评论

George M. von Furstenberg
{"title":"评论","authors":"George M. von Furstenberg","doi":"10.1086/596008","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Bergin and Lin pick up a venerable distinction that, poorly represented with disaggregated trade data now accessible, has become the dernier cri of trade theory. The general issue of the new literature is what influences the division into intensive and extensive margin of the growth of a country’s share in the global exports going to another country. The specific issue raised in a subset of papers like the one here that is of interest is how, and then why, that division is influenced by the exchange rate regime between pairs of countries. This comment first conveys the essence of the historical distinction and then shows how the data currently used fail to reflect that distinction. This raises the question of what a contemporary implementation of the classical concept, largely preserved in Bergin and Lin’s model but not in its empirical implementation, could imply. It then discusses the absence of substantial uncertainty about future real exchange rates in the model, which detracts from the paper’s main theme. Other aspects that are crucial to the industrial organization of cross‐border trade, such as foreign direct investment (FDI) and trade in components, also are missing from the model. This makes it difficult to test hypotheses with it or to account for its findings. One crude validation test could be to check on the growth of trade shares for Canada and Mexico with the United States since the Canada‐ U.S. Free Trade Agreement 1988 or the NAFTA (North American Free Trade Agreement) 1994 and examine how this growth has been divided between the extensive and intensivemargins. My hunch is that the expansion of the bilateral trade shares of these countries is about as large and as concentrated at the extensive margin as Bergin and Lin estimated for","PeriodicalId":353207,"journal":{"name":"NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics","volume":"26 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2009-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Comment\",\"authors\":\"George M. von Furstenberg\",\"doi\":\"10.1086/596008\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"Bergin and Lin pick up a venerable distinction that, poorly represented with disaggregated trade data now accessible, has become the dernier cri of trade theory. The general issue of the new literature is what influences the division into intensive and extensive margin of the growth of a country’s share in the global exports going to another country. The specific issue raised in a subset of papers like the one here that is of interest is how, and then why, that division is influenced by the exchange rate regime between pairs of countries. This comment first conveys the essence of the historical distinction and then shows how the data currently used fail to reflect that distinction. This raises the question of what a contemporary implementation of the classical concept, largely preserved in Bergin and Lin’s model but not in its empirical implementation, could imply. It then discusses the absence of substantial uncertainty about future real exchange rates in the model, which detracts from the paper’s main theme. Other aspects that are crucial to the industrial organization of cross‐border trade, such as foreign direct investment (FDI) and trade in components, also are missing from the model. This makes it difficult to test hypotheses with it or to account for its findings. One crude validation test could be to check on the growth of trade shares for Canada and Mexico with the United States since the Canada‐ U.S. Free Trade Agreement 1988 or the NAFTA (North American Free Trade Agreement) 1994 and examine how this growth has been divided between the extensive and intensivemargins. My hunch is that the expansion of the bilateral trade shares of these countries is about as large and as concentrated at the extensive margin as Bergin and Lin estimated for\",\"PeriodicalId\":353207,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics\",\"volume\":\"26 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2009-01-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"0\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.1086/596008\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1086/596008","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

摘要

Bergin和Lin提出了一个值得尊敬的区别,这一区别在目前可获得的分类贸易数据中表现不佳,已成为贸易理论的最重要的特征。新文献的一般问题是,是什么影响了一个国家对另一个国家的全球出口份额增长的集约边际和外延边际的划分。在像本文这样的论文中提出的具体问题是,这种划分是如何以及为什么受到两国之间汇率制度的影响的。这一评论首先传达了历史区别的本质,然后展示了当前使用的数据如何未能反映这种区别。这就提出了一个问题,古典概念的当代实施,在很大程度上保留在Bergin和Lin的模型中,但不是在其经验实施中,可能意味着什么。然后,它讨论了模型中对未来实际汇率缺乏实质性不确定性,这偏离了本文的主题。其他对跨境贸易的产业组织至关重要的方面,如外国直接投资(FDI)和零部件贸易,也在模型中缺失。这使得用它来检验假设或解释其发现变得困难。一个粗略的验证测试可以是检查自1988年加拿大-美国自由贸易协定或1994年北美自由贸易协定(NAFTA)以来加拿大和墨西哥与美国的贸易份额增长情况,并检查这种增长是如何在粗放型和集约型利润之间划分的。我的直觉是,这些国家的双边贸易份额的扩大,与Bergin和Lin所估计的一样大,而且集中在广泛的边际上
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Comment
Bergin and Lin pick up a venerable distinction that, poorly represented with disaggregated trade data now accessible, has become the dernier cri of trade theory. The general issue of the new literature is what influences the division into intensive and extensive margin of the growth of a country’s share in the global exports going to another country. The specific issue raised in a subset of papers like the one here that is of interest is how, and then why, that division is influenced by the exchange rate regime between pairs of countries. This comment first conveys the essence of the historical distinction and then shows how the data currently used fail to reflect that distinction. This raises the question of what a contemporary implementation of the classical concept, largely preserved in Bergin and Lin’s model but not in its empirical implementation, could imply. It then discusses the absence of substantial uncertainty about future real exchange rates in the model, which detracts from the paper’s main theme. Other aspects that are crucial to the industrial organization of cross‐border trade, such as foreign direct investment (FDI) and trade in components, also are missing from the model. This makes it difficult to test hypotheses with it or to account for its findings. One crude validation test could be to check on the growth of trade shares for Canada and Mexico with the United States since the Canada‐ U.S. Free Trade Agreement 1988 or the NAFTA (North American Free Trade Agreement) 1994 and examine how this growth has been divided between the extensive and intensivemargins. My hunch is that the expansion of the bilateral trade shares of these countries is about as large and as concentrated at the extensive margin as Bergin and Lin estimated for
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信