预期的股票市场回报和商业投资

Hui Guo
{"title":"预期的股票市场回报和商业投资","authors":"Hui Guo","doi":"10.20955/ES.2002.17","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"M ost financial economists would agree that expected stock returns vary somewhat across time. Of course, this variation in expected returns explains only a small fraction of the variation in actual returns. Consequently, attempting to time the market remains a risky endeavor and many risk-averse investors favor buy-and-hold investing. Busi ness investment projects, on the other hand, are unavoidably “lumpy” by nature and firms have strong incentives to wait for the most profitable periods to invest in irreversible, largescale projects. Do we see any evidence that business investment keys off expected stock market returns, and, if so, what is the current outlook for business investment? Recently, Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) showed that the deviation of consumption from aggregate wealth, which they label as the consumption-wealth ratio, is a useful indicator of expected stock returns, especially long-lasting shifts in expected returns.1 Their measure of aggregate wealth includes both financial assets and the present value of labor income. The predictive ability of the consumption-wealth ratio is consistent with the economic theory that views consumption as a forwardlooking variable. If investors foresee higher stock returns in the future, they will boost their consumption now to smooth consumption. Therefore, a high (low) level of the consumptionwealth ratio indicates high (low) expected stock returns in the future. Like consumption decisions, business investment is also forward-looking with respect to expected returns to capital. If expected returns shift upward, new capital put in place now is expected to garner those high returns. It follows that movements in the consumption-wealth ratio should presage movements in business investment because the consumption-wealth ratio contains information about expected stock returns. Lettau and Ludvigson (2002) show that this relationship is present in the post-World War II data.2 The accompanying chart demonstrates their main results. The thin dashed line is the consumption-wealth ratio and the thick solid line is the average growth rate of fixed, private nonresidential investment in the three subsequent years. In general, a high level of the consumption-wealth ratio is associated with high rates of future investment and the coefficient of correlation between these two variables is about 0.40. The business cycle, highlighted with recession bars in the chart, appears to be a significant source of variation in expected stock market returns. The correlation between the consumption-wealth ratio and business investment appears particularly strong in the last decade. Relatively high levels of the consumption-wealth ratio in the early 1990s preceded dramatic increases in both stock market prices and business invest ment in the subsequent years. Later in the 1990s, however, consumption did not rise at the same pace that financial wealth increased and the consumptionwealth ratio fell to an unusually low level. With this signal of low expected returns, investment and stock prices began to retreat in early 2000 and the economy eventually went into recession in the first quarter of 2001. At present, the consumptionwealth ratio is substantially above its recent trough, but it is still not at a level that suggests that business investment will be a strong driver of a new economic expansion. Lettau, Martin and Ludvigson, Sydney. “Consumption, Aggregate Wealth, and Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, June 2001, 56(3), pp. 815-49. Lettau, Martin and Ludvigson, Sydney. “Time-Varying Risk-Premia and the Cost of Capital: An Alternative Implication of the q Theory of Investment.” Journal of Monetary Economics, January 2002, 49(1), pp. 31-66. Expected Stock Market Returns and Business Investment","PeriodicalId":305484,"journal":{"name":"National Economic Trends","volume":"105 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"1900-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"2","resultStr":"{\"title\":\"Expected stock market returns and business investment\",\"authors\":\"Hui Guo\",\"doi\":\"10.20955/ES.2002.17\",\"DOIUrl\":null,\"url\":null,\"abstract\":\"M ost financial economists would agree that expected stock returns vary somewhat across time. Of course, this variation in expected returns explains only a small fraction of the variation in actual returns. Consequently, attempting to time the market remains a risky endeavor and many risk-averse investors favor buy-and-hold investing. Busi ness investment projects, on the other hand, are unavoidably “lumpy” by nature and firms have strong incentives to wait for the most profitable periods to invest in irreversible, largescale projects. Do we see any evidence that business investment keys off expected stock market returns, and, if so, what is the current outlook for business investment? Recently, Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) showed that the deviation of consumption from aggregate wealth, which they label as the consumption-wealth ratio, is a useful indicator of expected stock returns, especially long-lasting shifts in expected returns.1 Their measure of aggregate wealth includes both financial assets and the present value of labor income. The predictive ability of the consumption-wealth ratio is consistent with the economic theory that views consumption as a forwardlooking variable. If investors foresee higher stock returns in the future, they will boost their consumption now to smooth consumption. Therefore, a high (low) level of the consumptionwealth ratio indicates high (low) expected stock returns in the future. Like consumption decisions, business investment is also forward-looking with respect to expected returns to capital. If expected returns shift upward, new capital put in place now is expected to garner those high returns. It follows that movements in the consumption-wealth ratio should presage movements in business investment because the consumption-wealth ratio contains information about expected stock returns. Lettau and Ludvigson (2002) show that this relationship is present in the post-World War II data.2 The accompanying chart demonstrates their main results. The thin dashed line is the consumption-wealth ratio and the thick solid line is the average growth rate of fixed, private nonresidential investment in the three subsequent years. In general, a high level of the consumption-wealth ratio is associated with high rates of future investment and the coefficient of correlation between these two variables is about 0.40. The business cycle, highlighted with recession bars in the chart, appears to be a significant source of variation in expected stock market returns. The correlation between the consumption-wealth ratio and business investment appears particularly strong in the last decade. Relatively high levels of the consumption-wealth ratio in the early 1990s preceded dramatic increases in both stock market prices and business invest ment in the subsequent years. Later in the 1990s, however, consumption did not rise at the same pace that financial wealth increased and the consumptionwealth ratio fell to an unusually low level. With this signal of low expected returns, investment and stock prices began to retreat in early 2000 and the economy eventually went into recession in the first quarter of 2001. At present, the consumptionwealth ratio is substantially above its recent trough, but it is still not at a level that suggests that business investment will be a strong driver of a new economic expansion. Lettau, Martin and Ludvigson, Sydney. “Consumption, Aggregate Wealth, and Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, June 2001, 56(3), pp. 815-49. Lettau, Martin and Ludvigson, Sydney. “Time-Varying Risk-Premia and the Cost of Capital: An Alternative Implication of the q Theory of Investment.” Journal of Monetary Economics, January 2002, 49(1), pp. 31-66. Expected Stock Market Returns and Business Investment\",\"PeriodicalId\":305484,\"journal\":{\"name\":\"National Economic Trends\",\"volume\":\"105 1\",\"pages\":\"0\"},\"PeriodicalIF\":0.0000,\"publicationDate\":\"1900-01-01\",\"publicationTypes\":\"Journal Article\",\"fieldsOfStudy\":null,\"isOpenAccess\":false,\"openAccessPdf\":\"\",\"citationCount\":\"2\",\"resultStr\":null,\"platform\":\"Semanticscholar\",\"paperid\":null,\"PeriodicalName\":\"National Economic Trends\",\"FirstCategoryId\":\"1085\",\"ListUrlMain\":\"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2002.17\",\"RegionNum\":0,\"RegionCategory\":null,\"ArticlePicture\":[],\"TitleCN\":null,\"AbstractTextCN\":null,\"PMCID\":null,\"EPubDate\":\"\",\"PubModel\":\"\",\"JCR\":\"\",\"JCRName\":\"\",\"Score\":null,\"Total\":0}","platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"National Economic Trends","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.20955/ES.2002.17","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 2

摘要

大多数金融经济学家都会同意,股票的预期回报率在不同时间会有所不同。当然,这种预期收益的变化只能解释实际收益变化的一小部分。因此,试图把握市场时机仍然是一项有风险的努力,许多厌恶风险的投资者倾向于买入并持有投资。另一方面,商业投资项目在本质上不可避免地具有“起伏性”,企业有强烈的动机等待最有利可图的时期来投资不可逆转的大型项目。我们是否看到任何证据表明,企业投资是影响股市预期回报的关键因素?如果是这样,企业投资目前的前景如何?最近,Lettau和Ludvigson(2001)表明,消费与总财富的偏差,他们称之为消费-财富比,是预期股票收益的一个有用指标,特别是预期收益的长期变化他们对总财富的衡量包括金融资产和劳动收入的现值。消费财富比的预测能力与将消费视为前瞻性变量的经济理论是一致的。如果投资者预见到未来股票回报会更高,他们现在就会增加消费,以使消费平稳。因此,消费财富比的高(低)水平表明未来股票的预期回报高(低)。与消费决策一样,商业投资在预期资本回报方面也是前瞻性的。如果预期回报上升,现在投入的新资本预计将获得那些高回报。由此可见,消费财富比的变动应该预示着商业投资的变动,因为消费财富比包含了有关股票预期收益的信息。Lettau和Ludvigson(2002)表明,这种关系存在于二战后的数据中随附的图表展示了他们的主要结果。细虚线是消费财富比,粗实线是随后三年固定私人非住宅投资的平均增长率。一般来说,高水平的消费财富比与高的未来投资率相关,这两个变量之间的相关系数约为0.40。商业周期(图表中以衰退条形突出)似乎是股市预期回报率变化的一个重要来源。消费财富比和商业投资之间的相关性在过去十年中显得尤为强烈。20世纪90年代初,相对较高的消费-财富比率先于随后几年股市价格和商业投资的急剧增长。然而,在20世纪90年代后期,消费的增长速度并没有赶上金融财富的增长速度,消费财富比降到了一个异常低的水平。伴随着这种低预期回报的信号,投资和股票价格在2000年初开始回落,经济最终在2001年第一季度陷入衰退。目前,消费财富比已大大高于近期的低点,但仍未达到表明企业投资将成为新一轮经济扩张强劲驱动力的水平。Lettau, Martin和Ludvigson,悉尼。“消费、总财富和预期股票收益。”金融学报,2001,56(3),pp. 815- 849。Lettau, Martin和Ludvigson,悉尼。时变风险溢价与资本成本:q投资理论的另一种含义。货币经济学报,2002,49(1),pp. 31-66。预期股票市场回报和商业投资
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
Expected stock market returns and business investment
M ost financial economists would agree that expected stock returns vary somewhat across time. Of course, this variation in expected returns explains only a small fraction of the variation in actual returns. Consequently, attempting to time the market remains a risky endeavor and many risk-averse investors favor buy-and-hold investing. Busi ness investment projects, on the other hand, are unavoidably “lumpy” by nature and firms have strong incentives to wait for the most profitable periods to invest in irreversible, largescale projects. Do we see any evidence that business investment keys off expected stock market returns, and, if so, what is the current outlook for business investment? Recently, Lettau and Ludvigson (2001) showed that the deviation of consumption from aggregate wealth, which they label as the consumption-wealth ratio, is a useful indicator of expected stock returns, especially long-lasting shifts in expected returns.1 Their measure of aggregate wealth includes both financial assets and the present value of labor income. The predictive ability of the consumption-wealth ratio is consistent with the economic theory that views consumption as a forwardlooking variable. If investors foresee higher stock returns in the future, they will boost their consumption now to smooth consumption. Therefore, a high (low) level of the consumptionwealth ratio indicates high (low) expected stock returns in the future. Like consumption decisions, business investment is also forward-looking with respect to expected returns to capital. If expected returns shift upward, new capital put in place now is expected to garner those high returns. It follows that movements in the consumption-wealth ratio should presage movements in business investment because the consumption-wealth ratio contains information about expected stock returns. Lettau and Ludvigson (2002) show that this relationship is present in the post-World War II data.2 The accompanying chart demonstrates their main results. The thin dashed line is the consumption-wealth ratio and the thick solid line is the average growth rate of fixed, private nonresidential investment in the three subsequent years. In general, a high level of the consumption-wealth ratio is associated with high rates of future investment and the coefficient of correlation between these two variables is about 0.40. The business cycle, highlighted with recession bars in the chart, appears to be a significant source of variation in expected stock market returns. The correlation between the consumption-wealth ratio and business investment appears particularly strong in the last decade. Relatively high levels of the consumption-wealth ratio in the early 1990s preceded dramatic increases in both stock market prices and business invest ment in the subsequent years. Later in the 1990s, however, consumption did not rise at the same pace that financial wealth increased and the consumptionwealth ratio fell to an unusually low level. With this signal of low expected returns, investment and stock prices began to retreat in early 2000 and the economy eventually went into recession in the first quarter of 2001. At present, the consumptionwealth ratio is substantially above its recent trough, but it is still not at a level that suggests that business investment will be a strong driver of a new economic expansion. Lettau, Martin and Ludvigson, Sydney. “Consumption, Aggregate Wealth, and Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, June 2001, 56(3), pp. 815-49. Lettau, Martin and Ludvigson, Sydney. “Time-Varying Risk-Premia and the Cost of Capital: An Alternative Implication of the q Theory of Investment.” Journal of Monetary Economics, January 2002, 49(1), pp. 31-66. Expected Stock Market Returns and Business Investment
求助全文
通过发布文献求助,成功后即可免费获取论文全文。 去求助
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信