We also employ the assumption used in Chaney (Citation2008) that the total mass of potential entrants in each country in each differentiated sector is proportional to national labor income. As a result, larger and wealthier countries have more entrants.6 In contrast, the case where all exporters utilize RTA is called the homogeneous regime (Demidova and Krishna Citation2008). Under the homogeneous regime, MFN tariffs do not affect bilateral trade on the product-level. We focus on the heterogeneous regime to reveal the role of alternative tariffs in gravity analysis. In fact, the homogeneous regime is rarely observed in the data.7 Equation (A3) in Appendix A1 presents the theoretical condition for realizing the heterogeneous regime. Specifically, the heterogeneous regime takes place when (i) the fixed cost for RTA utilization is high compared to the fixed cost for exporting, (ii) the variable trade cost, i.e., the product of RTA tariff rates and procurement adjustment cost, is not significantly low compared to MFN rates, or (iii) the price elasticity of demand is small. Our focus on the heterogeneous regime is reasonable because our empirical analysis is conducted at an industry-level. At this level, it is relatively rare to observe that the share of imports under the RTA regimes is 0% or 100%. See, for example, Keck and Lendle (Citation2012).8 Equilibrium values are shown in Appendix A. Specifically, to derive (1), we used (A4), (A6), (A7), (A8), and (A9) for wiLi, xijh(φ), φijhM, φijhR>M and π, respectively.9 The number of MFN users tends to be large, and the coefficient for MFN rates tends to be negative if (i) initial levels of MFN rates are low, (ii) initial levels of RTA rates or procurement adjustment cost are high, or (iii) initial level of fixed cost for RTA utilization is high.10 Olivero and Yotov (Citation2012) provide the theoretical foundations for a dynamic gravity model.11 Henderson and Millimet (Citation2008) relax this assumption and estimate gravity models.12 We can normalize wages in all countries to 1 as we employ the numeraire sector and focus on equilibria where all countries produce some of the numeraire product. Therefore, for simplicity, we set wit to 1 hereafter.13 Baier and Bergstrand (Citation2009) showed that a Taylor approximation produces coefficient estimates virtually identical to those obtained from an unbiased nonlinear procedure. See also Anderson, Vesselovsky, and Yotov (Citation2016) and Behar and Nelson (Citation2014) for applying Taylor approximation in the derivation of gravity equations.14 Definitions and signs of the coefficients in equation Equation(5)(5) ln⁡Tijht≅ln⁡T¯h+ΔτM(ln⁡τjhtM−ln⁡τ¯hM)+ΔτR(ln⁡τijhtR−ln⁡τ¯hR)+Δρ(ln⁡ρijh−ln⁡ρ¯h)+Δf(ln⁡fijh−ln⁡f¯h)+ΔfR(ln⁡fijhR−ln⁡f¯hR),(5) are given in Appendix A4.15 As in the usual gravity studies, like Feenstra (Citation2002), third-country effects through multilateral resistance are controlled by our inclusion of import country-year fixed effects.16 From the theoretical perspective, the coefficients for tariff variables should be different across countries and products. However, we do not differentiate those and estimate the average magnitude.17 http://www.cepii.fr/CEPII/en/welcome.asp.18 As pointed out by Teti (Citation2020), there are some things that could be improved in the WITS database, which include missing data and misreporting. We set the missing tariff equal to the nearest preceding observation but do not address the misreporting issue.19 Our study period does not include the pandemic period when many countries imposed various trade-restrictive measures.20 The estimation results for other industries are reported in Table B2 in Appendix B.Additional informationFundingThis work was supported by Chuo University: [Grant Number Chuo University Grant for Special Research]; Japan Society for the Promotion of Science KAKENHI: [Grant Number JP17H02530 and JP20H01518].","PeriodicalId":51656,"journal":{"name":"Journal of International Trade & Economic Development","volume":"73 3","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":2.2000,"publicationDate":"2023-11-05","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Tariff rates in gravity\",\"authors\":\"Kazunobu Hayakawa, Taiyo Yoshimi\",\"doi\":\"10.1080/09638199.2023.2277779\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"AbstractThis paper considers the case where multiple tariff schemes (e.g. general and preferential schemes) are available between trading countries. We incorporate these tariffs into gravity equations and estimate them by the Pseudo-Poisson maximum likelihood technique. The results show that omitting either tariff type leads to significant estimates biases. If fixed effects to control other tariffs are not included in the model, both preferential and general tariffs are to be introduced in the gravity equation. Indeed, some estimation results for precision metals show that reducing both types of tariffs contributes to significantly increasing trade values. However, reducing general tariffs does not always have a trade-enhancing effect. In leather products, for example, its impact was insignificant. Nevertheless, the reduction of preferential tariffs was again found to increase trade values significantly.KEYWORDS: Gravitytariffsregional trade agreementsJEL Classifications: F15F53 AcknowledgementWe would like to thank Kyoji Fukao, Norikatsu Hiraide, Naoto Jinji, Fukunari Kimura, Yoshimasa Komoriya, Hitoshi Sato, Kenta Yamanouchi, and the seminar participants at Keio University, Kangwon National University, the Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA), the Nagoya International Economics Study Group (NIESG), the Japan Society of International Economics, the Japanese Economic Association, the Western Economic Association International (WEAI), and the Institute of Developing Economies (IDE-JETRO).Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 The earlier studies focused on trade by a single country. The examples include Trefler (Citation2004), Romalis (Citation2007), and Debaere and Mostashari (Citation2010). Also, the recent US-China trade disputes increased the number of studies on the trade effects of tariffs in the US or China (Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein Citation2019; Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein Citation2020; Fajgelbaum et al. Citation2020; Ma, Ning, and Xu Citation2021).2 Specifically, imports in Australia from the United States or Canada are approximately 50%. The share of European Union imports from Mexico is about 80%. A similar share can be found in the case of U.S. imports from Australia.3 In the empirical part, we define products at the tariff-section level, i.e., the industry level.4 Following Helpman, Melitz, and Rubinstein (Citation2008) and Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (Citation2004), we assume exporters pay fixed costs for products to every destination while dealing with multiple destinations simultaneously. Hence, they cannot save the total fixed costs based on economies of scale. A similar situation is assumed for the fixed cost for RTA usage. These cases are not examined to ensure the model's tractability and help develop an explicit gravity equation.5 We also employ the assumption used in Chaney (Citation2008) that the total mass of potential entrants in each country in each differentiated sector is proportional to national labor income. As a result, larger and wealthier countries have more entrants.6 In contrast, the case where all exporters utilize RTA is called the homogeneous regime (Demidova and Krishna Citation2008). Under the homogeneous regime, MFN tariffs do not affect bilateral trade on the product-level. We focus on the heterogeneous regime to reveal the role of alternative tariffs in gravity analysis. In fact, the homogeneous regime is rarely observed in the data.7 Equation (A3) in Appendix A1 presents the theoretical condition for realizing the heterogeneous regime. Specifically, the heterogeneous regime takes place when (i) the fixed cost for RTA utilization is high compared to the fixed cost for exporting, (ii) the variable trade cost, i.e., the product of RTA tariff rates and procurement adjustment cost, is not significantly low compared to MFN rates, or (iii) the price elasticity of demand is small. Our focus on the heterogeneous regime is reasonable because our empirical analysis is conducted at an industry-level. At this level, it is relatively rare to observe that the share of imports under the RTA regimes is 0% or 100%. See, for example, Keck and Lendle (Citation2012).8 Equilibrium values are shown in Appendix A. Specifically, to derive (1), we used (A4), (A6), (A7), (A8), and (A9) for wiLi, xijh(φ), φijhM, φijhR>M and π, respectively.9 The number of MFN users tends to be large, and the coefficient for MFN rates tends to be negative if (i) initial levels of MFN rates are low, (ii) initial levels of RTA rates or procurement adjustment cost are high, or (iii) initial level of fixed cost for RTA utilization is high.10 Olivero and Yotov (Citation2012) provide the theoretical foundations for a dynamic gravity model.11 Henderson and Millimet (Citation2008) relax this assumption and estimate gravity models.12 We can normalize wages in all countries to 1 as we employ the numeraire sector and focus on equilibria where all countries produce some of the numeraire product. Therefore, for simplicity, we set wit to 1 hereafter.13 Baier and Bergstrand (Citation2009) showed that a Taylor approximation produces coefficient estimates virtually identical to those obtained from an unbiased nonlinear procedure. See also Anderson, Vesselovsky, and Yotov (Citation2016) and Behar and Nelson (Citation2014) for applying Taylor approximation in the derivation of gravity equations.14 Definitions and signs of the coefficients in equation Equation(5)(5) ln⁡Tijht≅ln⁡T¯h+ΔτM(ln⁡τjhtM−ln⁡τ¯hM)+ΔτR(ln⁡τijhtR−ln⁡τ¯hR)+Δρ(ln⁡ρijh−ln⁡ρ¯h)+Δf(ln⁡fijh−ln⁡f¯h)+ΔfR(ln⁡fijhR−ln⁡f¯hR),(5) are given in Appendix A4.15 As in the usual gravity studies, like Feenstra (Citation2002), third-country effects through multilateral resistance are controlled by our inclusion of import country-year fixed effects.16 From the theoretical perspective, the coefficients for tariff variables should be different across countries and products. However, we do not differentiate those and estimate the average magnitude.17 http://www.cepii.fr/CEPII/en/welcome.asp.18 As pointed out by Teti (Citation2020), there are some things that could be improved in the WITS database, which include missing data and misreporting. We set the missing tariff equal to the nearest preceding observation but do not address the misreporting issue.19 Our study period does not include the pandemic period when many countries imposed various trade-restrictive measures.20 The estimation results for other industries are reported in Table B2 in Appendix B.Additional informationFundingThis work was supported by Chuo University: [Grant Number Chuo University Grant for Special Research]; Japan Society for the Promotion of Science KAKENHI: [Grant Number JP17H02530 and JP20H01518].\",\"PeriodicalId\":51656,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Journal of International Trade & Economic Development\",\"volume\":\"73 3\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":2.2000,\"publicationDate\":\"2023-11-05\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Journal of International Trade & Economic Development\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2023.2277779\",\"RegionNum\":3,\"RegionCategory\":\"经济学\",\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"Q2\",\"JCRName\":\"ECONOMICS\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Journal of International Trade & Economic Development","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/09638199.2023.2277779","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

我们可以将所有国家的工资正常化为1,因为我们采用了数字部门,并专注于所有国家都生产一些数字产品的均衡。因此,为了简单起见,我们将wit设置为1拜尔和伯格斯特兰德(Citation2009)表明,泰勒近似产生的系数估计值几乎与从无偏非线性过程中获得的估计值相同。参见Anderson, Vesselovsky和Yotov (Citation2016)以及Behar和Nelson (Citation2014)在引力方程推导中应用泰勒近似方程(5)(5)ln (Tijht) = ln (T¯h+ΔτM(ln (τ jhtm) - ln (τ¯hM)+ΔτR(ln (τ ijhtr - ln (τ¯hR))+Δρ(ln (ρijh - ln (ρ¯h))+Δf(ln (fijh - ln (f¯h))+ΔfR(ln (fijhR) - ln (f¯hR)),(5)的系数定义和符号在附录A4.15中给出。在通常的重力研究中,如Feenstra (Citation2002),通过多边阻力的第三国效应通过我们包括进口国家-年固定效应来控制从理论上讲,关税变量的系数在不同的国家和产品之间应该是不同的。然而,我们不区分这些和估计平均量级。17 http://www.cepii.fr/CEPII/en/welcome.asp.18正如Teti (Citation2020)所指出的,WITS数据库中有一些可以改进的地方,包括数据缺失和误报。我们将丢失的关税与最近的先前观察相等,但不解决误报问题我们的研究期间不包括大流行时期,当时许多国家实施了各种贸易限制措施其他行业的估算结果见附录b的表B2。附加信息经费支持:【资助号:中央大学专项研究资助】;日本科学促进会[资助号JP17H02530和JP20H01518]。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Tariff rates in gravity
AbstractThis paper considers the case where multiple tariff schemes (e.g. general and preferential schemes) are available between trading countries. We incorporate these tariffs into gravity equations and estimate them by the Pseudo-Poisson maximum likelihood technique. The results show that omitting either tariff type leads to significant estimates biases. If fixed effects to control other tariffs are not included in the model, both preferential and general tariffs are to be introduced in the gravity equation. Indeed, some estimation results for precision metals show that reducing both types of tariffs contributes to significantly increasing trade values. However, reducing general tariffs does not always have a trade-enhancing effect. In leather products, for example, its impact was insignificant. Nevertheless, the reduction of preferential tariffs was again found to increase trade values significantly.KEYWORDS: Gravitytariffsregional trade agreementsJEL Classifications: F15F53 AcknowledgementWe would like to thank Kyoji Fukao, Norikatsu Hiraide, Naoto Jinji, Fukunari Kimura, Yoshimasa Komoriya, Hitoshi Sato, Kenta Yamanouchi, and the seminar participants at Keio University, Kangwon National University, the Economic Research Institute for ASEAN and East Asia (ERIA), the Nagoya International Economics Study Group (NIESG), the Japan Society of International Economics, the Japanese Economic Association, the Western Economic Association International (WEAI), and the Institute of Developing Economies (IDE-JETRO).Disclosure statementNo potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s).Notes1 The earlier studies focused on trade by a single country. The examples include Trefler (Citation2004), Romalis (Citation2007), and Debaere and Mostashari (Citation2010). Also, the recent US-China trade disputes increased the number of studies on the trade effects of tariffs in the US or China (Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein Citation2019; Amiti, Redding, and Weinstein Citation2020; Fajgelbaum et al. Citation2020; Ma, Ning, and Xu Citation2021).2 Specifically, imports in Australia from the United States or Canada are approximately 50%. The share of European Union imports from Mexico is about 80%. A similar share can be found in the case of U.S. imports from Australia.3 In the empirical part, we define products at the tariff-section level, i.e., the industry level.4 Following Helpman, Melitz, and Rubinstein (Citation2008) and Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (Citation2004), we assume exporters pay fixed costs for products to every destination while dealing with multiple destinations simultaneously. Hence, they cannot save the total fixed costs based on economies of scale. A similar situation is assumed for the fixed cost for RTA usage. These cases are not examined to ensure the model's tractability and help develop an explicit gravity equation.5 We also employ the assumption used in Chaney (Citation2008) that the total mass of potential entrants in each country in each differentiated sector is proportional to national labor income. As a result, larger and wealthier countries have more entrants.6 In contrast, the case where all exporters utilize RTA is called the homogeneous regime (Demidova and Krishna Citation2008). Under the homogeneous regime, MFN tariffs do not affect bilateral trade on the product-level. We focus on the heterogeneous regime to reveal the role of alternative tariffs in gravity analysis. In fact, the homogeneous regime is rarely observed in the data.7 Equation (A3) in Appendix A1 presents the theoretical condition for realizing the heterogeneous regime. Specifically, the heterogeneous regime takes place when (i) the fixed cost for RTA utilization is high compared to the fixed cost for exporting, (ii) the variable trade cost, i.e., the product of RTA tariff rates and procurement adjustment cost, is not significantly low compared to MFN rates, or (iii) the price elasticity of demand is small. Our focus on the heterogeneous regime is reasonable because our empirical analysis is conducted at an industry-level. At this level, it is relatively rare to observe that the share of imports under the RTA regimes is 0% or 100%. See, for example, Keck and Lendle (Citation2012).8 Equilibrium values are shown in Appendix A. Specifically, to derive (1), we used (A4), (A6), (A7), (A8), and (A9) for wiLi, xijh(φ), φijhM, φijhR>M and π, respectively.9 The number of MFN users tends to be large, and the coefficient for MFN rates tends to be negative if (i) initial levels of MFN rates are low, (ii) initial levels of RTA rates or procurement adjustment cost are high, or (iii) initial level of fixed cost for RTA utilization is high.10 Olivero and Yotov (Citation2012) provide the theoretical foundations for a dynamic gravity model.11 Henderson and Millimet (Citation2008) relax this assumption and estimate gravity models.12 We can normalize wages in all countries to 1 as we employ the numeraire sector and focus on equilibria where all countries produce some of the numeraire product. Therefore, for simplicity, we set wit to 1 hereafter.13 Baier and Bergstrand (Citation2009) showed that a Taylor approximation produces coefficient estimates virtually identical to those obtained from an unbiased nonlinear procedure. See also Anderson, Vesselovsky, and Yotov (Citation2016) and Behar and Nelson (Citation2014) for applying Taylor approximation in the derivation of gravity equations.14 Definitions and signs of the coefficients in equation Equation(5)(5) ln⁡Tijht≅ln⁡T¯h+ΔτM(ln⁡τjhtM−ln⁡τ¯hM)+ΔτR(ln⁡τijhtR−ln⁡τ¯hR)+Δρ(ln⁡ρijh−ln⁡ρ¯h)+Δf(ln⁡fijh−ln⁡f¯h)+ΔfR(ln⁡fijhR−ln⁡f¯hR),(5) are given in Appendix A4.15 As in the usual gravity studies, like Feenstra (Citation2002), third-country effects through multilateral resistance are controlled by our inclusion of import country-year fixed effects.16 From the theoretical perspective, the coefficients for tariff variables should be different across countries and products. However, we do not differentiate those and estimate the average magnitude.17 http://www.cepii.fr/CEPII/en/welcome.asp.18 As pointed out by Teti (Citation2020), there are some things that could be improved in the WITS database, which include missing data and misreporting. We set the missing tariff equal to the nearest preceding observation but do not address the misreporting issue.19 Our study period does not include the pandemic period when many countries imposed various trade-restrictive measures.20 The estimation results for other industries are reported in Table B2 in Appendix B.Additional informationFundingThis work was supported by Chuo University: [Grant Number Chuo University Grant for Special Research]; Japan Society for the Promotion of Science KAKENHI: [Grant Number JP17H02530 and JP20H01518].
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
CiteScore
4.00
自引率
19.00%
发文量
66
期刊介绍: The Journal of International Trade and Economic Development ( JITED) focuses on international economics, economic development, and the interface between trade and development. The links between trade and development economics are critical at a time when fluctuating commodity prices, ongoing production fragmentation, and trade liberalisation can radically affect the economies of advanced and developing countries. Our aim is to keep in touch with the latest developments in research as well as setting the agenda for future analysis. Publication of high quality articles covering; theoretical and applied issues in international and development economics; econometric applications of trade and/or development issues based on sound theoretical economic models or testing fundamental economic hypotheses; models of structural change; trade and development issues of economies in Eastern Europe, Asia and the Pacific area; papers on specific topics which are policy-relevant; review articles on important branches of the literature including controversial and innovative ideas are also welcome. JITED is designed to meet the needs of international and development economists, economic historians, applied economists, and policy makers. The international experts who make up the journal’s Editorial Board encourage contributions from economists world-wide.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信