Commercializing Open Source Software: Do Property Rights Still Matter?

Ronald J. Mann
{"title":"Commercializing Open Source Software: Do Property Rights Still Matter?","authors":"Ronald J. Mann","doi":"10.7916/D8MW2GJ9","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"TABLE OF CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION II. THE LANDSCAPE A. The Proprietary Software Model 1. Formation and Maturation of the Proprietary Software Industry 2. Software Licensing Under Proprietary Models 3. Cross-Licensing: the Proprietary Equilibrium B. The Open Source Development Model 1. The Current State of Open Source: Commercialization 2. Software Products Licenses Under Open Source Models III. MOTIVATIONS FOR THE COMMERCIALIZATION OF OPEN SOURCE A. Open Source as a Viable Business Model 1. Predatory Motive: the \"Kill Microsoft\" Approach 2. Traditional Profit Motive: the Value Chain Approach B. Open Source as a Market Correction IV. THE EFFECT OF COMMERCIALIZED OPEN SOURCE A. Effect on Industry Organization and Innovation B. Effect on Intellectual Property Rights V. CONCLUSION I. INTRODUCTION For several years now, open source software products have been gaining prominence and market share. Yet the products themselves are not as provocative as the way in which they are developed and distributed. Two related features of the open source model are distinctive: the use of collaborative development structures that extend beyond the boundaries of a single firm, and the lack of reliance on intellectual property (\"IP\") rights as a means of appropriating the value of the underlying technologies. Firm-level control of intellectual property is replaced by a complex set of relations, both informal and sometimes contractual, among strategic partners not joined by firm boundaries. I argue here that those relations reflect not coalescence towards industry norms driven solely by superior output, but rather a series of strategic moves and countermoves that have had the effect of opening some markets while closing others, substantially reducing profit margins, and fostering consolidation of a traditionally fragmented industry. I have written elsewhere about the role of intellectual property rights in proprietary models of software development, where intellectual property rights are used (albeit somewhat ineffectively) by firms to exploit the value of their internal research and development (\"R&D\") investments. In that work, I generally reject the idea that the sheer number of patents is creating a thicket that deters innovation, largely because of the evidence of a robust startup market and of investors' lack of concern about patents held by competitors. More generally, I argue that many of the criticisms of software patents fail to account for the potential benefits those patents provide to smaller firms and focus much too heavily on the transaction costs associated with the massive patent portfolios that the larger industry participants have acquired (the so-called \"arms race\" build up). (1) Open source development models work differently. Because open source development proceeds on the premise that no individual or firm will have proprietary control of the software, the firms participating in those development projects might have little need for patents. The cooperative nature of development obviates any need for the actual and implicit cross licensing that provides access to technology throughout the proprietary software sector. The problem, however, is that the open source community does not exist in a vacuum. It exists in a world in which participants in the industry are building up large portfolios of patents, portfolios that pose a serious threat to open source development. Therefore, any thorough analysis of the role of patents in the industry must take account of the effects of the current property rights system on all participants. This Article takes up that issue. In essence, the problem is that open source developers can and often do operate outside of the IP licensing framework that dominates the software industry. Thus, many participants have no patents of their own with which they might protect themselves in IP litigation. …","PeriodicalId":81374,"journal":{"name":"Harvard journal of law & technology","volume":"125 4","pages":"1-47"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2006-09-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"46","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Harvard journal of law & technology","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.7916/D8MW2GJ9","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 46

Abstract

TABLE OF CONTENTS I. INTRODUCTION II. THE LANDSCAPE A. The Proprietary Software Model 1. Formation and Maturation of the Proprietary Software Industry 2. Software Licensing Under Proprietary Models 3. Cross-Licensing: the Proprietary Equilibrium B. The Open Source Development Model 1. The Current State of Open Source: Commercialization 2. Software Products Licenses Under Open Source Models III. MOTIVATIONS FOR THE COMMERCIALIZATION OF OPEN SOURCE A. Open Source as a Viable Business Model 1. Predatory Motive: the "Kill Microsoft" Approach 2. Traditional Profit Motive: the Value Chain Approach B. Open Source as a Market Correction IV. THE EFFECT OF COMMERCIALIZED OPEN SOURCE A. Effect on Industry Organization and Innovation B. Effect on Intellectual Property Rights V. CONCLUSION I. INTRODUCTION For several years now, open source software products have been gaining prominence and market share. Yet the products themselves are not as provocative as the way in which they are developed and distributed. Two related features of the open source model are distinctive: the use of collaborative development structures that extend beyond the boundaries of a single firm, and the lack of reliance on intellectual property ("IP") rights as a means of appropriating the value of the underlying technologies. Firm-level control of intellectual property is replaced by a complex set of relations, both informal and sometimes contractual, among strategic partners not joined by firm boundaries. I argue here that those relations reflect not coalescence towards industry norms driven solely by superior output, but rather a series of strategic moves and countermoves that have had the effect of opening some markets while closing others, substantially reducing profit margins, and fostering consolidation of a traditionally fragmented industry. I have written elsewhere about the role of intellectual property rights in proprietary models of software development, where intellectual property rights are used (albeit somewhat ineffectively) by firms to exploit the value of their internal research and development ("R&D") investments. In that work, I generally reject the idea that the sheer number of patents is creating a thicket that deters innovation, largely because of the evidence of a robust startup market and of investors' lack of concern about patents held by competitors. More generally, I argue that many of the criticisms of software patents fail to account for the potential benefits those patents provide to smaller firms and focus much too heavily on the transaction costs associated with the massive patent portfolios that the larger industry participants have acquired (the so-called "arms race" build up). (1) Open source development models work differently. Because open source development proceeds on the premise that no individual or firm will have proprietary control of the software, the firms participating in those development projects might have little need for patents. The cooperative nature of development obviates any need for the actual and implicit cross licensing that provides access to technology throughout the proprietary software sector. The problem, however, is that the open source community does not exist in a vacuum. It exists in a world in which participants in the industry are building up large portfolios of patents, portfolios that pose a serious threat to open source development. Therefore, any thorough analysis of the role of patents in the industry must take account of the effects of the current property rights system on all participants. This Article takes up that issue. In essence, the problem is that open source developers can and often do operate outside of the IP licensing framework that dominates the software industry. Thus, many participants have no patents of their own with which they might protect themselves in IP litigation. …
开源软件商业化:产权还重要吗?
目录1 .引言2 .前言A.专有软件模型专有软件产业的形成与成熟专有模式下的软件许可交叉许可:私有均衡B.开源开发模式开源的现状:商业化开源模式下的软件产品许可开源商业化的动机a .开源作为一种可行的商业模式掠夺性动机:“杀死微软”方法传统利润动机:价值链方法B.开源作为市场修正IV.开源商业化的影响a .对行业组织和创新的影响B.对知识产权的影响V.结论I.引言几年来,开源软件产品逐渐得到重视和市场份额。然而,这些产品本身并不像它们的开发和销售方式那样具有挑衅性。开源模式的两个相关特征是独特的:使用超越单个公司边界的协作开发结构,以及缺乏对知识产权(“IP”)权利的依赖,作为占用底层技术价值的手段。企业层面的知识产权控制被一系列复杂的关系所取代,这些关系既有非正式的,有时也有契约关系,这些关系是在没有企业边界的战略合作伙伴之间建立起来的。我在这里认为,这些关系反映的不是仅仅由优质产出驱动的行业规范的合并,而是一系列战略举措和对策,这些举措和对策开放了一些市场,关闭了另一些市场,大幅降低了利润率,并促进了传统上分散的行业的整合。我曾在其他地方写过关于知识产权在软件开发的专有模型中的作用,在这些模型中,知识产权被公司用来(尽管有些无效)利用其内部研究和开发(“R&D”)投资的价值。在那篇文章中,我通常不同意专利数量之多正在制造阻碍创新的障碍的观点,这主要是因为有证据表明,初创企业市场非常强劲,而且投资者对竞争对手持有的专利并不关心。更一般地说,我认为许多对软件专利的批评没有考虑到这些专利为小公司提供的潜在好处,而过于关注与大型行业参与者获得的大量专利组合相关的交易成本(所谓的“军备竞赛”建立)。(1)开源开发模型的工作方式不同。因为开源开发是在没有个人或公司对软件拥有专有控制权的前提下进行的,所以参与这些开发项目的公司可能不太需要专利。开发的合作性质消除了对实际的和隐含的交叉许可的任何需要,这种交叉许可提供了对整个专有软件部门技术的访问。然而,问题是开源社区并不是存在于真空中。它存在于一个行业参与者正在建立大量专利组合的世界中,这些专利组合对开源开发构成了严重威胁。因此,任何对专利在产业中的作用的深入分析都必须考虑到当前产权制度对所有参与者的影响。这篇文章讨论了那个问题。本质上,问题在于开源开发者可以并且经常在主导软件行业的IP许可框架之外操作。因此,许多参与者没有自己的专利,可以在知识产权诉讼中保护自己。…
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信