The Political Economy of Southeast Asia: Politics and Uneven Development under Hyperglobalisation (Fourth Edition) - edited by Toby Carroll, Shahar Hameiri and Lee Jones (eds), Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, Springer Nature Switzerland A.G., Pp. xxvi + 412, ISBN 978-3-030-28254-7, 978-3-030-28255-4 (ebook)

IF 1.1 4区 经济学 Q3 ECONOMICS
Anne Booth
{"title":"The Political Economy of Southeast Asia: Politics and Uneven Development under Hyperglobalisation (Fourth Edition) - edited by Toby Carroll, Shahar Hameiri and Lee Jones (eds), Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, Springer Nature Switzerland A.G., Pp. xxvi + 412, ISBN 978-3-030-28254-7, 978-3-030-28255-4 (ebook)","authors":"Anne Booth","doi":"10.1111/apel.12322","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>The usefulness of this approach in Southeast Asia in 2020 can be queried for reasons that will be discussed in more detail below. But there can be no doubt that it has resonated with scholars working in countries and academic environments well beyond Australia. Only one of the three editors of this volume is based in an Australian university, and of the 19 contributors only three are based at Murdoch itself. Eight are based outside Australia, in a diverse range of institutions across the USA, England, Japan, and Hong Kong; although only one is from Southeast Asia (Indonesia). Indeed it can be argued that the Murdoch School has had greater influence on the study of Southeast Asia over the past three decades than any other Australian academic group, except perhaps those associated with the Australian National University.</p><p>The authors suggest that mainstream or neo-liberal economics is characterised by an emphasis on rolling back the state in favour of private enterprise, a preference for private sector delivery of services such as health and education, and a tendency to deride redistributive policies such as progressive taxation. They view neo-liberal economic analysis as more ideological than theoretical. In fact modern economics is a much broader church than Hameiri and Jones seem willing to concede. Many economists including several Nobel prize winners in the discipline would advocate a stronger role for the state in developing countries, particularly in the provision of public goods and services, including infrastructure, health, and education. They also accept that interventions including conditional cash transfers can play a useful role in reducing poverty. To equate modern economic analysis with the more extreme views of Tea Party activists in the USA is neither accurate nor helpful in assessing its role in helping to solve the serious economic and social problems that confront many countries across the world.</p><p>Hameiri and Jones are on stronger ground when they point out that the Northeast Asian developmental state model was in several respects a poor empirical fit in the context of Southeast Asia. In the decades after 1960, several countries in the region failed to expand education beyond the primary level at a sufficiently rapid pace to meet the growing needs of the labour market. In Thailand, serious labour shortages were emerging by the late 1980s, which drove up labour costs and encouraged many firms to relocate to lower-wage countries including China and Vietnam. Even Singapore was slow to learn from the Taiwanese and Korean examples and expand post-secondary education, especially in science and technology. It still depends heavily on skilled labour from abroad in high-technology manufacturing and in the financial sector. Indonesia inherited a meagre educational legacy from the Dutch colonial era, and was slow to expand education beyond the primary level, even when government revenues grew after 1970. The Philippines inherited a more extensive education system from the American period, and even today has a better educated labour force than most of its ASEAN neighbours. But its slow economic growth, especially in the last two decades of the 20th century, combined with quite rapid population growth, meant that the domestic economy could not absorb the output of the school and university systems. The Philippines began to export workers in the 1960s and the numbers of migrant workers have grown rapidly over the past five decades.</p><p>All this is well known and has been widely discussed in many studies of Southeast Asian economic development over the years, including those written by mainstream economists, as well as authors who might prefer to call themselves historical institutionalists. In explaining the very diverse development outcomes in Southeast Asia and elsewhere, what does the Murdoch approach have to offer beyond these other approaches? Hameiri and Jones claim that the crucial context for the Murdoch approach is provided by ‘the global set of class relations attending capitalism and the manner in which they relate to locally variegated patterns of investment, production and consumption as well as geo-political considerations’ (p. 17). They go on to argue that economic development does not occur just because technocrats, shielded from political pressures, implement ‘good policies’, but because there have been since the 1950s a set of global dynamics including the Cold War and globalisation that have pushed the Southeast Asian countries to follow a particular set of policies. This may well be true, at least compared with low and middle-income countries in other parts of the world that have failed to achieve the GDP growth rates achieved in Southeast Asia since the 1960s.</p><p>But these policies have also produced diverse outcomes across the region. This is made clear in Chapter 2, where Carroll produces a range of statistics on GDP, population, poverty rates, and other indicators referring to the labour force, international trade, and tax policy. Most of these indicators are reproduced uncritically from World Bank, the International Labour Organization, and Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development sources. For what they are worth, they show diverse outcomes across the region, although not much attempt is made to explain the differences. Why are the various poverty indicators shown in figure 2.1 so much better for Thailand and Vietnam than for the Philippines or Indonesia? Perhaps the superior Thai performance can be explained in terms of faster GDP growth in the decades from 1957 to 1997, but Carroll does not really engage with the data on economic growth. The Vietnamese data may be flawed, but indicators on both education and health do show that Vietnam has performed very well for a low-middle-income country that only seriously began to engage with the regional and global economy in the mid-1990s. Why the differences?</p><p>These are not questions that Carroll addresses; rather she stresses the fact that most countries in Southeast Asia have historically grown on the back of exports of raw materials. The export diversification into manufactured exports has mainly been based on low to medium technology products, often made in factories owned by foreign companies which can re-locate if local conditions, including wage rates, change. No country in Southeast Asia, not even Singapore, has followed the Taiwanese or Korean examples in developing their own national champions. After stellar growth in Singapore, and five decades of solid growth in Malaysia, Thailand, and Indonesia between 1969 and 2019, there is no Hyundai or Samsung to be found. Companies from Japan, Taiwan, and South Korea manufacture components and assemble products across Southeast Asia, taking advantage of cheaper labour, but the development of new products is done at home, or in other developed economies.</p><p>Many researchers have addressed these problems over the years, although Carroll does not discuss their work in any detail, perhaps because it does not always fit into the ‘Murdoch’ template. Several studies have contrasted education policy in Taiwan and Korea with that in Thailand, Singapore, Malaysia, and Indonesia and pointed out that whereas Taiwan and Korea educated ahead of demand, the Southeast Asian countries have under-invested in post-primary education. Perhaps the Murdoch explanation for this failure would be that many governments in the regions are dominated by powerful oligarchs whose interests would not be served by a more progressive tax system. The resulting failure to mobilise domestic revenues means that government resources for education and health are limited and often the best services are only available in the private sector, where fees are high relative to average incomes. Yet educational reform has occurred, and in recent decades countries such as Indonesia and Thailand have seen a rapid improvement in the educational qualifications of both the male and female labour force. To what extent are these improvements linked to smaller families and a desire by families to invest in their children's education? The complex relationships between demographic change and the development of human resources are not addressed directly by Carroll or by other contributors. References to education, health, or population cannot be found in the index.</p><p>The Murdoch School prefers to focus on the growth of large conglomerates, which have grown on the back of cronyistic links to ruling families, and which have not displayed much interest in building up internationally competitive industries in medium to high technology sectors. More broadly, they argue that despite the various regime changes that have occurred in the region, Southeast Asian countries continue to be ruled by oligarchies, where power is concentrated, and narrow elites dominate policymaking (Rodin and Baker, pp. 91–92). They argue that, despite the changes that have occurred in several countries since the 1990s, oligarchs have managed to regroup and use their financial and political power to maintain or even extend their control over the levers of power. Where significant decentralisation measures have been implemented (Indonesia is the main example cited), fresh avenues for corruption and patronage have been provided that have benefited various oligarchic groups. Although Rodin and Baker (p. 88) acknowledge that economic growth in many parts of the region has produced a growing middle class with consumption patterns oriented to those found in high-income countries, they argue that this new middle class is directly or indirectly dependent on the state and lacks both the will and the capacity to challenge oligarchic power—although they do admit that Southeast Asian oligarchs face challenges from new social forces such as non-governmental organisations.</p><p>Rodin and Baker do not produce much evidence to support their arguments about middle class dependency on the state. Some of the figures given by Carroll support an alternative view that in several countries in the region central governments are rather weak, and indeed might have become weaker over the past two decades. Government expenditures relative to GDP in most parts of the region are much lower than the OECD average, and in Indonesia have fallen since the 1980s. In Indonesia, Thailand, and the Philippines, it is far from obvious that the growing middle class is dependent on the state; recent research has suggested that many are working in professional, technical and administrative occupations in the private sector. While some large private sector conglomerates may be linked to powerful political figures, and depend on them for preferential treatment in the granting of contracts, their employees comprise only a small proportion of the middle class.</p><p>In their chapter on populism in Southeast Asia, Robison and Hadiz argue that politicians such as Joko Widodo, Thaksin, and Duterte have all sought popularity by adopting programs that aim to improve health and social welfare for poorer groups, as well as providing improved infrastructure in both urban and rural areas. In Thailand, Thaksin's brand of reforming populism was unpopular with Bangkok elites, and led to his overthrow by a conservative coalition of the army and monarchist forces, although some of his policies have been continued by subsequent governments. In Indonesia and the Philippines, it would appear that a combination of reasonable economic growth and social welfare policies have led to some decline in poverty in recent years, although disparities in income and wealth remain high. But Robison and Hadiz point out that ‘genuine social democratic’ parties have not emerged in these countries that are committed to further social and economic reform, so the policies of Duterte and Joko Widodo will be vulnerable to the ‘chaos and upheavals often unleashed by neoliberalising economic projects’ (p. 171).</p><p>Most of the other chapters in this volume take up the theme of growing social resentment brought about by ‘neoliberal economic policies’ that uproot large sections of the population, deepen inequalities, destroy old certainties and communities, and force both men and women into new forms of work that are often both precarious and unpleasant. It is implied that neoliberal policies are exclusively concerned with economic growth and ignore the powerful vested interests, at both the national and international level, who insure that most of the benefits of growth accrue to them and their associates, leaving large sections of the population marginalised and impoverished. Governments and politicians are seen as tools of these interest groups, and lack either the ability or the will to act in the broader national interest.</p><p>Given that most contributors to this volume agree with Hirsch that class, power, and social conflict are important determinants of development outcomes in Southeast Asia, it is perhaps surprising that no author really explores what these terms mean in the context of contemporary Southeast Asian societies. Most contributors seem to agree that the middle class is growing everywhere in the region but offer little guidance as to how the middle class should be defined or measured. Three decades ago, ownership of a motor cycle or a hand phone might have been sufficient to classify a person as middle class; but by 2020 these products are available to the great majority. And even if the middle class is growing, what are the implications for future conflicts? If class conflict is the inevitable result of capitalist development, then why is it that much of the recent conflict across Southeast Asia appears to have resulted from religious and ethnic antagonisms? Is class, however defined, really a useful concept in examining both the causes and consequences of economic change in Asia? Perhaps this question will be explored in future volumes from these authors.</p>","PeriodicalId":44776,"journal":{"name":"Asian-Pacific Economic Literature","volume":"35 1","pages":"153-157"},"PeriodicalIF":1.1000,"publicationDate":"2021-03-22","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/apel.12322","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Asian-Pacific Economic Literature","FirstCategoryId":"96","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/apel.12322","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

The usefulness of this approach in Southeast Asia in 2020 can be queried for reasons that will be discussed in more detail below. But there can be no doubt that it has resonated with scholars working in countries and academic environments well beyond Australia. Only one of the three editors of this volume is based in an Australian university, and of the 19 contributors only three are based at Murdoch itself. Eight are based outside Australia, in a diverse range of institutions across the USA, England, Japan, and Hong Kong; although only one is from Southeast Asia (Indonesia). Indeed it can be argued that the Murdoch School has had greater influence on the study of Southeast Asia over the past three decades than any other Australian academic group, except perhaps those associated with the Australian National University.

The authors suggest that mainstream or neo-liberal economics is characterised by an emphasis on rolling back the state in favour of private enterprise, a preference for private sector delivery of services such as health and education, and a tendency to deride redistributive policies such as progressive taxation. They view neo-liberal economic analysis as more ideological than theoretical. In fact modern economics is a much broader church than Hameiri and Jones seem willing to concede. Many economists including several Nobel prize winners in the discipline would advocate a stronger role for the state in developing countries, particularly in the provision of public goods and services, including infrastructure, health, and education. They also accept that interventions including conditional cash transfers can play a useful role in reducing poverty. To equate modern economic analysis with the more extreme views of Tea Party activists in the USA is neither accurate nor helpful in assessing its role in helping to solve the serious economic and social problems that confront many countries across the world.

Hameiri and Jones are on stronger ground when they point out that the Northeast Asian developmental state model was in several respects a poor empirical fit in the context of Southeast Asia. In the decades after 1960, several countries in the region failed to expand education beyond the primary level at a sufficiently rapid pace to meet the growing needs of the labour market. In Thailand, serious labour shortages were emerging by the late 1980s, which drove up labour costs and encouraged many firms to relocate to lower-wage countries including China and Vietnam. Even Singapore was slow to learn from the Taiwanese and Korean examples and expand post-secondary education, especially in science and technology. It still depends heavily on skilled labour from abroad in high-technology manufacturing and in the financial sector. Indonesia inherited a meagre educational legacy from the Dutch colonial era, and was slow to expand education beyond the primary level, even when government revenues grew after 1970. The Philippines inherited a more extensive education system from the American period, and even today has a better educated labour force than most of its ASEAN neighbours. But its slow economic growth, especially in the last two decades of the 20th century, combined with quite rapid population growth, meant that the domestic economy could not absorb the output of the school and university systems. The Philippines began to export workers in the 1960s and the numbers of migrant workers have grown rapidly over the past five decades.

All this is well known and has been widely discussed in many studies of Southeast Asian economic development over the years, including those written by mainstream economists, as well as authors who might prefer to call themselves historical institutionalists. In explaining the very diverse development outcomes in Southeast Asia and elsewhere, what does the Murdoch approach have to offer beyond these other approaches? Hameiri and Jones claim that the crucial context for the Murdoch approach is provided by ‘the global set of class relations attending capitalism and the manner in which they relate to locally variegated patterns of investment, production and consumption as well as geo-political considerations’ (p. 17). They go on to argue that economic development does not occur just because technocrats, shielded from political pressures, implement ‘good policies’, but because there have been since the 1950s a set of global dynamics including the Cold War and globalisation that have pushed the Southeast Asian countries to follow a particular set of policies. This may well be true, at least compared with low and middle-income countries in other parts of the world that have failed to achieve the GDP growth rates achieved in Southeast Asia since the 1960s.

But these policies have also produced diverse outcomes across the region. This is made clear in Chapter 2, where Carroll produces a range of statistics on GDP, population, poverty rates, and other indicators referring to the labour force, international trade, and tax policy. Most of these indicators are reproduced uncritically from World Bank, the International Labour Organization, and Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development sources. For what they are worth, they show diverse outcomes across the region, although not much attempt is made to explain the differences. Why are the various poverty indicators shown in figure 2.1 so much better for Thailand and Vietnam than for the Philippines or Indonesia? Perhaps the superior Thai performance can be explained in terms of faster GDP growth in the decades from 1957 to 1997, but Carroll does not really engage with the data on economic growth. The Vietnamese data may be flawed, but indicators on both education and health do show that Vietnam has performed very well for a low-middle-income country that only seriously began to engage with the regional and global economy in the mid-1990s. Why the differences?

These are not questions that Carroll addresses; rather she stresses the fact that most countries in Southeast Asia have historically grown on the back of exports of raw materials. The export diversification into manufactured exports has mainly been based on low to medium technology products, often made in factories owned by foreign companies which can re-locate if local conditions, including wage rates, change. No country in Southeast Asia, not even Singapore, has followed the Taiwanese or Korean examples in developing their own national champions. After stellar growth in Singapore, and five decades of solid growth in Malaysia, Thailand, and Indonesia between 1969 and 2019, there is no Hyundai or Samsung to be found. Companies from Japan, Taiwan, and South Korea manufacture components and assemble products across Southeast Asia, taking advantage of cheaper labour, but the development of new products is done at home, or in other developed economies.

Many researchers have addressed these problems over the years, although Carroll does not discuss their work in any detail, perhaps because it does not always fit into the ‘Murdoch’ template. Several studies have contrasted education policy in Taiwan and Korea with that in Thailand, Singapore, Malaysia, and Indonesia and pointed out that whereas Taiwan and Korea educated ahead of demand, the Southeast Asian countries have under-invested in post-primary education. Perhaps the Murdoch explanation for this failure would be that many governments in the regions are dominated by powerful oligarchs whose interests would not be served by a more progressive tax system. The resulting failure to mobilise domestic revenues means that government resources for education and health are limited and often the best services are only available in the private sector, where fees are high relative to average incomes. Yet educational reform has occurred, and in recent decades countries such as Indonesia and Thailand have seen a rapid improvement in the educational qualifications of both the male and female labour force. To what extent are these improvements linked to smaller families and a desire by families to invest in their children's education? The complex relationships between demographic change and the development of human resources are not addressed directly by Carroll or by other contributors. References to education, health, or population cannot be found in the index.

The Murdoch School prefers to focus on the growth of large conglomerates, which have grown on the back of cronyistic links to ruling families, and which have not displayed much interest in building up internationally competitive industries in medium to high technology sectors. More broadly, they argue that despite the various regime changes that have occurred in the region, Southeast Asian countries continue to be ruled by oligarchies, where power is concentrated, and narrow elites dominate policymaking (Rodin and Baker, pp. 91–92). They argue that, despite the changes that have occurred in several countries since the 1990s, oligarchs have managed to regroup and use their financial and political power to maintain or even extend their control over the levers of power. Where significant decentralisation measures have been implemented (Indonesia is the main example cited), fresh avenues for corruption and patronage have been provided that have benefited various oligarchic groups. Although Rodin and Baker (p. 88) acknowledge that economic growth in many parts of the region has produced a growing middle class with consumption patterns oriented to those found in high-income countries, they argue that this new middle class is directly or indirectly dependent on the state and lacks both the will and the capacity to challenge oligarchic power—although they do admit that Southeast Asian oligarchs face challenges from new social forces such as non-governmental organisations.

Rodin and Baker do not produce much evidence to support their arguments about middle class dependency on the state. Some of the figures given by Carroll support an alternative view that in several countries in the region central governments are rather weak, and indeed might have become weaker over the past two decades. Government expenditures relative to GDP in most parts of the region are much lower than the OECD average, and in Indonesia have fallen since the 1980s. In Indonesia, Thailand, and the Philippines, it is far from obvious that the growing middle class is dependent on the state; recent research has suggested that many are working in professional, technical and administrative occupations in the private sector. While some large private sector conglomerates may be linked to powerful political figures, and depend on them for preferential treatment in the granting of contracts, their employees comprise only a small proportion of the middle class.

In their chapter on populism in Southeast Asia, Robison and Hadiz argue that politicians such as Joko Widodo, Thaksin, and Duterte have all sought popularity by adopting programs that aim to improve health and social welfare for poorer groups, as well as providing improved infrastructure in both urban and rural areas. In Thailand, Thaksin's brand of reforming populism was unpopular with Bangkok elites, and led to his overthrow by a conservative coalition of the army and monarchist forces, although some of his policies have been continued by subsequent governments. In Indonesia and the Philippines, it would appear that a combination of reasonable economic growth and social welfare policies have led to some decline in poverty in recent years, although disparities in income and wealth remain high. But Robison and Hadiz point out that ‘genuine social democratic’ parties have not emerged in these countries that are committed to further social and economic reform, so the policies of Duterte and Joko Widodo will be vulnerable to the ‘chaos and upheavals often unleashed by neoliberalising economic projects’ (p. 171).

Most of the other chapters in this volume take up the theme of growing social resentment brought about by ‘neoliberal economic policies’ that uproot large sections of the population, deepen inequalities, destroy old certainties and communities, and force both men and women into new forms of work that are often both precarious and unpleasant. It is implied that neoliberal policies are exclusively concerned with economic growth and ignore the powerful vested interests, at both the national and international level, who insure that most of the benefits of growth accrue to them and their associates, leaving large sections of the population marginalised and impoverished. Governments and politicians are seen as tools of these interest groups, and lack either the ability or the will to act in the broader national interest.

Given that most contributors to this volume agree with Hirsch that class, power, and social conflict are important determinants of development outcomes in Southeast Asia, it is perhaps surprising that no author really explores what these terms mean in the context of contemporary Southeast Asian societies. Most contributors seem to agree that the middle class is growing everywhere in the region but offer little guidance as to how the middle class should be defined or measured. Three decades ago, ownership of a motor cycle or a hand phone might have been sufficient to classify a person as middle class; but by 2020 these products are available to the great majority. And even if the middle class is growing, what are the implications for future conflicts? If class conflict is the inevitable result of capitalist development, then why is it that much of the recent conflict across Southeast Asia appears to have resulted from religious and ethnic antagonisms? Is class, however defined, really a useful concept in examining both the causes and consequences of economic change in Asia? Perhaps this question will be explored in future volumes from these authors.

东南亚的政治经济学:超级全球化下的政治和不平衡发展(第四版)-由Toby Carroll, Shahar Hameiri和Lee Jones编辑(编辑),Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, b施普林格Nature Switzerland A.G, Pp. xxvi + 412, ISBN 978-3-030-28254- 7,978 -3-030-28255-4(电子书)
88)承认该地区许多地区的经济增长产生了一个不断壮大的中产阶级,其消费模式与高收入国家的消费模式相似,但他们认为,这个新的中产阶级直接或间接依赖于国家,缺乏挑战寡头权力的意愿和能力,尽管他们确实承认东南亚的寡头面临着来自非政府组织等新社会力量的挑战。罗丹和贝克没有拿出太多证据来支持他们关于中产阶级依赖国家的论点。卡罗尔给出的一些数据支持另一种观点,即该地区几个国家的中央政府相当软弱,而且在过去20年里确实可能变得更加软弱。该区域大多数国家的政府支出占国内生产总值的比例远低于经合发组织的平均水平,印度尼西亚自1980年代以来一直在下降。在印尼、泰国和菲律宾,不断壮大的中产阶级依赖政府的现象远不明显;最近的研究表明,许多人在私营部门从事专业、技术和行政工作。尽管一些大型私营企业集团可能与强大的政治人物有联系,并依赖他们在授予合同时获得优惠待遇,但它们的雇员只占中产阶级的一小部分。在他们关于东南亚民粹主义的章节中,罗宾逊和哈迪兹认为,佐科·维多多(Joko Widodo)、他信(Thaksin)和杜特尔特(Duterte)等政治家都通过实施旨在改善贫困群体健康和社会福利的计划,以及改善城市和农村地区的基础设施,来寻求人气。在泰国,他信的民粹主义改革不受曼谷精英的欢迎,并导致他被军队和君主主义势力组成的保守联盟推翻,尽管他的一些政策被后来的政府延续。在印度尼西亚和菲律宾,合理的经济增长和社会福利政策的结合似乎导致近年来贫穷有所减少,尽管收入和财富的差距仍然很大。但罗宾逊和哈迪兹指出,在这些致力于进一步社会和经济改革的国家中,“真正的社会民主主义”政党尚未出现,因此杜特尔特和佐科·维多多的政策将容易受到“新自由主义经济项目经常引发的混乱和动荡”的影响(第171页)。本卷的大多数其他章节都以“新自由主义经济政策”所带来的日益增长的社会怨恨为主题,这些政策将大部分人口连根拔起,加深了不平等,摧毁了旧的确定性和社区,并迫使男性和女性从事往往既不稳定又不愉快的新形式的工作。这意味着,新自由主义政策只关注经济增长,而忽视了强大的既得利益集团,无论是在国家层面还是在国际层面,这些既得利益集团都确保了增长的大部分好处都归他们自己和他们的同伙所有,而让大部分人口被边缘化和贫困。政府和政治家被视为这些利益集团的工具,既没有能力也没有意愿为更广泛的国家利益行事。考虑到本书的大多数作者都同意赫希的观点,即阶级、权力和社会冲突是东南亚发展结果的重要决定因素,也许令人惊讶的是,没有作者真正探讨这些术语在当代东南亚社会背景下的含义。大多数撰稿人似乎都同意,中产阶级在亚洲各地都在增长,但对于如何定义或衡量中产阶级,他们几乎没有提供任何指导。30年前,拥有一辆摩托车或一部手机可能足以将一个人归类为中产阶级;但到2020年,大多数人都能买到这些产品。即使中产阶级在壮大,这对未来的冲突又意味着什么呢?如果阶级冲突是资本主义发展不可避免的结果,那么为什么最近东南亚地区的许多冲突似乎是由宗教和种族对立造成的呢?阶级,无论如何定义,在研究亚洲经济变化的原因和后果时,真的是一个有用的概念吗?也许这个问题将在这些作者的未来卷中进行探讨。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
CiteScore
1.70
自引率
0.00%
发文量
27
期刊介绍: Asian-Pacific Economic Literature (APEL) is an essential resource for anyone interested in economic development in the Asian-Pacific region. With original articles on topical policy issues, literature surveys, and abstracts of articles from over 300 journals, APEL makes it easy for you to keep ahead of the proliferating research on this dynamic and increasingly important region. Read by politicians, journalists, businesspeople, policy-makers, industrialists and academics, APEL avoids technical jargon, and is the only journal devoted to one-stop, in-depth reporting of research on the development of Asian-Pacific economies.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信