赋予腐败受害者权力:沉睡的第三方受益人条款的潜力

Abiola O. Makinwa
{"title":"赋予腐败受害者权力:沉睡的第三方受益人条款的潜力","authors":"Abiola O. Makinwa","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3088964","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"This paper proposes that third-party beneficiary clauses, rights ius quaesitum tertio, can be used to create platforms for private actor intervention in the fight against corruption that can help to shape an environment that discourages corruption in a self-regulatory manner. By linking those who bear the brunt of the negative consequences of corruption to public contracts tainted by corruption, third-party beneficiary clauses would give victims of corruption a seat at the table, a right to sue and a right to be engaged in the sanctioning processes with regard to such corrupt transactions. This approach can also act as a check on the actions of government officials and corporations by increasing the risk they incur through corrupt activity. However, there are good reasons for rules of standing; the machinery of justice may break down under the weight of a multiplicity of claims or, worse, an onslaught of frivolous claims. This paper therefore proposes that it is possible to provide third party redress, while also providing mechanisms to avoid encouraging excessive litigation, through establishing a sleeping third-party beneficiary clause in procurement contracts. Such clauses remain dormant unless the third party can demonstrate evidence of corrupt activity relating to the award of a specific contract. A threshold of evidence of corruption or fraud can be defined that will trigger the clause into operation, upon which it automatically comes into effect, making the identified third-party beneficiaries parties to the contract and giving them standing to sue on the contract. Ultimately, such a clause would be most successful if the specter of direct intervention discourages corruption so effectively that the clause is in fact never triggered into operation.","PeriodicalId":129207,"journal":{"name":"Law & Society: Private Law - Contracts eJournal","volume":"1 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2016-09-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Empowering the Victims of Corruption: The Potential of Sleeping Third-Party Beneficiary Clauses\",\"authors\":\"Abiola O. Makinwa\",\"doi\":\"10.2139/ssrn.3088964\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"This paper proposes that third-party beneficiary clauses, rights ius quaesitum tertio, can be used to create platforms for private actor intervention in the fight against corruption that can help to shape an environment that discourages corruption in a self-regulatory manner. By linking those who bear the brunt of the negative consequences of corruption to public contracts tainted by corruption, third-party beneficiary clauses would give victims of corruption a seat at the table, a right to sue and a right to be engaged in the sanctioning processes with regard to such corrupt transactions. This approach can also act as a check on the actions of government officials and corporations by increasing the risk they incur through corrupt activity. However, there are good reasons for rules of standing; the machinery of justice may break down under the weight of a multiplicity of claims or, worse, an onslaught of frivolous claims. This paper therefore proposes that it is possible to provide third party redress, while also providing mechanisms to avoid encouraging excessive litigation, through establishing a sleeping third-party beneficiary clause in procurement contracts. Such clauses remain dormant unless the third party can demonstrate evidence of corrupt activity relating to the award of a specific contract. A threshold of evidence of corruption or fraud can be defined that will trigger the clause into operation, upon which it automatically comes into effect, making the identified third-party beneficiaries parties to the contract and giving them standing to sue on the contract. Ultimately, such a clause would be most successful if the specter of direct intervention discourages corruption so effectively that the clause is in fact never triggered into operation.\",\"PeriodicalId\":129207,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Law & Society: Private Law - Contracts eJournal\",\"volume\":\"1 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2016-09-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Law & Society: Private Law - Contracts eJournal\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3088964\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Law & Society: Private Law - Contracts eJournal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3088964","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

本文提出,第三方受益人条款,即准物权不受侵犯条款,可用于为私人行为者干预反腐败创造平台,从而有助于塑造一种以自律方式遏制腐败的环境。第三方受益人条款将受腐败负面后果影响最大的人与受腐败污染的公共合同联系起来,使腐败受害者有发言权,有权提起诉讼,并有权参与对此类腐败交易的制裁程序。这种方法还可以通过增加政府官员和公司因腐败活动而招致的风险来检查他们的行为。然而,制定诉讼资格规则是有充分理由的;司法机制可能会在多重索赔的重压下崩溃,或者更糟的是,在琐碎索赔的冲击下崩溃。因此,本文提出,可以通过在采购合同中设立沉睡的第三方受益人条款,在提供第三方补救的同时,提供避免鼓励过度诉讼的机制。除非第三方能够证明与授予特定合同有关的腐败行为,否则此类条款将处于休眠状态。可以确定一个腐败或欺诈证据的门槛,该门槛将触发该条款生效,并在此基础上自动生效,使已确定的第三方受益人成为合同的当事人,并赋予他们就合同提起诉讼的资格。最终,如果直接干预的幽灵能够有效地阻止腐败,以至于该条款实际上从未触发生效,那么这样的条款将是最成功的。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Empowering the Victims of Corruption: The Potential of Sleeping Third-Party Beneficiary Clauses
This paper proposes that third-party beneficiary clauses, rights ius quaesitum tertio, can be used to create platforms for private actor intervention in the fight against corruption that can help to shape an environment that discourages corruption in a self-regulatory manner. By linking those who bear the brunt of the negative consequences of corruption to public contracts tainted by corruption, third-party beneficiary clauses would give victims of corruption a seat at the table, a right to sue and a right to be engaged in the sanctioning processes with regard to such corrupt transactions. This approach can also act as a check on the actions of government officials and corporations by increasing the risk they incur through corrupt activity. However, there are good reasons for rules of standing; the machinery of justice may break down under the weight of a multiplicity of claims or, worse, an onslaught of frivolous claims. This paper therefore proposes that it is possible to provide third party redress, while also providing mechanisms to avoid encouraging excessive litigation, through establishing a sleeping third-party beneficiary clause in procurement contracts. Such clauses remain dormant unless the third party can demonstrate evidence of corrupt activity relating to the award of a specific contract. A threshold of evidence of corruption or fraud can be defined that will trigger the clause into operation, upon which it automatically comes into effect, making the identified third-party beneficiaries parties to the contract and giving them standing to sue on the contract. Ultimately, such a clause would be most successful if the specter of direct intervention discourages corruption so effectively that the clause is in fact never triggered into operation.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信