{"title":"给予的经济学","authors":"Rubén Hernández-Murillo","doi":"10.20955/es.2005.24","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"In America, charitable giving is a thriving multibillion dollar enterprise, as illustrated in the accompanying chart. Most charitable contributions arise from the generosity of individual donors. In fact, the Giving USA Foundation estimates that individuals gave almost $188 billion to charities in 2004 (a 175 percent inflation-adjusted increase from 1964).1 Generosity is particularly evident after unexpected disasters. In September 2005, for example, the American Red Cross received about $807 million in gifts and pledges earmarked for Hurricane Katrina relief efforts—an increase of about $250 million over total Red Cross contributions during the 2003-04 fiscal year (www.redcross.org/news/ds/hurricanes/katrina_facts.html). Economists analyze the motivations behind individual giving to better understand how contributions are influenced by demographic characteristics, tax policies, and fundraising behavior. A fundamental issue of this analysis is the nature of the benefits that individuals receive when they give to charity. A recent study summarizes two alternative views.2 First, donors may focus on the well-being of charity recipients. In this case, the benefits from giving have a public nature. If the well-being of recipients is tied to the charity’s activities (the provision of disaster relief or the funding of cancer research), donors derive benefits from giving in the same way they derive benefits from public goods such as national defense. That is, a donor cannot exclude anyone else from enjoying the charity’s accomplishments; also, a donor’s enjoyment is not affected by the enjoyment or benefit derived by others. Second, donors may focus on the enjoyment they receive from the act of giving itself—that is, the internal feeling they derive from “doing their share” or “giving back to society.” Donors may also care about public recognition or about signaling wealth status. In these cases, the benefits from giving have a private nature. Individuals derive satisfaction from giving in the same way they derive benefits from consuming other private goods or services, such as clothing or food. These two motives for giving (public and private) have entirely different implications on giving behavior. Donors who experience public benefits look at the overall amount of charitable contributions, and donors who experience private benefits look only at their own contributions. If a donor’s benefits from giving are public, then a total contribution of $100 gives him the same sense that good is being done, even if his own contribution is $10 or $20. On the other hand, if a donor’s benefits from giving are private, a contribution of $20 generates more satisfaction than a contribution of $10, even if the total contribution is $100 either way. Economists predict that, according to the public benefits view, government subsidies to charities that are funded with increased taxes on donors will have no effect on the total contribution. This is because donors will reduce their private contributions by the same amount of the tax because they do not care whether they are giving on their own or indirectly through the tax. In other words, government grants to charities will completely crowd out private contributions. If donor benefits are entirely private, there should be no crowding out because donors do not care about the total amount of contributions, only about their own. Empirical studies have found only limited crowding out, suggesting that most donors are not solely concerned with the charities’ accomplishments, regardless of the source of contributions; instead, private motivations, such as the joy of giving or recognition, play an important role in their giving decisions.","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"5 2 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"53","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"The economics of giving\",\"authors\":\"Rubén Hernández-Murillo\",\"doi\":\"10.20955/es.2005.24\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"In America, charitable giving is a thriving multibillion dollar enterprise, as illustrated in the accompanying chart. Most charitable contributions arise from the generosity of individual donors. In fact, the Giving USA Foundation estimates that individuals gave almost $188 billion to charities in 2004 (a 175 percent inflation-adjusted increase from 1964).1 Generosity is particularly evident after unexpected disasters. In September 2005, for example, the American Red Cross received about $807 million in gifts and pledges earmarked for Hurricane Katrina relief efforts—an increase of about $250 million over total Red Cross contributions during the 2003-04 fiscal year (www.redcross.org/news/ds/hurricanes/katrina_facts.html). Economists analyze the motivations behind individual giving to better understand how contributions are influenced by demographic characteristics, tax policies, and fundraising behavior. A fundamental issue of this analysis is the nature of the benefits that individuals receive when they give to charity. A recent study summarizes two alternative views.2 First, donors may focus on the well-being of charity recipients. In this case, the benefits from giving have a public nature. If the well-being of recipients is tied to the charity’s activities (the provision of disaster relief or the funding of cancer research), donors derive benefits from giving in the same way they derive benefits from public goods such as national defense. That is, a donor cannot exclude anyone else from enjoying the charity’s accomplishments; also, a donor’s enjoyment is not affected by the enjoyment or benefit derived by others. Second, donors may focus on the enjoyment they receive from the act of giving itself—that is, the internal feeling they derive from “doing their share” or “giving back to society.” Donors may also care about public recognition or about signaling wealth status. In these cases, the benefits from giving have a private nature. Individuals derive satisfaction from giving in the same way they derive benefits from consuming other private goods or services, such as clothing or food. These two motives for giving (public and private) have entirely different implications on giving behavior. Donors who experience public benefits look at the overall amount of charitable contributions, and donors who experience private benefits look only at their own contributions. If a donor’s benefits from giving are public, then a total contribution of $100 gives him the same sense that good is being done, even if his own contribution is $10 or $20. On the other hand, if a donor’s benefits from giving are private, a contribution of $20 generates more satisfaction than a contribution of $10, even if the total contribution is $100 either way. Economists predict that, according to the public benefits view, government subsidies to charities that are funded with increased taxes on donors will have no effect on the total contribution. This is because donors will reduce their private contributions by the same amount of the tax because they do not care whether they are giving on their own or indirectly through the tax. In other words, government grants to charities will completely crowd out private contributions. If donor benefits are entirely private, there should be no crowding out because donors do not care about the total amount of contributions, only about their own. Empirical studies have found only limited crowding out, suggesting that most donors are not solely concerned with the charities’ accomplishments, regardless of the source of contributions; instead, private motivations, such as the joy of giving or recognition, play an important role in their giving decisions.\",\"PeriodicalId\":305484,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"National Economic Trends\",\"volume\":\"5 2 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"1900-01-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"53\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"National Economic Trends\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.20955/es.2005.24\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"National Economic Trends","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.20955/es.2005.24","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 53
摘要
在美国,慈善捐赠是一项蓬勃发展的数十亿美元的事业,如图所示。大多数慈善捐款来自个人捐赠者的慷慨。事实上,美国捐赠基金会(Giving USA Foundation)估计,2004年个人向慈善机构捐赠了近1880亿美元(与1964年相比,经通货膨胀调整后增长了175%)在意外的灾难之后,慷慨尤其明显。例如,2005年9月,美国红十字会收到了约8.07亿美元的捐赠和承诺,专门用于卡特里娜飓风的救援工作,比2003-04财政年度红十字会的捐款总额增加了约2.5亿美元(www.redcross.org/news/ds/hurricanes/katrina_facts.html)。经济学家分析个人捐赠背后的动机,以更好地理解捐赠是如何受到人口特征、税收政策和筹款行为的影响的。这种分析的一个基本问题是,个人在向慈善机构捐款时所获得的利益的性质。最近的一项研究总结了两种不同的观点首先,捐赠者可能会关注慈善接受者的福祉。在这种情况下,给予的好处具有公共性。如果接受者的福利与慈善活动(提供救灾或资助癌症研究)联系在一起,捐赠者从捐赠中获得利益的方式与他们从国防等公共产品中获得利益的方式相同。也就是说,捐赠者不能排除其他人享受慈善机构的成果;同时,捐赠人的享受不受他人的享受或者利益的影响。其次,捐赠者可能会关注他们从捐赠行为中获得的快乐——也就是说,他们从“尽自己的一份力”或“回馈社会”中获得的内心感受。捐赠者可能还关心公众的认可或彰显财富地位。在这些情况下,给予的好处具有私人性质。个人从给予中获得满足,就像他们从消费其他私人物品或服务(如衣服或食物)中获得利益一样。这两种捐赠动机(公共的和私人的)对捐赠行为有着完全不同的含义。获得公共利益的捐赠者关注的是慈善捐款的总量,而获得私人利益的捐赠者只关注自己的捐款。如果捐赠者从捐赠中获得的利益是公开的,那么100美元的总捐款会给他同样的感觉,即使他自己的捐款是10美元或20美元。另一方面,如果捐赠者从捐赠中获得的利益是私人的,那么20美元的捐赠比10美元的捐赠更能产生满足感,即使捐赠总额都是100美元。经济学家预测,根据公共利益观点,政府对慈善机构的补贴是通过增加捐赠者的税收来筹集的,对总捐款没有影响。这是因为,捐赠者不关心自己的捐赠还是通过税收间接捐赠,因此会减少与税收相同数额的私人捐款。换句话说,政府对慈善机构的拨款将完全挤出私人捐款。如果捐助者的利益完全是私人的,就不应该出现挤出现象,因为捐助者不关心捐款的总量,只关心他们自己的。实证研究只发现了有限的挤出效应,这表明大多数捐赠者并不只关心慈善机构的成就,而不考虑捐款的来源;相反,私人动机,如给予或认可的乐趣,在他们的捐赠决定中起着重要作用。
In America, charitable giving is a thriving multibillion dollar enterprise, as illustrated in the accompanying chart. Most charitable contributions arise from the generosity of individual donors. In fact, the Giving USA Foundation estimates that individuals gave almost $188 billion to charities in 2004 (a 175 percent inflation-adjusted increase from 1964).1 Generosity is particularly evident after unexpected disasters. In September 2005, for example, the American Red Cross received about $807 million in gifts and pledges earmarked for Hurricane Katrina relief efforts—an increase of about $250 million over total Red Cross contributions during the 2003-04 fiscal year (www.redcross.org/news/ds/hurricanes/katrina_facts.html). Economists analyze the motivations behind individual giving to better understand how contributions are influenced by demographic characteristics, tax policies, and fundraising behavior. A fundamental issue of this analysis is the nature of the benefits that individuals receive when they give to charity. A recent study summarizes two alternative views.2 First, donors may focus on the well-being of charity recipients. In this case, the benefits from giving have a public nature. If the well-being of recipients is tied to the charity’s activities (the provision of disaster relief or the funding of cancer research), donors derive benefits from giving in the same way they derive benefits from public goods such as national defense. That is, a donor cannot exclude anyone else from enjoying the charity’s accomplishments; also, a donor’s enjoyment is not affected by the enjoyment or benefit derived by others. Second, donors may focus on the enjoyment they receive from the act of giving itself—that is, the internal feeling they derive from “doing their share” or “giving back to society.” Donors may also care about public recognition or about signaling wealth status. In these cases, the benefits from giving have a private nature. Individuals derive satisfaction from giving in the same way they derive benefits from consuming other private goods or services, such as clothing or food. These two motives for giving (public and private) have entirely different implications on giving behavior. Donors who experience public benefits look at the overall amount of charitable contributions, and donors who experience private benefits look only at their own contributions. If a donor’s benefits from giving are public, then a total contribution of $100 gives him the same sense that good is being done, even if his own contribution is $10 or $20. On the other hand, if a donor’s benefits from giving are private, a contribution of $20 generates more satisfaction than a contribution of $10, even if the total contribution is $100 either way. Economists predict that, according to the public benefits view, government subsidies to charities that are funded with increased taxes on donors will have no effect on the total contribution. This is because donors will reduce their private contributions by the same amount of the tax because they do not care whether they are giving on their own or indirectly through the tax. In other words, government grants to charities will completely crowd out private contributions. If donor benefits are entirely private, there should be no crowding out because donors do not care about the total amount of contributions, only about their own. Empirical studies have found only limited crowding out, suggesting that most donors are not solely concerned with the charities’ accomplishments, regardless of the source of contributions; instead, private motivations, such as the joy of giving or recognition, play an important role in their giving decisions.