Team Collaboration in Innovation Contests

Sıdıka Tunç Candoğan, C. G. Korpeoglu, Christopher S. Tang
{"title":"Team Collaboration in Innovation Contests","authors":"Sıdıka Tunç Candoğan, C. G. Korpeoglu, Christopher S. Tang","doi":"10.2139/ssrn.3607769","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"In an innovation contest, an organizer elicits solutions to an innovation-related problem from a group of internal solvers (e.g., in-house employees) or from a group of external solvers (e.g., crowdsourcing-platform members). These solvers may develop individual solutions and make individual submissions, or if the organizer encourages it, they may collaborate as teams and make team submissions. The quality of an individual (resp., team) submission depends on the solver's (resp., team's) effort as well as the solver's (resp., team's) output shock. Motivated from different policies adopted by various crowdsourcing platforms in practice, we identify conditions under which the organizer and solvers can benefit from team submissions. By examining equilibrium outcomes of a game-theoretic model, we show that both the organizer and solvers may benefit from team submissions when the organizer seeks solutions to a shock-driven problem from external solvers (e.g., via a crowdsourcing platform). However, the organizer may not benefit from team submissions when he seeks solutions to an effort-driven problem from external solvers. These results provide a plausible explanation for why some platforms encourage team submissions, while others discourage them. Interestingly, we also show that when the organizer elicits solutions to an effort-driven problem from internal solvers, the organizer may benefit from team submissions but internal solvers may not. In this case, it may be advisable for the organizer to obligate solvers to make team submissions, if possible.","PeriodicalId":82888,"journal":{"name":"Technology (Elmsford, N.Y.)","volume":"C-19 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2020-05-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"6","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Technology (Elmsford, N.Y.)","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3607769","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 6

Abstract

In an innovation contest, an organizer elicits solutions to an innovation-related problem from a group of internal solvers (e.g., in-house employees) or from a group of external solvers (e.g., crowdsourcing-platform members). These solvers may develop individual solutions and make individual submissions, or if the organizer encourages it, they may collaborate as teams and make team submissions. The quality of an individual (resp., team) submission depends on the solver's (resp., team's) effort as well as the solver's (resp., team's) output shock. Motivated from different policies adopted by various crowdsourcing platforms in practice, we identify conditions under which the organizer and solvers can benefit from team submissions. By examining equilibrium outcomes of a game-theoretic model, we show that both the organizer and solvers may benefit from team submissions when the organizer seeks solutions to a shock-driven problem from external solvers (e.g., via a crowdsourcing platform). However, the organizer may not benefit from team submissions when he seeks solutions to an effort-driven problem from external solvers. These results provide a plausible explanation for why some platforms encourage team submissions, while others discourage them. Interestingly, we also show that when the organizer elicits solutions to an effort-driven problem from internal solvers, the organizer may benefit from team submissions but internal solvers may not. In this case, it may be advisable for the organizer to obligate solvers to make team submissions, if possible.
创新竞赛中的团队协作
在创新竞赛中,组织者从一组内部解决者(例如,内部员工)或一组外部解决者(例如,众包平台成员)中引出与创新相关的问题的解决方案。这些解决者可以开发个人解决方案并进行个人提交,或者如果组织者鼓励这样做,他们可以作为团队合作并进行团队提交。个人素质:一个人的素质。(团队)的提交取决于求解者的回答。(团队的)努力以及解决者的(回应)。(团队的)输出冲击。根据不同众包平台在实践中采取的不同政策,我们确定了组织者和解决者可以从团队提交中受益的条件。通过检查博弈论模型的均衡结果,我们表明,当组织者从外部解决者(例如,通过众包平台)寻求冲击驱动问题的解决方案时,组织者和解决者都可能从团队提交中受益。然而,当组织者从外部解决者那里寻求解决努力驱动问题的方法时,他可能不会从团队提交的内容中受益。这些结果合理地解释了为什么有些平台鼓励团队提交,而有些平台则不鼓励团队提交。有趣的是,我们还表明,当组织者从内部解决者那里引出努力驱动问题的解决方案时,组织者可能会从团队提交的意见中受益,但内部解决者可能不会。在这种情况下,如果可能的话,组织者可能会要求解决者进行团队提交。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信