部落与气质:市场行动者行为、动机与信念的两个未被充分认识的决定因素

C. Hill
{"title":"部落与气质:市场行动者行为、动机与信念的两个未被充分认识的决定因素","authors":"C. Hill","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3876431","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"This chapter, written for a volume on Hidden Fallacies in Corporate Law and Financial Regulation, argues that markets and market actors can be better understood by taking into account some neglected determinants of behavior, motivations and beliefs -- and ultimately, by embracing an expanded view of rationality. The neglected determinants are tribes, by which I mean communities with their own norms, rituals, and institutions, and temperament, which I use in its colloquial sense. Deal makers, for instance, can be said to have a community, with norms as to, among other things, ‘what’s market.” Knowing and abiding by the norms conveys information about a person’s willingness and ability to function as a member of the community. The community anoints certain experts who pass muster as experts for purposes of community judgments. Interestingly, the status as anointed expert can be sticky notwithstanding significant disconfirming evidence, as demonstrated by the continuing high market shares of the major rating agencies. Temperament figures in when a less confident investor, even a “sophisticated” institutional investor, rushes to buy “a hot new issue” because it is hot, notwithstanding ample cautionary disclosure. Temperament also figures in when a banker designs a financial instrument or sales strategy that honors the letter of the law while arguably violating its spirit. The chapter discusses temperament on two different dimensions: greater or lesser degrees of confidence in one’s own judgments, including, at the extremes, the least confident and the contrarians, and “regulatory focus,” a concept developed by psychologist and business school professor Tory Higgins, which distinguishes “prevention” focus (more vigilant, hate to lose) from “promotion” focus (less vigilant, love to win). My arguments succeed, or not, by persuasion rather than proof – it’s not clear what proof would look like in any event. Certainly, the personality types I describe are well-known, in the literature and in real life, as are, at some level of generality, the social dynamics I describe, such as herding, and the existence of market communities, broadly construed, that have norms, rituals and institutions. My burden is more to show that taking tribes and temperament into account in analyses of market behavior is feasible and desirable, and that not doing so unnecessarily sacrifices realism. Since around the mid-‘90s, there has been a push to make economics, and law and economics, more realistic. Exploring the neglect of tribes and temperament and how this could be remedied can be an effective means of doing so: rather than characterizing ways in which people are less rational than law and economics assumes them to be, law and economics can instead reconceive what rationality requires. The re-conception of rationality should, in my view, be radical as to economics’ ontology but not as to its conceptual toolbox. Underlying the standard economics worldview is a metaphorical or perhaps literal acceptance of the credo ‘survival of the fittest.’ But an alternative view, advanced by philosopher Daniel Milo, ‘survival of the good enough,’ seems far more plausible. Without the specter of extinction, many more courses of action become viable. Of course, if we try to fully capture the nuances, we will lose all possibility of a tractable theory. But we can do far better than we do now, by taking into account three things: that we live in a world of uncertainty (“unknown unknowns”), not just risk; that our cognitive capacity is limited; and that how people react to uncertainty and cognitive limitations turns on who they are and how they view themselves.","PeriodicalId":448402,"journal":{"name":"Corporate Governance & Sociology or Psychology eJournal","volume":"36 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2021-05-28","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Tribes and Temperament: Two Underappreciated Determinants of Market Actor Behavior, Motivations and Beliefs\",\"authors\":\"C. Hill\",\"doi\":\"10.2139/ssrn.3876431\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"This chapter, written for a volume on Hidden Fallacies in Corporate Law and Financial Regulation, argues that markets and market actors can be better understood by taking into account some neglected determinants of behavior, motivations and beliefs -- and ultimately, by embracing an expanded view of rationality. The neglected determinants are tribes, by which I mean communities with their own norms, rituals, and institutions, and temperament, which I use in its colloquial sense. Deal makers, for instance, can be said to have a community, with norms as to, among other things, ‘what’s market.” Knowing and abiding by the norms conveys information about a person’s willingness and ability to function as a member of the community. The community anoints certain experts who pass muster as experts for purposes of community judgments. Interestingly, the status as anointed expert can be sticky notwithstanding significant disconfirming evidence, as demonstrated by the continuing high market shares of the major rating agencies. Temperament figures in when a less confident investor, even a “sophisticated” institutional investor, rushes to buy “a hot new issue” because it is hot, notwithstanding ample cautionary disclosure. Temperament also figures in when a banker designs a financial instrument or sales strategy that honors the letter of the law while arguably violating its spirit. The chapter discusses temperament on two different dimensions: greater or lesser degrees of confidence in one’s own judgments, including, at the extremes, the least confident and the contrarians, and “regulatory focus,” a concept developed by psychologist and business school professor Tory Higgins, which distinguishes “prevention” focus (more vigilant, hate to lose) from “promotion” focus (less vigilant, love to win). My arguments succeed, or not, by persuasion rather than proof – it’s not clear what proof would look like in any event. Certainly, the personality types I describe are well-known, in the literature and in real life, as are, at some level of generality, the social dynamics I describe, such as herding, and the existence of market communities, broadly construed, that have norms, rituals and institutions. My burden is more to show that taking tribes and temperament into account in analyses of market behavior is feasible and desirable, and that not doing so unnecessarily sacrifices realism. Since around the mid-‘90s, there has been a push to make economics, and law and economics, more realistic. Exploring the neglect of tribes and temperament and how this could be remedied can be an effective means of doing so: rather than characterizing ways in which people are less rational than law and economics assumes them to be, law and economics can instead reconceive what rationality requires. The re-conception of rationality should, in my view, be radical as to economics’ ontology but not as to its conceptual toolbox. Underlying the standard economics worldview is a metaphorical or perhaps literal acceptance of the credo ‘survival of the fittest.’ But an alternative view, advanced by philosopher Daniel Milo, ‘survival of the good enough,’ seems far more plausible. Without the specter of extinction, many more courses of action become viable. Of course, if we try to fully capture the nuances, we will lose all possibility of a tractable theory. But we can do far better than we do now, by taking into account three things: that we live in a world of uncertainty (“unknown unknowns”), not just risk; that our cognitive capacity is limited; and that how people react to uncertainty and cognitive limitations turns on who they are and how they view themselves.\",\"PeriodicalId\":448402,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Corporate Governance & Sociology or Psychology eJournal\",\"volume\":\"36 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2021-05-28\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Corporate Governance & Sociology or Psychology eJournal\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3876431\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Corporate Governance & Sociology or Psychology eJournal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3876431","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

这一章是为《公司法和金融监管中的隐藏谬误》一书而写的,它认为,如果考虑到一些被忽视的行为、动机和信念的决定因素,并最终接受一种扩展的理性观点,就可以更好地理解市场和市场参与者。被忽视的决定因素是部落,我指的是有自己的规范、仪式、制度和气质的社区,我用的是口语。例如,交易撮合者可以说有一个社区,在“什么是市场”等问题上,他们都有自己的规范。了解并遵守规范传达了一个人作为社区成员的意愿和能力的信息。为了社区判断的目的,社区指定某些通过审查的专家为专家。有趣的是,尽管有大量不确定的证据,但被指定为专家的地位可能是粘性的,主要评级机构的持续高市场份额就证明了这一点。当一个不那么自信的投资者,甚至是一个“老练的”机构投资者,因为“热门新股”很热门而急于购买它时,性情就会发挥作用,尽管有大量的警告性信息披露。当银行家设计一种金融工具或销售策略时,气质也会发挥作用,这种金融工具或销售策略既遵守法律条文,又有可能违反法律精神。这一章从两个不同的维度讨论了气质:对自己判断的信心程度,极端情况下包括最不自信和逆势而为的人,以及“监管焦点”,这是由心理学家、商学院教授托里·希金斯(Tory Higgins)提出的概念,它将“预防”焦点(更加警惕,讨厌失败)与“促进”焦点(不那么警惕,喜欢胜利)区分开来。我的论点成功与否,靠的是说服而不是证明——在任何情况下,证明是什么样子都不清楚。当然,我所描述的人格类型在文学作品和现实生活中都是众所周知的,在某种程度上,我所描述的社会动态也很普遍,比如羊群,以及市场社区的存在,广义上讲,它们有规范、仪式和制度。我的责任更多是要说明,在分析市场行为时,把部落和性情考虑进去是可行的,也是可取的,不这样做就不必要地牺牲了现实主义。自上世纪90年代中期以来,一直有一股推动经济学、法律和经济学变得更加现实的力量。探索对部落和气质的忽视,以及如何补救,可能是一种有效的方法:与其描述人们在哪些方面不如法律和经济学所假设的那样理性,不如法律和经济学来重新思考理性需要什么。在我看来,理性的重新定义应该是对经济学本体论的激进,而不是对其概念工具箱的激进。标准经济学世界观的基础是对“适者生存”信条的隐喻性或字面上的接受。但哲学家米洛(Daniel Milo)提出的另一种观点“适者生存”似乎更有道理。没有了灭绝的幽灵,更多的行动方案变得可行。当然,如果我们试图完全捕捉细微差别,我们将失去所有可处理理论的可能性。但我们可以做得比现在好得多,只要考虑到三件事:我们生活在一个不确定的世界(“未知的未知”),而不仅仅是风险;我们的认知能力是有限的;人们对不确定性和认知限制的反应取决于他们是谁以及他们如何看待自己。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Tribes and Temperament: Two Underappreciated Determinants of Market Actor Behavior, Motivations and Beliefs
This chapter, written for a volume on Hidden Fallacies in Corporate Law and Financial Regulation, argues that markets and market actors can be better understood by taking into account some neglected determinants of behavior, motivations and beliefs -- and ultimately, by embracing an expanded view of rationality. The neglected determinants are tribes, by which I mean communities with their own norms, rituals, and institutions, and temperament, which I use in its colloquial sense. Deal makers, for instance, can be said to have a community, with norms as to, among other things, ‘what’s market.” Knowing and abiding by the norms conveys information about a person’s willingness and ability to function as a member of the community. The community anoints certain experts who pass muster as experts for purposes of community judgments. Interestingly, the status as anointed expert can be sticky notwithstanding significant disconfirming evidence, as demonstrated by the continuing high market shares of the major rating agencies. Temperament figures in when a less confident investor, even a “sophisticated” institutional investor, rushes to buy “a hot new issue” because it is hot, notwithstanding ample cautionary disclosure. Temperament also figures in when a banker designs a financial instrument or sales strategy that honors the letter of the law while arguably violating its spirit. The chapter discusses temperament on two different dimensions: greater or lesser degrees of confidence in one’s own judgments, including, at the extremes, the least confident and the contrarians, and “regulatory focus,” a concept developed by psychologist and business school professor Tory Higgins, which distinguishes “prevention” focus (more vigilant, hate to lose) from “promotion” focus (less vigilant, love to win). My arguments succeed, or not, by persuasion rather than proof – it’s not clear what proof would look like in any event. Certainly, the personality types I describe are well-known, in the literature and in real life, as are, at some level of generality, the social dynamics I describe, such as herding, and the existence of market communities, broadly construed, that have norms, rituals and institutions. My burden is more to show that taking tribes and temperament into account in analyses of market behavior is feasible and desirable, and that not doing so unnecessarily sacrifices realism. Since around the mid-‘90s, there has been a push to make economics, and law and economics, more realistic. Exploring the neglect of tribes and temperament and how this could be remedied can be an effective means of doing so: rather than characterizing ways in which people are less rational than law and economics assumes them to be, law and economics can instead reconceive what rationality requires. The re-conception of rationality should, in my view, be radical as to economics’ ontology but not as to its conceptual toolbox. Underlying the standard economics worldview is a metaphorical or perhaps literal acceptance of the credo ‘survival of the fittest.’ But an alternative view, advanced by philosopher Daniel Milo, ‘survival of the good enough,’ seems far more plausible. Without the specter of extinction, many more courses of action become viable. Of course, if we try to fully capture the nuances, we will lose all possibility of a tractable theory. But we can do far better than we do now, by taking into account three things: that we live in a world of uncertainty (“unknown unknowns”), not just risk; that our cognitive capacity is limited; and that how people react to uncertainty and cognitive limitations turns on who they are and how they view themselves.
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信