{"title":"德里国家首都地区的实际购买揭示了消费者对昂贵耐用品的品味、偏好和优先事项","authors":"Anshu Goel","doi":"10.18701/IMSMANTHAN.V11I01.6875","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"especially the pricey consumer durables in a highly competitive\nglobalized Indian market. Conventional wisdom postulates that\nprice and income constraints are the major determinants of\nconsumers’/buyers’ choices and resultant purchase decisions.\nIncome constraint is overcome by access to finance, but prices\nhave no such options except the choice of inferior quality lower\npriced goods/models. In fact, there is a wide range of options to\nchoose from and many white Goods have relatively cheaper\nlocal brands available in the market. There exists highly marked\nmarket segmentation based on product prices and paying\ncapacity of the buyers. Price constraint may constitute the\nbottleneck for only buyers in one segment of the market. A\nsubstantial proportion of low/moderate income group of buyers\nalso tend to use finance to overcome their income constraint in\norder to buy high priced white consumer goods. The high income\nupward mobile and trendsetting consumers choose pricey\noptions; they often go for newly produced goods on low scales\nwhich enter the market for the first time and which command\nextremely high prices. Greater the price of such goods, lower is\ndemand for the same and higher is their conspicuousness,\ndistinctiveness and snob value even among the higher income\npeer groups (See, Baghati, Arvind, 2012, Shri Prakash, 2010,\nand Shri Prakash, Shalini Sharma and Arvind Baghati, 2010).\nGenerally, such products as enter the market for the first time\nembody entirely new designs and models while new designs and\nnew models of existing products command extremely high prices\ndue to production on a lower scale, high cost of innovation\nembodied in the evolving of new product or designs and attractive\nfeatures, and high cost of market exploration and marketing\n(Cf. Cramer, 1972). High price, in its turn, limits the market\nsize. This also adds to demonstration effect and snob value for\nthe owners. First group of buyers of such new market entrant\ngoods become the lead buyers for subsequent purchasers of\nthese goods; they in fact act as advertisers of such goods without\ngetting paid for it by the producers. They act as the leading\nconsumers and trend setters in society and activate urges in\nothers for the acquisition for these goods. This makes such\nbuyers/owners of such goods feel not to be a part of the crowd\nand as ones who belong to exclusive class like the erstwhile\nMaharajas and Nobabs.\nPrice is, however, also supposed to be a proxy of quality; higher\nthe price, greater is the perceived quality, and the snob or\ndemonstration value for the owners. All above facets reflect\npsychological urges and drivers of motivation, which directly or\nindirectly influences buyers’/consumers’ tastes and preferences.\nTastes and preferences have, however, remained hidden behind\nthe invisible curtain simply because these are neither observable\ndirectly nor measurable quantitatively. Therefore, tastes and\npreferences have generally been taken as given and fixed at the\ngiven point in time, though no one questions the validity of the\nhypothesis the tastes and preferences tend to change through\ntime in ad dynamically growing economy due to (i) increase in\nincomes, (ii) rise in social status, (iii) upward movement in\noccupational ladder, (iv) Increased level of education of the\nyounger members and their influence on purchase decisions of\nthe households, and (iv) continuous entry of new and better\nproducts or models in the market. This study assumes that\nobserved buying behavior of purchasers/consumers reveal their\ntastes and preferences. Under the given price and income\nconditions confronting buyers/consumers at any given time, actual\npurchases reflect the choices based on tastes and preferences;\ntastes and preferences are the real drives of choices reflected by\nactual purchases. For example, if m models of a pricey good are\navailable at Pm, m=1,2,…j,……. m. The following relation is\nsatisfied by the observed prices: P1 less than P2 less than P3 less than Pj>Pj+1>….>\nPm. Thus, Pj is the highest observed price at the given time. If we\nobserve one or some buyers opting for j-th model, he/she has\ndisplayed his/her preference for model j. His tastes and\npreferences afe defined by this choice. This notion of tastes and\npreferences is based on Marshall’s adage that the ‘strength of’\nabstract and unobservable factors and forces ‘such as motivation’\nis defined by the outcome(s) that have emanated from the operative\ninfluence of these factors on human behavior.\nThis paper explores the influence of tastes and preferences and\nfactors affecting the same on consumer’s choices involved in\npurchase decisions of pricey white goods. The determinants of\ntastes and preferences lie in the domain of psychological urges/\nmotivation/drivers. One may be motivated by the desire to move\nup the social ladder by keeping up with peers or group leaders,\nor to maintain the current status, or move from lower to higher\nlifestyle, or to catch up with neighbors, friends and relatives.\nPushed by needling of spouse and children, taunts or sneering\nby neighbors, friends, colleagues and/or desire to acquire snob\nvalue or satisfy the urge to show off, and backed by purchasing\npower people opt for the best available in the market. In some\ncases, income constraint induces to opt for 2nd or 3rd best. But\npsychological urges/drivers cannot be translated into actuality without the backing of adequate purchasing power and\nwillingness to part with the money required for the purchase of\na chosen good. This paper explores and examines these facets\nof purchase behavior of consumers. The study is based on\nprimary data collected from households residing in National\ncapital region of Delhi. The sample comprises 600 respondents\nthrough geographically stratified systematic random sampling\nprocedure. The study focuses on purchases related to White\ngoods. Both quantitative and non-parametric methods are used\nin data analysis.","PeriodicalId":135569,"journal":{"name":"The Journal of Innovations","volume":"7 3 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2016-06-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Consumer’s Tastes Preferences and Priorities for Pricey Durablesas Revealed by Actual Purchases in National Capital Region of Delhi\",\"authors\":\"Anshu Goel\",\"doi\":\"10.18701/IMSMANTHAN.V11I01.6875\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"especially the pricey consumer durables in a highly competitive\\nglobalized Indian market. Conventional wisdom postulates that\\nprice and income constraints are the major determinants of\\nconsumers’/buyers’ choices and resultant purchase decisions.\\nIncome constraint is overcome by access to finance, but prices\\nhave no such options except the choice of inferior quality lower\\npriced goods/models. In fact, there is a wide range of options to\\nchoose from and many white Goods have relatively cheaper\\nlocal brands available in the market. There exists highly marked\\nmarket segmentation based on product prices and paying\\ncapacity of the buyers. Price constraint may constitute the\\nbottleneck for only buyers in one segment of the market. A\\nsubstantial proportion of low/moderate income group of buyers\\nalso tend to use finance to overcome their income constraint in\\norder to buy high priced white consumer goods. The high income\\nupward mobile and trendsetting consumers choose pricey\\noptions; they often go for newly produced goods on low scales\\nwhich enter the market for the first time and which command\\nextremely high prices. Greater the price of such goods, lower is\\ndemand for the same and higher is their conspicuousness,\\ndistinctiveness and snob value even among the higher income\\npeer groups (See, Baghati, Arvind, 2012, Shri Prakash, 2010,\\nand Shri Prakash, Shalini Sharma and Arvind Baghati, 2010).\\nGenerally, such products as enter the market for the first time\\nembody entirely new designs and models while new designs and\\nnew models of existing products command extremely high prices\\ndue to production on a lower scale, high cost of innovation\\nembodied in the evolving of new product or designs and attractive\\nfeatures, and high cost of market exploration and marketing\\n(Cf. Cramer, 1972). High price, in its turn, limits the market\\nsize. This also adds to demonstration effect and snob value for\\nthe owners. First group of buyers of such new market entrant\\ngoods become the lead buyers for subsequent purchasers of\\nthese goods; they in fact act as advertisers of such goods without\\ngetting paid for it by the producers. They act as the leading\\nconsumers and trend setters in society and activate urges in\\nothers for the acquisition for these goods. This makes such\\nbuyers/owners of such goods feel not to be a part of the crowd\\nand as ones who belong to exclusive class like the erstwhile\\nMaharajas and Nobabs.\\nPrice is, however, also supposed to be a proxy of quality; higher\\nthe price, greater is the perceived quality, and the snob or\\ndemonstration value for the owners. All above facets reflect\\npsychological urges and drivers of motivation, which directly or\\nindirectly influences buyers’/consumers’ tastes and preferences.\\nTastes and preferences have, however, remained hidden behind\\nthe invisible curtain simply because these are neither observable\\ndirectly nor measurable quantitatively. Therefore, tastes and\\npreferences have generally been taken as given and fixed at the\\ngiven point in time, though no one questions the validity of the\\nhypothesis the tastes and preferences tend to change through\\ntime in ad dynamically growing economy due to (i) increase in\\nincomes, (ii) rise in social status, (iii) upward movement in\\noccupational ladder, (iv) Increased level of education of the\\nyounger members and their influence on purchase decisions of\\nthe households, and (iv) continuous entry of new and better\\nproducts or models in the market. This study assumes that\\nobserved buying behavior of purchasers/consumers reveal their\\ntastes and preferences. Under the given price and income\\nconditions confronting buyers/consumers at any given time, actual\\npurchases reflect the choices based on tastes and preferences;\\ntastes and preferences are the real drives of choices reflected by\\nactual purchases. For example, if m models of a pricey good are\\navailable at Pm, m=1,2,…j,……. m. The following relation is\\nsatisfied by the observed prices: P1 less than P2 less than P3 less than Pj>Pj+1>….>\\nPm. Thus, Pj is the highest observed price at the given time. If we\\nobserve one or some buyers opting for j-th model, he/she has\\ndisplayed his/her preference for model j. His tastes and\\npreferences afe defined by this choice. This notion of tastes and\\npreferences is based on Marshall’s adage that the ‘strength of’\\nabstract and unobservable factors and forces ‘such as motivation’\\nis defined by the outcome(s) that have emanated from the operative\\ninfluence of these factors on human behavior.\\nThis paper explores the influence of tastes and preferences and\\nfactors affecting the same on consumer’s choices involved in\\npurchase decisions of pricey white goods. The determinants of\\ntastes and preferences lie in the domain of psychological urges/\\nmotivation/drivers. One may be motivated by the desire to move\\nup the social ladder by keeping up with peers or group leaders,\\nor to maintain the current status, or move from lower to higher\\nlifestyle, or to catch up with neighbors, friends and relatives.\\nPushed by needling of spouse and children, taunts or sneering\\nby neighbors, friends, colleagues and/or desire to acquire snob\\nvalue or satisfy the urge to show off, and backed by purchasing\\npower people opt for the best available in the market. In some\\ncases, income constraint induces to opt for 2nd or 3rd best. But\\npsychological urges/drivers cannot be translated into actuality without the backing of adequate purchasing power and\\nwillingness to part with the money required for the purchase of\\na chosen good. This paper explores and examines these facets\\nof purchase behavior of consumers. The study is based on\\nprimary data collected from households residing in National\\ncapital region of Delhi. The sample comprises 600 respondents\\nthrough geographically stratified systematic random sampling\\nprocedure. The study focuses on purchases related to White\\ngoods. Both quantitative and non-parametric methods are used\\nin data analysis.\",\"PeriodicalId\":135569,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"The Journal of Innovations\",\"volume\":\"7 3 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2016-06-28\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"The Journal of Innovations\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.18701/IMSMANTHAN.V11I01.6875\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"The Journal of Innovations","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.18701/IMSMANTHAN.V11I01.6875","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
Consumer’s Tastes Preferences and Priorities for Pricey Durablesas Revealed by Actual Purchases in National Capital Region of Delhi
especially the pricey consumer durables in a highly competitive
globalized Indian market. Conventional wisdom postulates that
price and income constraints are the major determinants of
consumers’/buyers’ choices and resultant purchase decisions.
Income constraint is overcome by access to finance, but prices
have no such options except the choice of inferior quality lower
priced goods/models. In fact, there is a wide range of options to
choose from and many white Goods have relatively cheaper
local brands available in the market. There exists highly marked
market segmentation based on product prices and paying
capacity of the buyers. Price constraint may constitute the
bottleneck for only buyers in one segment of the market. A
substantial proportion of low/moderate income group of buyers
also tend to use finance to overcome their income constraint in
order to buy high priced white consumer goods. The high income
upward mobile and trendsetting consumers choose pricey
options; they often go for newly produced goods on low scales
which enter the market for the first time and which command
extremely high prices. Greater the price of such goods, lower is
demand for the same and higher is their conspicuousness,
distinctiveness and snob value even among the higher income
peer groups (See, Baghati, Arvind, 2012, Shri Prakash, 2010,
and Shri Prakash, Shalini Sharma and Arvind Baghati, 2010).
Generally, such products as enter the market for the first time
embody entirely new designs and models while new designs and
new models of existing products command extremely high prices
due to production on a lower scale, high cost of innovation
embodied in the evolving of new product or designs and attractive
features, and high cost of market exploration and marketing
(Cf. Cramer, 1972). High price, in its turn, limits the market
size. This also adds to demonstration effect and snob value for
the owners. First group of buyers of such new market entrant
goods become the lead buyers for subsequent purchasers of
these goods; they in fact act as advertisers of such goods without
getting paid for it by the producers. They act as the leading
consumers and trend setters in society and activate urges in
others for the acquisition for these goods. This makes such
buyers/owners of such goods feel not to be a part of the crowd
and as ones who belong to exclusive class like the erstwhile
Maharajas and Nobabs.
Price is, however, also supposed to be a proxy of quality; higher
the price, greater is the perceived quality, and the snob or
demonstration value for the owners. All above facets reflect
psychological urges and drivers of motivation, which directly or
indirectly influences buyers’/consumers’ tastes and preferences.
Tastes and preferences have, however, remained hidden behind
the invisible curtain simply because these are neither observable
directly nor measurable quantitatively. Therefore, tastes and
preferences have generally been taken as given and fixed at the
given point in time, though no one questions the validity of the
hypothesis the tastes and preferences tend to change through
time in ad dynamically growing economy due to (i) increase in
incomes, (ii) rise in social status, (iii) upward movement in
occupational ladder, (iv) Increased level of education of the
younger members and their influence on purchase decisions of
the households, and (iv) continuous entry of new and better
products or models in the market. This study assumes that
observed buying behavior of purchasers/consumers reveal their
tastes and preferences. Under the given price and income
conditions confronting buyers/consumers at any given time, actual
purchases reflect the choices based on tastes and preferences;
tastes and preferences are the real drives of choices reflected by
actual purchases. For example, if m models of a pricey good are
available at Pm, m=1,2,…j,……. m. The following relation is
satisfied by the observed prices: P1 less than P2 less than P3 less than Pj>Pj+1>….>
Pm. Thus, Pj is the highest observed price at the given time. If we
observe one or some buyers opting for j-th model, he/she has
displayed his/her preference for model j. His tastes and
preferences afe defined by this choice. This notion of tastes and
preferences is based on Marshall’s adage that the ‘strength of’
abstract and unobservable factors and forces ‘such as motivation’
is defined by the outcome(s) that have emanated from the operative
influence of these factors on human behavior.
This paper explores the influence of tastes and preferences and
factors affecting the same on consumer’s choices involved in
purchase decisions of pricey white goods. The determinants of
tastes and preferences lie in the domain of psychological urges/
motivation/drivers. One may be motivated by the desire to move
up the social ladder by keeping up with peers or group leaders,
or to maintain the current status, or move from lower to higher
lifestyle, or to catch up with neighbors, friends and relatives.
Pushed by needling of spouse and children, taunts or sneering
by neighbors, friends, colleagues and/or desire to acquire snob
value or satisfy the urge to show off, and backed by purchasing
power people opt for the best available in the market. In some
cases, income constraint induces to opt for 2nd or 3rd best. But
psychological urges/drivers cannot be translated into actuality without the backing of adequate purchasing power and
willingness to part with the money required for the purchase of
a chosen good. This paper explores and examines these facets
of purchase behavior of consumers. The study is based on
primary data collected from households residing in National
capital region of Delhi. The sample comprises 600 respondents
through geographically stratified systematic random sampling
procedure. The study focuses on purchases related to White
goods. Both quantitative and non-parametric methods are used
in data analysis.