从封建主义到资本主义的过渡与时代化问题——纪念库拉诞辰100周年

Agnieszka Pufelska
{"title":"从封建主义到资本主义的过渡与时代化问题——纪念库拉诞辰100周年","authors":"Agnieszka Pufelska","doi":"10.1515/9783110492415-021","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The Marxist social historian Witold Kula (1916– 1988) demonstrated more thoroughly than any other scholar that the changes in the conditions of agricultural production also changed ‘historical time’. Kula describes the period between 1770 and 1880 as a transition zone in which an acceleration of historical time occurs because it does not yet correspond to experience. The historical process bursts open the old European continuum of experience, and the first category in which the temporal difference between experience and expectation is conceptualized is the term ‘progress’. He does not, however, consider this transition from the feudal to the capitalist movement pattern to be fluent. According to Kula, capitalism in most countries did not develop out of the feudal economy or as a consequence of gradual changes within the system, but developed above it as an autonomous system in the form of a superstructure. Stability through cyclicity In the last century, the transition from feudalism to capitalism has been the subject of a number of debates on both sides of the Atlantic. This was particularly the case in the 60s and 70s when the topic served to position economic history firmly within the historical sciences and philosophy. As part of this quest for the realignment of economic history as a field of research, some historians favorably disposed to philosophy were resolute in their insistence on the philosophical roots of the economic sciences, in an endeavor to secure a firm place for philosophy—or, to be more precise, for Marx’s philosophical categories—within historical studies (see as an example: Kittsteiner 1980). Those historians, on the other hand, who favored researching socio-economic structures endeavored to establish the economic sciences as a subdivision of social history, and to strip them of any budding historical-philosophical tendencies (cf. Wehler 1973). If one were to ask today any scholar of modern history interested or involved in these past debates whether he or she had been aware of an Eastern European position on this discussion, the answer would most certainly be in the affirmaAgnieszka Pufelska, Universität Potsdam (UP) OpenAccess. © 2018 Agnieszka Pufelska, published by De Gruyter. This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 License. https://doi.org/10.1515/9783110492415-021 Unauthenticated Download Date | 5/28/19 12:15 AM tive (in the case of Marx readers, not without a degree of cheer), and Witold Kula would be named. His books, and first and foremost his An Economic Theory of the Feudal System, were read, valued and criticized by both camps.Whereas social historians were interested in Kula’s analyses of the feudal social order, their adversaries concentrated mainly on his universal historical model of economic theory, or his dynamic functional model of the feudal economy. But who was this Polish scholar,whose feudalism theory won recognition far beyond the borders of Europe? Witold Kula was born in Warsaw in 1916 into a Protestant family of German descent. After graduating in Economics and History from the University of Warsaw, he lectured at a private university, where he defended his doctoral thesis in 1939. During the Second World War, he was a member of the Home Army and was taken prisoner by the Germans. In 1945 he returned to Poland and immediately took up his academic career. He obtained his post-doctoral degree (Habilitation) from the University of Łódź in 1947, following which he received a scholarship for two years in Paris, where he was influenced by the Annales school. Shortly after his return, he was appointed Professor at Warsaw University where he held the Chair for Economic History until 1975. By then seriously ill, he had to give up his academic teaching at the age of just 60. Witold Kula died in Warsaw on 12 February 1988. Kula’s academic work consists mainly of studies on Polish economic history, but he also worked intensively on the methodological and theoretical problems of the historical sciences. His most well known work in this field is the book that appeared in 1963 entitled The Problems and Methods of Economic History. It is in this almost 800-page work of a universalist nature that Kula most clearly formulates his methodology. He accepts, not only in a formal sense, the progressive tenets of Marxist methodology and assumes the position of Marxist periodization that is based on the development of socio-economic formations. “For the Marxists,” Kula writes, “the periodisation of history is, therefore, equally a synthesis of historical cognition and a tool thereof” (Kula 1963, p. 175). One of the central problems in Kula’s work is the question of synthesis in economic history. He emphasizes the essential differences between the courses of many economic processes in diverse social orders and draws attention to the limited comparability of these processes. The disparity between the socioeconomic systems necessitates a different methodological approach that, in turn, should result in a synthesis determined by time and space. In the most renowned of his works, the above-mentioned An Economic Theory of the Feudal System, Kula uses the Polish transition from feudalism to capitalism to describe how this research method could be applied. The book was first published in 1962 but only became known in Western Europe in the 1970s when it was translated, 288 Agnieszka Pufelska Unauthenticated Download Date | 5/28/19 12:15 AM first into French and then into English. What, in Kula’s opinion, were the conditions that such a theory should fulfill? We can say that the task of every economic theory of a system consists in formulating the laws governing the volume of the economic surplus and its utilization and that these problems have to be explained in the short-term and in the long-term. (Kula 1976, p. 27) However, in order to speak of the conclusion or the climax of an economic theory, Kula argues that it has to be able to explain the transformation of one given system into another (Kula 1976, p. 27). Clearly, Kula attempts in his feudalism research to investigate what Marx did not achieve—at least not as an independent analysis—and that he only analyzed based on what was apparent to him from the viewpoint of the emerging capitalist mode of production. It is not in vain that Kula’s temporal framework of the 16th to the 19th centuries covers Marx’s history of ‘primitive accumulation’, i.e. the history of the separation of the direct producers from their means of production and nourishment, which was for Marx the core of the history of the transition from feudalism to capitalism.1 In Kula’s historical reconstruction, the first signs of economic decline in Poland are evident in the 16th century, otherwise seen as the ‘golden century’, characterized by economic, cultural and political development. Kula sees the causes for this in the strengthening of serfdom and the corresponding increase in the power of the nobility. Their high standard of living was supported by an economy that guaranteed Poland the position of a European granary and enabled the aristocracy to import luxury goods from abroad. Whilst the aristocracy thus had close connections with the international market, also through the ‘term of trade’, the peasants remained excluded and increasingly tied to feudal dependencies. This process reached its climax in the so-called ‘crisis of the 17th century’, which was heightened in Poland by external influences such as the wars against the Cossacks and Sweden. The country fell into a state of economic backwardness characterized by a concentration of land ownership in the form of estates ruled by the wealthy nobility. All types of feudal dues, both ordinary and extraordinary, were fully developed and the peasants’ obligations had become very oppressive. An analysis of surviving invoices showing income and expenditure of several feudal estates led Kula to conclude that, when considering only monetary expenditure and income,  Marx writes: “The economic structure of capitalist society has grown out of the economic structure of feudal society. The dissolution of the latter set free the elements of the former.” (Marx 1972, p. 743.) The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism 289 Unauthenticated Download Date | 5/28/19 12:15 AM these estates must have produced a substantial yield, but that if the material effort (not measured in terms of money) in the form of corvées obligations was calculated into this, the result would be a large deficit: “The average peasant does not take into account the cost of family labor nor interest on capital because he has not knowledge of such categories and does not know how to make accurate calculations” (Kula 1976, p. 41). The farms were inefficient without knowing it. In Kula’s opinion, this is not simply an invoicing problem: he derives from it a ‘two-sector system’, i.e. the side-by-side existence of a monetary and a natural economy. The peasants who belonged to the nobility had to pay them dues, mostly as payment in kind, but they were also obliged to perform certain services for the nobility. The activities of the noble landowners on the other hand, were oriented around a market where they exchanged the peasants’ dues for money, such that their calculations were focused on increasing income from the manorial estate. Under manorial rule, the production of commodities was successfully developed: the ruling class used their privileges to secure cheap labor power, raw materials and advantages in selling their goods. The feudal lords were thus able to make good use of the economic advantages of peasant agriculture; that is, of low labor costs, high labor intensity and low unproductive expenses. The lower the intensity and productivity of agricultural labor, the more the manorial lords attempted to reduce production costs by increasing feudal labor obligations. Feudal labor service reduced production and tr","PeriodicalId":126664,"journal":{"name":"Philosophy of Globalization","volume":"29 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2018-06-11","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism and the Problem of Temporalization—on the 100th Anniversary of Witold Kula’s Birth\",\"authors\":\"Agnieszka Pufelska\",\"doi\":\"10.1515/9783110492415-021\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"The Marxist social historian Witold Kula (1916– 1988) demonstrated more thoroughly than any other scholar that the changes in the conditions of agricultural production also changed ‘historical time’. Kula describes the period between 1770 and 1880 as a transition zone in which an acceleration of historical time occurs because it does not yet correspond to experience. The historical process bursts open the old European continuum of experience, and the first category in which the temporal difference between experience and expectation is conceptualized is the term ‘progress’. He does not, however, consider this transition from the feudal to the capitalist movement pattern to be fluent. According to Kula, capitalism in most countries did not develop out of the feudal economy or as a consequence of gradual changes within the system, but developed above it as an autonomous system in the form of a superstructure. Stability through cyclicity In the last century, the transition from feudalism to capitalism has been the subject of a number of debates on both sides of the Atlantic. This was particularly the case in the 60s and 70s when the topic served to position economic history firmly within the historical sciences and philosophy. As part of this quest for the realignment of economic history as a field of research, some historians favorably disposed to philosophy were resolute in their insistence on the philosophical roots of the economic sciences, in an endeavor to secure a firm place for philosophy—or, to be more precise, for Marx’s philosophical categories—within historical studies (see as an example: Kittsteiner 1980). Those historians, on the other hand, who favored researching socio-economic structures endeavored to establish the economic sciences as a subdivision of social history, and to strip them of any budding historical-philosophical tendencies (cf. Wehler 1973). If one were to ask today any scholar of modern history interested or involved in these past debates whether he or she had been aware of an Eastern European position on this discussion, the answer would most certainly be in the affirmaAgnieszka Pufelska, Universität Potsdam (UP) OpenAccess. © 2018 Agnieszka Pufelska, published by De Gruyter. This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 License. https://doi.org/10.1515/9783110492415-021 Unauthenticated Download Date | 5/28/19 12:15 AM tive (in the case of Marx readers, not without a degree of cheer), and Witold Kula would be named. His books, and first and foremost his An Economic Theory of the Feudal System, were read, valued and criticized by both camps.Whereas social historians were interested in Kula’s analyses of the feudal social order, their adversaries concentrated mainly on his universal historical model of economic theory, or his dynamic functional model of the feudal economy. But who was this Polish scholar,whose feudalism theory won recognition far beyond the borders of Europe? Witold Kula was born in Warsaw in 1916 into a Protestant family of German descent. After graduating in Economics and History from the University of Warsaw, he lectured at a private university, where he defended his doctoral thesis in 1939. During the Second World War, he was a member of the Home Army and was taken prisoner by the Germans. In 1945 he returned to Poland and immediately took up his academic career. He obtained his post-doctoral degree (Habilitation) from the University of Łódź in 1947, following which he received a scholarship for two years in Paris, where he was influenced by the Annales school. Shortly after his return, he was appointed Professor at Warsaw University where he held the Chair for Economic History until 1975. By then seriously ill, he had to give up his academic teaching at the age of just 60. Witold Kula died in Warsaw on 12 February 1988. Kula’s academic work consists mainly of studies on Polish economic history, but he also worked intensively on the methodological and theoretical problems of the historical sciences. His most well known work in this field is the book that appeared in 1963 entitled The Problems and Methods of Economic History. It is in this almost 800-page work of a universalist nature that Kula most clearly formulates his methodology. He accepts, not only in a formal sense, the progressive tenets of Marxist methodology and assumes the position of Marxist periodization that is based on the development of socio-economic formations. “For the Marxists,” Kula writes, “the periodisation of history is, therefore, equally a synthesis of historical cognition and a tool thereof” (Kula 1963, p. 175). One of the central problems in Kula’s work is the question of synthesis in economic history. He emphasizes the essential differences between the courses of many economic processes in diverse social orders and draws attention to the limited comparability of these processes. The disparity between the socioeconomic systems necessitates a different methodological approach that, in turn, should result in a synthesis determined by time and space. In the most renowned of his works, the above-mentioned An Economic Theory of the Feudal System, Kula uses the Polish transition from feudalism to capitalism to describe how this research method could be applied. The book was first published in 1962 but only became known in Western Europe in the 1970s when it was translated, 288 Agnieszka Pufelska Unauthenticated Download Date | 5/28/19 12:15 AM first into French and then into English. What, in Kula’s opinion, were the conditions that such a theory should fulfill? We can say that the task of every economic theory of a system consists in formulating the laws governing the volume of the economic surplus and its utilization and that these problems have to be explained in the short-term and in the long-term. (Kula 1976, p. 27) However, in order to speak of the conclusion or the climax of an economic theory, Kula argues that it has to be able to explain the transformation of one given system into another (Kula 1976, p. 27). Clearly, Kula attempts in his feudalism research to investigate what Marx did not achieve—at least not as an independent analysis—and that he only analyzed based on what was apparent to him from the viewpoint of the emerging capitalist mode of production. It is not in vain that Kula’s temporal framework of the 16th to the 19th centuries covers Marx’s history of ‘primitive accumulation’, i.e. the history of the separation of the direct producers from their means of production and nourishment, which was for Marx the core of the history of the transition from feudalism to capitalism.1 In Kula’s historical reconstruction, the first signs of economic decline in Poland are evident in the 16th century, otherwise seen as the ‘golden century’, characterized by economic, cultural and political development. Kula sees the causes for this in the strengthening of serfdom and the corresponding increase in the power of the nobility. Their high standard of living was supported by an economy that guaranteed Poland the position of a European granary and enabled the aristocracy to import luxury goods from abroad. Whilst the aristocracy thus had close connections with the international market, also through the ‘term of trade’, the peasants remained excluded and increasingly tied to feudal dependencies. This process reached its climax in the so-called ‘crisis of the 17th century’, which was heightened in Poland by external influences such as the wars against the Cossacks and Sweden. The country fell into a state of economic backwardness characterized by a concentration of land ownership in the form of estates ruled by the wealthy nobility. All types of feudal dues, both ordinary and extraordinary, were fully developed and the peasants’ obligations had become very oppressive. An analysis of surviving invoices showing income and expenditure of several feudal estates led Kula to conclude that, when considering only monetary expenditure and income,  Marx writes: “The economic structure of capitalist society has grown out of the economic structure of feudal society. The dissolution of the latter set free the elements of the former.” (Marx 1972, p. 743.) The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism 289 Unauthenticated Download Date | 5/28/19 12:15 AM these estates must have produced a substantial yield, but that if the material effort (not measured in terms of money) in the form of corvées obligations was calculated into this, the result would be a large deficit: “The average peasant does not take into account the cost of family labor nor interest on capital because he has not knowledge of such categories and does not know how to make accurate calculations” (Kula 1976, p. 41). The farms were inefficient without knowing it. In Kula’s opinion, this is not simply an invoicing problem: he derives from it a ‘two-sector system’, i.e. the side-by-side existence of a monetary and a natural economy. The peasants who belonged to the nobility had to pay them dues, mostly as payment in kind, but they were also obliged to perform certain services for the nobility. The activities of the noble landowners on the other hand, were oriented around a market where they exchanged the peasants’ dues for money, such that their calculations were focused on increasing income from the manorial estate. Under manorial rule, the production of commodities was successfully developed: the ruling class used their privileges to secure cheap labor power, raw materials and advantages in selling their goods. The feudal lords were thus able to make good use of the economic advantages of peasant agriculture; that is, of low labor costs, high labor intensity and low unproductive expenses. The lower the intensity and productivity of agricultural labor, the more the manorial lords attempted to reduce production costs by increasing feudal labor obligations. Feudal labor service reduced production and tr\",\"PeriodicalId\":126664,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Philosophy of Globalization\",\"volume\":\"29 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2018-06-11\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"1\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Philosophy of Globalization\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1515/9783110492415-021\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Philosophy of Globalization","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1515/9783110492415-021","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

摘要

马克思主义社会历史学家维托尔德·库拉(1916 - 1988)比其他任何学者都更彻底地证明了农业生产条件的变化也改变了“历史时间”。库拉把1770年到1880年这段时间描述为一个过渡时期,在这个时期,历史时间的加速发生了,因为它还不符合经验。历史进程打开了旧欧洲经验的连续统一体,经验和期望之间的时间差异被概念化的第一个范畴是“进步”一词。然而,他并不认为这种从封建到资本主义运动模式的转变是流畅的。根据库拉的观点,大多数国家的资本主义不是从封建经济中发展出来的,也不是作为制度内部逐渐变化的结果,而是作为一种上层建筑形式的自治制度在其之上发展起来的。在上个世纪,从封建主义到资本主义的过渡一直是大西洋两岸许多辩论的主题。这在60年代和70年代尤其如此,当时这个话题将经济史牢牢地置于历史科学和哲学之中。作为重新调整经济史作为研究领域的一部分,一些倾向于哲学的历史学家坚决坚持经济科学的哲学根源,努力为哲学——或者更准确地说,为马克思的哲学范畴——在历史研究中争取一个稳固的地位(见一个例子:Kittsteiner 1980)。另一方面,那些倾向于研究社会经济结构的历史学家努力将经济科学建立为社会历史的一个分支,并剥离任何萌芽的历史哲学倾向(参见Wehler 1973)。如果今天有人问任何对这些过去的争论感兴趣或参与其中的近代史学者,他或她是否意识到东欧在这一讨论中的立场,答案肯定是肯定的agnieszka Pufelska, Universität波茨坦(UP) OpenAccess。©2018 Agnieszka Pufelska, De Gruyter出版。本作品采用知识共享署名-非商业-非衍生品4.0许可协议。https://doi.org/10.1515/9783110492415-021未经确认的下载日期| 5/28/19 12:15 AM tive(在马克思读者的情况下,不是没有一定程度的欢呼),和Witold Kula将被命名。他的书,首先是他的《封建制度经济理论》,被两个阵营阅读、评价和批评。社会历史学家对库拉对封建社会秩序的分析感兴趣,而他们的对手则主要关注他的经济理论的普遍历史模型,或者他的封建经济的动态功能模型。但是,这位波兰学者是谁,他的封建主义理论赢得了远在欧洲边界之外的认可?维托尔德·库拉1916年出生于华沙的一个德裔新教家庭。从华沙大学(University of Warsaw)经济学和历史系毕业后,他在一所私立大学任教,并于1939年在那里完成了博士论文答辩。在第二次世界大战期间,他是本土军的一员,被德国人俘虏。1945年,他回到波兰,立即开始了他的学术生涯。1947年,他在Łódź大学获得博士后学位(Habilitation),之后他在巴黎获得了两年的奖学金,在那里他受到了Annales学校的影响。回国后不久,他被任命为华沙大学教授,在那里担任经济史教授,直到1975年。那时他身患重病,不得不在年仅60岁时放弃学术教学。维托尔德·库拉于1988年2月12日在华沙去世。库拉的学术工作主要包括对波兰经济史的研究,但他也对历史科学的方法论和理论问题进行了深入研究。他在这一领域最著名的著作是1963年出版的《经济史的问题和方法》。正是在这本近800页的普遍主义著作中,库拉最清晰地阐述了他的方法论。他不仅在形式上接受了马克思主义方法论的进步原则,而且接受了基于社会经济形态发展的马克思主义分期的立场。“对马克思主义者来说,”库拉写道,“因此,历史的分期同样是历史认识的综合及其工具”(库拉1963,第175页)。库拉著作的核心问题之一是经济史中的综合问题。他强调了不同社会秩序中许多经济过程的本质差异,并提请注意这些过程的有限可比性。 农业劳动的强度和生产率越低,庄园领主就越想通过增加封建劳动义务来降低生产成本。封建的劳动制度减少了生产和贸易
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism and the Problem of Temporalization—on the 100th Anniversary of Witold Kula’s Birth
The Marxist social historian Witold Kula (1916– 1988) demonstrated more thoroughly than any other scholar that the changes in the conditions of agricultural production also changed ‘historical time’. Kula describes the period between 1770 and 1880 as a transition zone in which an acceleration of historical time occurs because it does not yet correspond to experience. The historical process bursts open the old European continuum of experience, and the first category in which the temporal difference between experience and expectation is conceptualized is the term ‘progress’. He does not, however, consider this transition from the feudal to the capitalist movement pattern to be fluent. According to Kula, capitalism in most countries did not develop out of the feudal economy or as a consequence of gradual changes within the system, but developed above it as an autonomous system in the form of a superstructure. Stability through cyclicity In the last century, the transition from feudalism to capitalism has been the subject of a number of debates on both sides of the Atlantic. This was particularly the case in the 60s and 70s when the topic served to position economic history firmly within the historical sciences and philosophy. As part of this quest for the realignment of economic history as a field of research, some historians favorably disposed to philosophy were resolute in their insistence on the philosophical roots of the economic sciences, in an endeavor to secure a firm place for philosophy—or, to be more precise, for Marx’s philosophical categories—within historical studies (see as an example: Kittsteiner 1980). Those historians, on the other hand, who favored researching socio-economic structures endeavored to establish the economic sciences as a subdivision of social history, and to strip them of any budding historical-philosophical tendencies (cf. Wehler 1973). If one were to ask today any scholar of modern history interested or involved in these past debates whether he or she had been aware of an Eastern European position on this discussion, the answer would most certainly be in the affirmaAgnieszka Pufelska, Universität Potsdam (UP) OpenAccess. © 2018 Agnieszka Pufelska, published by De Gruyter. This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 License. https://doi.org/10.1515/9783110492415-021 Unauthenticated Download Date | 5/28/19 12:15 AM tive (in the case of Marx readers, not without a degree of cheer), and Witold Kula would be named. His books, and first and foremost his An Economic Theory of the Feudal System, were read, valued and criticized by both camps.Whereas social historians were interested in Kula’s analyses of the feudal social order, their adversaries concentrated mainly on his universal historical model of economic theory, or his dynamic functional model of the feudal economy. But who was this Polish scholar,whose feudalism theory won recognition far beyond the borders of Europe? Witold Kula was born in Warsaw in 1916 into a Protestant family of German descent. After graduating in Economics and History from the University of Warsaw, he lectured at a private university, where he defended his doctoral thesis in 1939. During the Second World War, he was a member of the Home Army and was taken prisoner by the Germans. In 1945 he returned to Poland and immediately took up his academic career. He obtained his post-doctoral degree (Habilitation) from the University of Łódź in 1947, following which he received a scholarship for two years in Paris, where he was influenced by the Annales school. Shortly after his return, he was appointed Professor at Warsaw University where he held the Chair for Economic History until 1975. By then seriously ill, he had to give up his academic teaching at the age of just 60. Witold Kula died in Warsaw on 12 February 1988. Kula’s academic work consists mainly of studies on Polish economic history, but he also worked intensively on the methodological and theoretical problems of the historical sciences. His most well known work in this field is the book that appeared in 1963 entitled The Problems and Methods of Economic History. It is in this almost 800-page work of a universalist nature that Kula most clearly formulates his methodology. He accepts, not only in a formal sense, the progressive tenets of Marxist methodology and assumes the position of Marxist periodization that is based on the development of socio-economic formations. “For the Marxists,” Kula writes, “the periodisation of history is, therefore, equally a synthesis of historical cognition and a tool thereof” (Kula 1963, p. 175). One of the central problems in Kula’s work is the question of synthesis in economic history. He emphasizes the essential differences between the courses of many economic processes in diverse social orders and draws attention to the limited comparability of these processes. The disparity between the socioeconomic systems necessitates a different methodological approach that, in turn, should result in a synthesis determined by time and space. In the most renowned of his works, the above-mentioned An Economic Theory of the Feudal System, Kula uses the Polish transition from feudalism to capitalism to describe how this research method could be applied. The book was first published in 1962 but only became known in Western Europe in the 1970s when it was translated, 288 Agnieszka Pufelska Unauthenticated Download Date | 5/28/19 12:15 AM first into French and then into English. What, in Kula’s opinion, were the conditions that such a theory should fulfill? We can say that the task of every economic theory of a system consists in formulating the laws governing the volume of the economic surplus and its utilization and that these problems have to be explained in the short-term and in the long-term. (Kula 1976, p. 27) However, in order to speak of the conclusion or the climax of an economic theory, Kula argues that it has to be able to explain the transformation of one given system into another (Kula 1976, p. 27). Clearly, Kula attempts in his feudalism research to investigate what Marx did not achieve—at least not as an independent analysis—and that he only analyzed based on what was apparent to him from the viewpoint of the emerging capitalist mode of production. It is not in vain that Kula’s temporal framework of the 16th to the 19th centuries covers Marx’s history of ‘primitive accumulation’, i.e. the history of the separation of the direct producers from their means of production and nourishment, which was for Marx the core of the history of the transition from feudalism to capitalism.1 In Kula’s historical reconstruction, the first signs of economic decline in Poland are evident in the 16th century, otherwise seen as the ‘golden century’, characterized by economic, cultural and political development. Kula sees the causes for this in the strengthening of serfdom and the corresponding increase in the power of the nobility. Their high standard of living was supported by an economy that guaranteed Poland the position of a European granary and enabled the aristocracy to import luxury goods from abroad. Whilst the aristocracy thus had close connections with the international market, also through the ‘term of trade’, the peasants remained excluded and increasingly tied to feudal dependencies. This process reached its climax in the so-called ‘crisis of the 17th century’, which was heightened in Poland by external influences such as the wars against the Cossacks and Sweden. The country fell into a state of economic backwardness characterized by a concentration of land ownership in the form of estates ruled by the wealthy nobility. All types of feudal dues, both ordinary and extraordinary, were fully developed and the peasants’ obligations had become very oppressive. An analysis of surviving invoices showing income and expenditure of several feudal estates led Kula to conclude that, when considering only monetary expenditure and income,  Marx writes: “The economic structure of capitalist society has grown out of the economic structure of feudal society. The dissolution of the latter set free the elements of the former.” (Marx 1972, p. 743.) The Transition from Feudalism to Capitalism 289 Unauthenticated Download Date | 5/28/19 12:15 AM these estates must have produced a substantial yield, but that if the material effort (not measured in terms of money) in the form of corvées obligations was calculated into this, the result would be a large deficit: “The average peasant does not take into account the cost of family labor nor interest on capital because he has not knowledge of such categories and does not know how to make accurate calculations” (Kula 1976, p. 41). The farms were inefficient without knowing it. In Kula’s opinion, this is not simply an invoicing problem: he derives from it a ‘two-sector system’, i.e. the side-by-side existence of a monetary and a natural economy. The peasants who belonged to the nobility had to pay them dues, mostly as payment in kind, but they were also obliged to perform certain services for the nobility. The activities of the noble landowners on the other hand, were oriented around a market where they exchanged the peasants’ dues for money, such that their calculations were focused on increasing income from the manorial estate. Under manorial rule, the production of commodities was successfully developed: the ruling class used their privileges to secure cheap labor power, raw materials and advantages in selling their goods. The feudal lords were thus able to make good use of the economic advantages of peasant agriculture; that is, of low labor costs, high labor intensity and low unproductive expenses. The lower the intensity and productivity of agricultural labor, the more the manorial lords attempted to reduce production costs by increasing feudal labor obligations. Feudal labor service reduced production and tr
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信