交通基础设施发展和维修的收费原则

T. Nemoto
{"title":"交通基础设施发展和维修的收费原则","authors":"T. Nemoto","doi":"10.15057/25928","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"With the onset of an aging society and low birth rates, coupled with tight financial conditions being experienced by central and local governments, the need to ensure transport services that protect people’s life in rural areas and provide infrastructure that strengthens global competitiveness of large cities has become more vital than before. Moreover, costs concerning maintenance and renewal of transport infrastructure are also expected to be needed (MLIT, 2012). Under such a situation, what kind of charging principle should be introduced in order to ensure revenue sources for maintenance and renewal of transport infrastructure, such as roads and railways? The objectives of this paper are: 1) to clarify definitions of short run marginal cost pricing and short run average cost pricing (charging principles when transport infrastructure capacity is given), 2) to explain how to obtain long run marginal cost pricing assuming a condition that can optimize transport infrastructure capacity to meet transport demand, and 3) to demonstrate the validity of short run marginal cost pricing through a planning process that gradually increases or reduces transport infrastructure capacity. 1. Transport System Costs It is necessary to define transport system costs to design charging in transport. Transport system costs refer to the costs arising from the construction and maintenance of transport infrastructure and its use. When considering a cost item, it is necessary to differentiate first between fixed and variable costs. Fixed costs are costs which are not related to traffic volume, such as construction costs. Variable costs are costs determined according to the amount of traffic, such as maintenance costs. The value which divides traffic volume from the aggregate total cost (the sum of fixed costs and variable costs) is the average cost; and the value which differentiates variable cost from traffic volume is the marginal cost. It is also important to pay attention to stakeholders that generate costs. Broadly speaking, the stakeholders consist of that of the transport infrastructure manager doing construction and maintenance, the user using the transport infrastructure, and other stakeholder which can be subjected to positive and/or negative impacts arising from the use of the transport infrastructure although not directly related to the provision and use of transport infrastructure. Transport infrastructure managers and users are assumed to form a pseudo market, and their costs are called internal costs, while costs arising on other stakeholder are called external costs. Although users can be divided into transport companies (e.g. bus companies) who provide transport services and directly use the transport infrastructure, and service users who purchase these transport services, this paper focuses on the former type of users who directly use the transport infrastructure, and looks at how taxes and charges are collected for maintenance and renewal of transport infrastructure. Since transport companies do not exist for \"road use by private cars\", the transport system is simpler and it is easier to appreciate the distribution of benefits and costs. Therefore, this paper concentrates on the case of “road use by private cars”. Let us suppose that items of transport system costs on the road (i.e. road system costs) can be specifically observed. The road user may use the road by paying C, D, E, and F. Among these, E and F are taxes and charges which the road user pays for car ownership and use. These are transferred to the road manager, and are appropriated for the maintenance of roads. These charges serve as revenue to the road manager, and then are cancelled resulting in no social costs. The ultimate costs remaining are A, B, C, D, G, and H. This sum functions as an aggregate total cost. The charges and taxes which the users pay are not all appropriated for the maintenance of the transport infrastructure. Historically, there exist an earmarked financing system which uses taxes and charges from users of specific transport infrastructure for its maintenance. However, the number of countries using this system has been reduced at the moment. Some examples that have exceptionally remained are the federal gasoline tax of the U.S., the energy tax of Germany, and the axle tax of France. While new road construction becomes difficult partly owing to people’s environmental concerns, the Ministry of Finance, which wants to secure the favourably increasing automobile-related taxes as a source of revenue, abolished the earmarked financing system, and has been using them as a general revenue source. In the newest European transport white paper (EC, 2011), it has been specified that “it is important to establish a financial system in which revenue from transport users is used for the improvement of transport\". This is in agreement with the position of this paper which aims at coinciding both benefit and cost. Furthermore, it is necessary to distinguish between short run and long run costs. Short run costs are costs when the given transport infrastructure does not change. Table 1 distinguishes between fixed costs and variable costs, although these are both for the short-term. In the long run, wherein transport infrastructure capacity may change through road widening and road network extension, all costs become variable costs. Therefore, for short run optimization, given the present transport infrastructure, traffic can be rationalized by introducing charges. On the other hand, for long run optimization, a policy is examined to rationalize transport infrastructure capacity given future traffic volumes. Table 1. Road system costs Fixed costs Variable costs (related to traffic volume) Internal Cost Road Manager A: Construction cost B: Maintenance cost Road User (i.e., E and F are taxes/charges transferred to the road manager) C: Vehicle cost D: Time cost, Fuel cost E: Vehicle ownership charges F:Gasoline tax, toll charges, distance-based charges External Cost Other Stakeholder G: Improvement or destruction of scenery H: Congestion, Air pollution The cost functions for two-lane and four-lane roads connecting two cities are illustrated in Fig. 1. As mentioned above, the average cost is the value equal to the sum of fixed cost and variable cost divided by traffic volume. The fixed cost divided by traffic volume decreases as traffic volume increases. However, since congestion arises and time cost increases as traffic increases, the average cost also increases (i.e. convex form). The marginal cost is the increase in total social cost caused by unit increases in traffic. Since the increase in time cost of the society caused by the additional users at congested periods may surpass by far the increase in the concerned user's time cost, the marginal cost curve rapidly increases after crossing the lowest point of the average cost curve. Although the average cost curves of two-lane and four-lane roads are of the same shape, the cost curve for the four-lane road is shifted towards the lower right. As will be mentioned later, economies of scale may be assumed at these numbers of lanes. The long run average cost curve is an envelope curve connecting the bottoms of the short run average cost curves. If the number of lanes and road capacity increases, it can be seen that the long run average cost decreases. For transport infrastructure, it has been pointed out that ‘indivisibilities’, which means that the number of lanes of a road must be an integar, may become obstacles during road capacity optimization. In Fig. 1, the long run average cost cannot be differentiated at the intersection. However, as far as the road is concerned, the road capacity is not a function of the number of lanes, but also a function of the width of each lane and the width of the shoulder. Conversely, it seems that the road capacity can be increased almost continuously if maximum roadway capacity can be secured and designed under a certain width of the street facility. 2. Short Run Marginal Cost Pricing that Realizes Optimal Traffic Given the Transport Infrastructure Let us examine the charging principle given the transport infrastructure. Corresponding to the short run decision-making problem in economics, it is understood that price setting by short run marginal cost (or for accuracy, short run marginal social cost containing external cost), can realize optimal usage of a transport infrastructure. That is, it is believed that traffic volume that maximizes social benefits can be realized using road capacity at that time. Marginal cost pricing is explained using Fig. 2. Let us recall the two-lane short run average cost and the short run marginal cost curves which were shown in Fig. 1. There, a short run user average cost curve is added. The user average cost is the value equal to the user cost (C and D of Table 1) divided by traffic volume. Of the user average cost, the time cost required for travel becomes the major cost (average time value of the road user is about 40 yen/minute). Furthermore, the high and low demand curves are added. Traffic volume Cost Figure 1. Short run average cost, Short run marginal cost, and Long run average cost • Bold line represents long run average cost Short run marginal cost (2-lane) Short run marginal cost (4-lane) Short run average cost (4-lane) Short run average cost (2-lane) If there are no taxes and charges, since the road can be used by payment of the short run user average cost, the road may be used up to Q1 corresponding to intersection A of the high demand curve (traffic volume is equivalent to Q2 at low demand). At this traffic volume, however, total cost increases by the short run marginal cost shown in the Figure due to the increase in the number of concerned road users. Social loss is produced between the short run marginal cost curve and the demand curve (a triangle ABC). The amount of traffic decided by the intersection of the demand curve an","PeriodicalId":154016,"journal":{"name":"Hitotsubashi journal of commerce and management","volume":"25 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2013-10-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"THE CHARGING PRINCIPLE FOR THE DEVELOPMENT AND MAINTENANCE OF TRANSPORT INFRASTRUCTURE\",\"authors\":\"T. Nemoto\",\"doi\":\"10.15057/25928\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"With the onset of an aging society and low birth rates, coupled with tight financial conditions being experienced by central and local governments, the need to ensure transport services that protect people’s life in rural areas and provide infrastructure that strengthens global competitiveness of large cities has become more vital than before. Moreover, costs concerning maintenance and renewal of transport infrastructure are also expected to be needed (MLIT, 2012). Under such a situation, what kind of charging principle should be introduced in order to ensure revenue sources for maintenance and renewal of transport infrastructure, such as roads and railways? The objectives of this paper are: 1) to clarify definitions of short run marginal cost pricing and short run average cost pricing (charging principles when transport infrastructure capacity is given), 2) to explain how to obtain long run marginal cost pricing assuming a condition that can optimize transport infrastructure capacity to meet transport demand, and 3) to demonstrate the validity of short run marginal cost pricing through a planning process that gradually increases or reduces transport infrastructure capacity. 1. Transport System Costs It is necessary to define transport system costs to design charging in transport. Transport system costs refer to the costs arising from the construction and maintenance of transport infrastructure and its use. When considering a cost item, it is necessary to differentiate first between fixed and variable costs. Fixed costs are costs which are not related to traffic volume, such as construction costs. Variable costs are costs determined according to the amount of traffic, such as maintenance costs. The value which divides traffic volume from the aggregate total cost (the sum of fixed costs and variable costs) is the average cost; and the value which differentiates variable cost from traffic volume is the marginal cost. It is also important to pay attention to stakeholders that generate costs. Broadly speaking, the stakeholders consist of that of the transport infrastructure manager doing construction and maintenance, the user using the transport infrastructure, and other stakeholder which can be subjected to positive and/or negative impacts arising from the use of the transport infrastructure although not directly related to the provision and use of transport infrastructure. Transport infrastructure managers and users are assumed to form a pseudo market, and their costs are called internal costs, while costs arising on other stakeholder are called external costs. Although users can be divided into transport companies (e.g. bus companies) who provide transport services and directly use the transport infrastructure, and service users who purchase these transport services, this paper focuses on the former type of users who directly use the transport infrastructure, and looks at how taxes and charges are collected for maintenance and renewal of transport infrastructure. Since transport companies do not exist for \\\"road use by private cars\\\", the transport system is simpler and it is easier to appreciate the distribution of benefits and costs. Therefore, this paper concentrates on the case of “road use by private cars”. Let us suppose that items of transport system costs on the road (i.e. road system costs) can be specifically observed. The road user may use the road by paying C, D, E, and F. Among these, E and F are taxes and charges which the road user pays for car ownership and use. These are transferred to the road manager, and are appropriated for the maintenance of roads. These charges serve as revenue to the road manager, and then are cancelled resulting in no social costs. The ultimate costs remaining are A, B, C, D, G, and H. This sum functions as an aggregate total cost. The charges and taxes which the users pay are not all appropriated for the maintenance of the transport infrastructure. Historically, there exist an earmarked financing system which uses taxes and charges from users of specific transport infrastructure for its maintenance. However, the number of countries using this system has been reduced at the moment. Some examples that have exceptionally remained are the federal gasoline tax of the U.S., the energy tax of Germany, and the axle tax of France. While new road construction becomes difficult partly owing to people’s environmental concerns, the Ministry of Finance, which wants to secure the favourably increasing automobile-related taxes as a source of revenue, abolished the earmarked financing system, and has been using them as a general revenue source. In the newest European transport white paper (EC, 2011), it has been specified that “it is important to establish a financial system in which revenue from transport users is used for the improvement of transport\\\". This is in agreement with the position of this paper which aims at coinciding both benefit and cost. Furthermore, it is necessary to distinguish between short run and long run costs. Short run costs are costs when the given transport infrastructure does not change. Table 1 distinguishes between fixed costs and variable costs, although these are both for the short-term. In the long run, wherein transport infrastructure capacity may change through road widening and road network extension, all costs become variable costs. Therefore, for short run optimization, given the present transport infrastructure, traffic can be rationalized by introducing charges. On the other hand, for long run optimization, a policy is examined to rationalize transport infrastructure capacity given future traffic volumes. Table 1. Road system costs Fixed costs Variable costs (related to traffic volume) Internal Cost Road Manager A: Construction cost B: Maintenance cost Road User (i.e., E and F are taxes/charges transferred to the road manager) C: Vehicle cost D: Time cost, Fuel cost E: Vehicle ownership charges F:Gasoline tax, toll charges, distance-based charges External Cost Other Stakeholder G: Improvement or destruction of scenery H: Congestion, Air pollution The cost functions for two-lane and four-lane roads connecting two cities are illustrated in Fig. 1. As mentioned above, the average cost is the value equal to the sum of fixed cost and variable cost divided by traffic volume. The fixed cost divided by traffic volume decreases as traffic volume increases. However, since congestion arises and time cost increases as traffic increases, the average cost also increases (i.e. convex form). The marginal cost is the increase in total social cost caused by unit increases in traffic. Since the increase in time cost of the society caused by the additional users at congested periods may surpass by far the increase in the concerned user's time cost, the marginal cost curve rapidly increases after crossing the lowest point of the average cost curve. Although the average cost curves of two-lane and four-lane roads are of the same shape, the cost curve for the four-lane road is shifted towards the lower right. As will be mentioned later, economies of scale may be assumed at these numbers of lanes. The long run average cost curve is an envelope curve connecting the bottoms of the short run average cost curves. If the number of lanes and road capacity increases, it can be seen that the long run average cost decreases. For transport infrastructure, it has been pointed out that ‘indivisibilities’, which means that the number of lanes of a road must be an integar, may become obstacles during road capacity optimization. In Fig. 1, the long run average cost cannot be differentiated at the intersection. However, as far as the road is concerned, the road capacity is not a function of the number of lanes, but also a function of the width of each lane and the width of the shoulder. Conversely, it seems that the road capacity can be increased almost continuously if maximum roadway capacity can be secured and designed under a certain width of the street facility. 2. Short Run Marginal Cost Pricing that Realizes Optimal Traffic Given the Transport Infrastructure Let us examine the charging principle given the transport infrastructure. Corresponding to the short run decision-making problem in economics, it is understood that price setting by short run marginal cost (or for accuracy, short run marginal social cost containing external cost), can realize optimal usage of a transport infrastructure. That is, it is believed that traffic volume that maximizes social benefits can be realized using road capacity at that time. Marginal cost pricing is explained using Fig. 2. Let us recall the two-lane short run average cost and the short run marginal cost curves which were shown in Fig. 1. There, a short run user average cost curve is added. The user average cost is the value equal to the user cost (C and D of Table 1) divided by traffic volume. Of the user average cost, the time cost required for travel becomes the major cost (average time value of the road user is about 40 yen/minute). Furthermore, the high and low demand curves are added. Traffic volume Cost Figure 1. Short run average cost, Short run marginal cost, and Long run average cost • Bold line represents long run average cost Short run marginal cost (2-lane) Short run marginal cost (4-lane) Short run average cost (4-lane) Short run average cost (2-lane) If there are no taxes and charges, since the road can be used by payment of the short run user average cost, the road may be used up to Q1 corresponding to intersection A of the high demand curve (traffic volume is equivalent to Q2 at low demand). At this traffic volume, however, total cost increases by the short run marginal cost shown in the Figure due to the increase in the number of concerned road users. Social loss is produced between the short run marginal cost curve and the demand curve (a triangle ABC). The amount of traffic decided by the intersection of the demand curve an\",\"PeriodicalId\":154016,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"Hitotsubashi journal of commerce and management\",\"volume\":\"25 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"2013-10-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"1\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"Hitotsubashi journal of commerce and management\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.15057/25928\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Hitotsubashi journal of commerce and management","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.15057/25928","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

摘要

随着老龄化社会和低出生率的到来,加上中央和地方政府的财政状况紧张,确保交通服务,保护农村地区人民的生活,提供基础设施,增强大城市的全球竞争力,变得比以往更加重要。此外,预计还需要运输基础设施的维护和更新成本(MLIT, 2012)。在这种情况下,应该采用怎样的收费原则,以确保道路和铁路等交通基础设施的维修和更新的收入来源?本文的目的是:1)澄清短期边际成本定价和短期平均成本定价的定义(交通基础设施容量给定时的收费原则),2)解释如何在能够优化交通基础设施容量以满足运输需求的条件下获得长期边际成本定价,3)通过逐步增加或减少交通基础设施容量的规划过程证明短期边际成本定价的有效性。1. 交通运输收费设计需要明确交通运输系统成本。运输系统成本是指运输基础设施的建造、维护和使用所产生的成本。在考虑成本项目时,有必要首先区分固定成本和可变成本。固定成本是指与交通量无关的成本,如建筑成本。可变成本是根据交通量确定的成本,如维护成本。将交通量与总成本(固定成本和可变成本之和)相除的值为平均成本;而区分可变成本和交通量的值是边际成本。关注产生成本的利益相关者也很重要。广义而言,持份者包括进行建造及维修的运输基建经理、使用运输基建的使用者,以及其他可能因使用运输基建而受到正面及/或负面影响的持份者,尽管这些持份者与运输基建的提供及使用并无直接关系。假设交通基础设施管理者和用户形成一个伪市场,其成本称为内部成本,其他利益相关者产生的成本称为外部成本。虽然用户可以分为提供运输服务并直接使用运输基础设施的运输公司(如巴士公司)和购买这些运输服务的服务用户,但本文主要关注前者直接使用运输基础设施的用户,并研究如何收取运输基础设施维护和更新的税费。由于运输公司不为“私家车使用道路”而存在,因此运输系统更简单,更容易理解收益和成本的分配。因此,本文主要以“私家车使用道路”为案例。让我们假设道路上的运输系统成本项目(即道路系统成本)可以具体观察到。道路使用者可以通过支付C、D、E和F来使用道路。其中,E和F是道路使用者为拥有和使用汽车而支付的税费。这些钱被转交给道路管理者,并被用于道路的维护。这些费用作为道路管理者的收入,然后被取消,没有社会成本。剩余的最终成本是A、B、C、D、G和h。这个总和作为总成本。使用者支付的费用和税收并不都是用于维持运输基础设施。从历史上看,存在一种专用的融资制度,该制度利用特定运输基础设施的用户的税收和费用来维持其维修。不过,目前使用这一制度的国家数目已经减少。美国的联邦汽油税、德国的能源税、法国的车轴税等都例外地保留了下来。由于人们对环境的担忧,新道路建设变得困难,财政部为了确保有利的汽车相关税收作为收入来源,取消了专项融资制度,并将其作为一般收入来源。在最新的欧洲交通白皮书(EC, 2011)中,它已经明确指出“建立一个财政体系是很重要的,在这个体系中,来自交通用户的收入用于改善交通”。这与本文旨在兼顾效益和成本的立场是一致的。 此外,有必要区分短期成本和长期成本。短期成本是指给定的交通基础设施不变时的成本。表1区分了固定成本和可变成本,尽管它们都是短期成本。从长期来看,交通基础设施能力可能会因道路加宽和路网扩展而发生变化,所有成本都成为可变成本。因此,对于短期优化,在现有交通基础设施的情况下,可以通过收费来实现交通的合理化。另一方面,对于长期优化,在给定未来交通量的情况下,研究一项使交通基础设施容量合理化的政策。表1。道路系统成本固定成本可变成本(与交通量相关)内部成本道路管理者A:建设成本B:维护成本道路使用者(即,E和F是转移给道路管理者的税收/费用)C:车辆成本D:时间成本,燃料成本E:车辆所有权费用F:汽油税,通行费,距离收费外部成本其他利益相关者G:改善或破坏风景H:连接两个城市的双车道和四车道道路的成本函数如图1所示。如上所述,平均成本等于固定成本和可变成本之和除以交通量。固定成本除以交通量随交通量的增加而减小。然而,由于拥堵的出现和时间成本随着交通流量的增加而增加,平均成本也会增加(即凸形式)。边际成本是单位交通量增加所引起的社会总成本的增加。由于拥挤期新增用户所造成的社会时间成本的增加可能远远超过相关用户时间成本的增加,因此边际成本曲线在越过平均成本曲线的最低点后迅速增加。虽然两车道和四车道道路的平均成本曲线形状相同,但四车道道路的成本曲线向右下方偏移。正如后面将提到的,在这些车道数量上可以假设规模经济。长期平均成本曲线是一条连接短期平均成本曲线底部的包络曲线。当车道数和道路容量增加时,可以看出长期平均成本降低。对于交通基础设施,有人指出,“不可分割性”,即道路的车道数必须是一个整数,可能成为道路容量优化的障碍。在图1中,长期平均成本在交叉口处无法区分。然而,就道路而言,道路容量不是车道数的函数,而是每条车道宽度和肩宽的函数。相反,如果在一定的街道设施宽度下,能够确保和设计最大的道路容量,道路容量似乎可以几乎连续地增加。2. 在交通基础设施条件下实现最优交通的短期边际成本定价我们考察在交通基础设施条件下的收费原则。与经济学中的短期决策问题相对应,可以理解为通过短期边际成本(或者准确地说,是包含外部成本的短期边际社会成本)来确定价格,可以实现交通基础设施的最优使用。也就是说,我们认为可以利用当时的道路容量来实现社会效益最大化的交通量。边际成本定价用图2来解释。让我们回顾一下图1所示的两车道短期平均成本和短期边际成本曲线。在这里,添加了一个短期用户平均成本曲线。用户平均成本等于用户成本(表1中的C和D)除以流量。在用户平均成本中,出行所需的时间成本成为主要成本(道路使用者的平均时间价值约为40日元/分钟)。此外,还增加了高需求曲线和低需求曲线。交通量及成本图1短期平均成本,短期边际成本和长期平均成本•粗线代表长期平均成本短期边际成本(文体馆)短期边际成本(4-lane)短期平均成本(4-lane)短期平均成本(文体馆)如果没有税收和费用,因为路上可以通过短期支付的用户平均成本,这条路可以到Q1交点对应的高需求曲线(交通量等于Q2在低需求)。然而,在这个交通量下,由于有关道路使用者数目的增加,总成本增加了图中所示的短期边际成本。社会损失产生于短期边际成本曲线和需求曲线之间(三角形ABC)。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
THE CHARGING PRINCIPLE FOR THE DEVELOPMENT AND MAINTENANCE OF TRANSPORT INFRASTRUCTURE
With the onset of an aging society and low birth rates, coupled with tight financial conditions being experienced by central and local governments, the need to ensure transport services that protect people’s life in rural areas and provide infrastructure that strengthens global competitiveness of large cities has become more vital than before. Moreover, costs concerning maintenance and renewal of transport infrastructure are also expected to be needed (MLIT, 2012). Under such a situation, what kind of charging principle should be introduced in order to ensure revenue sources for maintenance and renewal of transport infrastructure, such as roads and railways? The objectives of this paper are: 1) to clarify definitions of short run marginal cost pricing and short run average cost pricing (charging principles when transport infrastructure capacity is given), 2) to explain how to obtain long run marginal cost pricing assuming a condition that can optimize transport infrastructure capacity to meet transport demand, and 3) to demonstrate the validity of short run marginal cost pricing through a planning process that gradually increases or reduces transport infrastructure capacity. 1. Transport System Costs It is necessary to define transport system costs to design charging in transport. Transport system costs refer to the costs arising from the construction and maintenance of transport infrastructure and its use. When considering a cost item, it is necessary to differentiate first between fixed and variable costs. Fixed costs are costs which are not related to traffic volume, such as construction costs. Variable costs are costs determined according to the amount of traffic, such as maintenance costs. The value which divides traffic volume from the aggregate total cost (the sum of fixed costs and variable costs) is the average cost; and the value which differentiates variable cost from traffic volume is the marginal cost. It is also important to pay attention to stakeholders that generate costs. Broadly speaking, the stakeholders consist of that of the transport infrastructure manager doing construction and maintenance, the user using the transport infrastructure, and other stakeholder which can be subjected to positive and/or negative impacts arising from the use of the transport infrastructure although not directly related to the provision and use of transport infrastructure. Transport infrastructure managers and users are assumed to form a pseudo market, and their costs are called internal costs, while costs arising on other stakeholder are called external costs. Although users can be divided into transport companies (e.g. bus companies) who provide transport services and directly use the transport infrastructure, and service users who purchase these transport services, this paper focuses on the former type of users who directly use the transport infrastructure, and looks at how taxes and charges are collected for maintenance and renewal of transport infrastructure. Since transport companies do not exist for "road use by private cars", the transport system is simpler and it is easier to appreciate the distribution of benefits and costs. Therefore, this paper concentrates on the case of “road use by private cars”. Let us suppose that items of transport system costs on the road (i.e. road system costs) can be specifically observed. The road user may use the road by paying C, D, E, and F. Among these, E and F are taxes and charges which the road user pays for car ownership and use. These are transferred to the road manager, and are appropriated for the maintenance of roads. These charges serve as revenue to the road manager, and then are cancelled resulting in no social costs. The ultimate costs remaining are A, B, C, D, G, and H. This sum functions as an aggregate total cost. The charges and taxes which the users pay are not all appropriated for the maintenance of the transport infrastructure. Historically, there exist an earmarked financing system which uses taxes and charges from users of specific transport infrastructure for its maintenance. However, the number of countries using this system has been reduced at the moment. Some examples that have exceptionally remained are the federal gasoline tax of the U.S., the energy tax of Germany, and the axle tax of France. While new road construction becomes difficult partly owing to people’s environmental concerns, the Ministry of Finance, which wants to secure the favourably increasing automobile-related taxes as a source of revenue, abolished the earmarked financing system, and has been using them as a general revenue source. In the newest European transport white paper (EC, 2011), it has been specified that “it is important to establish a financial system in which revenue from transport users is used for the improvement of transport". This is in agreement with the position of this paper which aims at coinciding both benefit and cost. Furthermore, it is necessary to distinguish between short run and long run costs. Short run costs are costs when the given transport infrastructure does not change. Table 1 distinguishes between fixed costs and variable costs, although these are both for the short-term. In the long run, wherein transport infrastructure capacity may change through road widening and road network extension, all costs become variable costs. Therefore, for short run optimization, given the present transport infrastructure, traffic can be rationalized by introducing charges. On the other hand, for long run optimization, a policy is examined to rationalize transport infrastructure capacity given future traffic volumes. Table 1. Road system costs Fixed costs Variable costs (related to traffic volume) Internal Cost Road Manager A: Construction cost B: Maintenance cost Road User (i.e., E and F are taxes/charges transferred to the road manager) C: Vehicle cost D: Time cost, Fuel cost E: Vehicle ownership charges F:Gasoline tax, toll charges, distance-based charges External Cost Other Stakeholder G: Improvement or destruction of scenery H: Congestion, Air pollution The cost functions for two-lane and four-lane roads connecting two cities are illustrated in Fig. 1. As mentioned above, the average cost is the value equal to the sum of fixed cost and variable cost divided by traffic volume. The fixed cost divided by traffic volume decreases as traffic volume increases. However, since congestion arises and time cost increases as traffic increases, the average cost also increases (i.e. convex form). The marginal cost is the increase in total social cost caused by unit increases in traffic. Since the increase in time cost of the society caused by the additional users at congested periods may surpass by far the increase in the concerned user's time cost, the marginal cost curve rapidly increases after crossing the lowest point of the average cost curve. Although the average cost curves of two-lane and four-lane roads are of the same shape, the cost curve for the four-lane road is shifted towards the lower right. As will be mentioned later, economies of scale may be assumed at these numbers of lanes. The long run average cost curve is an envelope curve connecting the bottoms of the short run average cost curves. If the number of lanes and road capacity increases, it can be seen that the long run average cost decreases. For transport infrastructure, it has been pointed out that ‘indivisibilities’, which means that the number of lanes of a road must be an integar, may become obstacles during road capacity optimization. In Fig. 1, the long run average cost cannot be differentiated at the intersection. However, as far as the road is concerned, the road capacity is not a function of the number of lanes, but also a function of the width of each lane and the width of the shoulder. Conversely, it seems that the road capacity can be increased almost continuously if maximum roadway capacity can be secured and designed under a certain width of the street facility. 2. Short Run Marginal Cost Pricing that Realizes Optimal Traffic Given the Transport Infrastructure Let us examine the charging principle given the transport infrastructure. Corresponding to the short run decision-making problem in economics, it is understood that price setting by short run marginal cost (or for accuracy, short run marginal social cost containing external cost), can realize optimal usage of a transport infrastructure. That is, it is believed that traffic volume that maximizes social benefits can be realized using road capacity at that time. Marginal cost pricing is explained using Fig. 2. Let us recall the two-lane short run average cost and the short run marginal cost curves which were shown in Fig. 1. There, a short run user average cost curve is added. The user average cost is the value equal to the user cost (C and D of Table 1) divided by traffic volume. Of the user average cost, the time cost required for travel becomes the major cost (average time value of the road user is about 40 yen/minute). Furthermore, the high and low demand curves are added. Traffic volume Cost Figure 1. Short run average cost, Short run marginal cost, and Long run average cost • Bold line represents long run average cost Short run marginal cost (2-lane) Short run marginal cost (4-lane) Short run average cost (4-lane) Short run average cost (2-lane) If there are no taxes and charges, since the road can be used by payment of the short run user average cost, the road may be used up to Q1 corresponding to intersection A of the high demand curve (traffic volume is equivalent to Q2 at low demand). At this traffic volume, however, total cost increases by the short run marginal cost shown in the Figure due to the increase in the number of concerned road users. Social loss is produced between the short run marginal cost curve and the demand curve (a triangle ABC). The amount of traffic decided by the intersection of the demand curve an
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信