政策选择

{"title":"政策选择","authors":"","doi":"10.1163/9789047407485_005","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"A s we approach the fiftieth anniversary of Nobel laureate Gary Becker's seminal contribution (Becker, 1968), it is fair to say that the economics of crime is part of the standard portfolio that makes up the discipline. On both sides of the Atlantic, a critical mass of academic economists has specialised in the study of crime and its control. For example, a series of CEP studies has contributed to making sense of the UK's 'riddle of peacefulness' (Draca, 2013) and analysing which policies can be most effective in reducing crime (Marie, 2010). Of course, social scientific study of crime was well established by the time of Gary Becker's contribution. Prior to that, from the 1920s, the dominant disciplines were sociology and psychology, and that continued as criminology departments and schools were established in the postwar period. Becker chose to bypass rather than engage with that tradition, stating that 'a useful theory of criminal behaviour can dispense with special theories of anomie, psychological inadequacies, or inheritance of special traits and simply extend the economist's analysis of choice.' With this bit of disciplinary imperialism as a guide, subsequent contributions from economics tended to adopt the view that crime research was virgin territory. Economists were initially not so welcome in criminology and, for the most part, were unconcerned, feeling that they had little to learn from the 'natives'. More recently, that separation between economics and criminology has begun to break down, an encouraging trend that can be traced in part to the growth of multidisciplinary public-policy programmes and think-tanks. In a new book, we examine what economists have contributed to the study of criminal behaviour and crime control and identify four key strands: n A normative framework for evaluating criminal law and crime prevention. n The application of sophisticated quantitative methods to analyse the causes of crime and the effects of crime-control measures in this framework. n The conception of criminal behaviour as individual choice, influenced by perceived consequences. n The aggregation of individual choices into a systems framework for understanding crime rates and patterns. During the tumultuous years of the 1960s, with riots in US cities and escalating rates of crime and drug abuse, Congress created several high-profile commissions to assess the underlying problems and recommend effective reforms. When these commissions turned to the prominent criminologists of the day, they offered their opinions but had little in the way of relevant evidence. …","PeriodicalId":210878,"journal":{"name":"Dispute Resolution in Electronic Commerce","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"2","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Policy Choice\",\"authors\":\"\",\"doi\":\"10.1163/9789047407485_005\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"A s we approach the fiftieth anniversary of Nobel laureate Gary Becker's seminal contribution (Becker, 1968), it is fair to say that the economics of crime is part of the standard portfolio that makes up the discipline. On both sides of the Atlantic, a critical mass of academic economists has specialised in the study of crime and its control. For example, a series of CEP studies has contributed to making sense of the UK's 'riddle of peacefulness' (Draca, 2013) and analysing which policies can be most effective in reducing crime (Marie, 2010). Of course, social scientific study of crime was well established by the time of Gary Becker's contribution. Prior to that, from the 1920s, the dominant disciplines were sociology and psychology, and that continued as criminology departments and schools were established in the postwar period. Becker chose to bypass rather than engage with that tradition, stating that 'a useful theory of criminal behaviour can dispense with special theories of anomie, psychological inadequacies, or inheritance of special traits and simply extend the economist's analysis of choice.' With this bit of disciplinary imperialism as a guide, subsequent contributions from economics tended to adopt the view that crime research was virgin territory. Economists were initially not so welcome in criminology and, for the most part, were unconcerned, feeling that they had little to learn from the 'natives'. More recently, that separation between economics and criminology has begun to break down, an encouraging trend that can be traced in part to the growth of multidisciplinary public-policy programmes and think-tanks. In a new book, we examine what economists have contributed to the study of criminal behaviour and crime control and identify four key strands: n A normative framework for evaluating criminal law and crime prevention. n The application of sophisticated quantitative methods to analyse the causes of crime and the effects of crime-control measures in this framework. n The conception of criminal behaviour as individual choice, influenced by perceived consequences. n The aggregation of individual choices into a systems framework for understanding crime rates and patterns. During the tumultuous years of the 1960s, with riots in US cities and escalating rates of crime and drug abuse, Congress created several high-profile commissions to assess the underlying problems and recommend effective reforms. When these commissions turned to the prominent criminologists of the day, they offered their opinions but had little in the way of relevant evidence. …\",\"PeriodicalId\":210878,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Dispute Resolution in Electronic Commerce\",\"volume\":\"1 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"1900-01-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"2\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Dispute Resolution in Electronic Commerce\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1163/9789047407485_005\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Dispute Resolution in Electronic Commerce","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1163/9789047407485_005","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2

摘要

在我们接近诺贝尔奖得主加里•贝克尔(Gary Becker)开创性贡献50周年之际(Becker, 1968),我们可以说,犯罪经济学是构成该学科的标准投资组合的一部分。在大西洋两岸,大批学院派经济学家专门从事犯罪及其控制的研究。例如,一系列CEP研究有助于理解英国的“和平之谜”(Draca, 2013),并分析哪些政策可以最有效地减少犯罪(Marie, 2010)。当然,在加里·贝克尔做出贡献之前,犯罪的社会科学研究已经很成熟了。在此之前,从20世纪20年代开始,主要学科是社会学和心理学,并在战后时期继续建立犯罪学部门和学校。贝克尔选择绕过而不是参与这一传统,他说:“一个有用的犯罪行为理论可以省去关于社会反常、心理缺陷或特殊特征遗传的特殊理论,而只是扩展经济学家对选择的分析。”以这一点学科帝国主义为指导,经济学的后续贡献倾向于采用犯罪研究是处女地的观点。经济学家最初在犯罪学领域并不受欢迎,而且在很大程度上,他们并不关心,觉得他们没有什么可以从“本地人”那里学到的。最近,经济学和犯罪学之间的分离已经开始被打破,这是一个令人鼓舞的趋势,部分可以追溯到多学科公共政策项目和智库的增长。在一本新书中,我们考察了经济学家对犯罪行为和犯罪控制研究的贡献,并确定了四个关键方面:评估刑法和犯罪预防的规范性框架。n采用复杂的数量方法来分析犯罪的原因和在这一框架内控制犯罪措施的效果。n犯罪行为是受感知后果影响的个人选择的概念。n将个人选择汇总到一个系统框架中,以了解犯罪率和模式。在动荡的20世纪60年代,美国城市发生骚乱,犯罪率和药物滥用率不断上升,国会成立了几个备受瞩目的委员会来评估潜在问题,并提出有效的改革建议。当这些委员会求助于当时著名的犯罪学家时,他们提出了自己的意见,但几乎没有相关的证据。…
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Policy Choice
A s we approach the fiftieth anniversary of Nobel laureate Gary Becker's seminal contribution (Becker, 1968), it is fair to say that the economics of crime is part of the standard portfolio that makes up the discipline. On both sides of the Atlantic, a critical mass of academic economists has specialised in the study of crime and its control. For example, a series of CEP studies has contributed to making sense of the UK's 'riddle of peacefulness' (Draca, 2013) and analysing which policies can be most effective in reducing crime (Marie, 2010). Of course, social scientific study of crime was well established by the time of Gary Becker's contribution. Prior to that, from the 1920s, the dominant disciplines were sociology and psychology, and that continued as criminology departments and schools were established in the postwar period. Becker chose to bypass rather than engage with that tradition, stating that 'a useful theory of criminal behaviour can dispense with special theories of anomie, psychological inadequacies, or inheritance of special traits and simply extend the economist's analysis of choice.' With this bit of disciplinary imperialism as a guide, subsequent contributions from economics tended to adopt the view that crime research was virgin territory. Economists were initially not so welcome in criminology and, for the most part, were unconcerned, feeling that they had little to learn from the 'natives'. More recently, that separation between economics and criminology has begun to break down, an encouraging trend that can be traced in part to the growth of multidisciplinary public-policy programmes and think-tanks. In a new book, we examine what economists have contributed to the study of criminal behaviour and crime control and identify four key strands: n A normative framework for evaluating criminal law and crime prevention. n The application of sophisticated quantitative methods to analyse the causes of crime and the effects of crime-control measures in this framework. n The conception of criminal behaviour as individual choice, influenced by perceived consequences. n The aggregation of individual choices into a systems framework for understanding crime rates and patterns. During the tumultuous years of the 1960s, with riots in US cities and escalating rates of crime and drug abuse, Congress created several high-profile commissions to assess the underlying problems and recommend effective reforms. When these commissions turned to the prominent criminologists of the day, they offered their opinions but had little in the way of relevant evidence. …
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信