The Reserve Bank of Australia’s pandemic response and the New Keynesian trap

IF 0.1
S. Kirchner
{"title":"The Reserve Bank of Australia’s pandemic response and the New Keynesian trap","authors":"S. Kirchner","doi":"10.22459/ag.28.01.2021.06","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"The Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) has been overly wedded to a New Keynesian conception of the monetary policy transmission mechanism, in which the official cash rate is seen as the main instrument for policy implementation and the main measure of the stance of monetary policy. The ‘effective lower bound’ on the official cash rate became an artificial, selfimposed constraint on the RBA’s initial response to the Covid-19 pandemic. By contrast, a monetarist conception of the monetary transmission mechanism would have encouraged more rapid adoption of alternative operating instruments. Reserve Bank of Australia Governor Phillip Lowe characterised the Covid-19 pandemic as the worst shock to the Australian economy in 100 years. Yet the bank’s initial response to the pandemic in March 2020 was limited, seeking to exhaust the possibilities of its pre-pandemic operating instruments. While Australia’s fiscal policy response was in line with that of other advanced economies, its monetary response, measured by the expansion in its balance sheet, lagged that of its G10 peers. Only in November 2020 did the RBA resort to alternative operating instruments to play catch-up with other central banks. In the intervening period, Australia’s fiscal and monetary policy mix saw the Australian dollar outperform its G10 peers—a classic case of open-economy crowding-out. 1 United States Studies Centre, University of Sydney; stephen.kirchner@sydney.edu.au. The author’s newsletter can be found at stephenkirchner.substack.com. AGENDA, VOLUME 28, NUMBER 1, 2021 106 This article will argue that the RBA was overly wedded to a New Keynesian conception of the monetary policy transmission mechanism, in which the official cash rate is seen as the main instrument for policy implementation and the main measure of the stance of monetary policy. The ‘effective lower bound’ on the official cash rate became an artificial, self-imposed constraint on the RBA’s initial pandemic response. In contrast, a monetarist conception of the monetary transmission mechanism would have encouraged more rapid adoption of alternative operating instruments. Before the pandemic, Governor Lowe signalled his reluctance to embrace alternative operating instruments, questioned their effectiveness and hinted vaguely at unwelcome costs associated with easier monetary policy (Lowe, 2019). Both before and during the pandemic, Lowe called on federal and state governments to do more with fiscal and structural policy, implicitly conceding that macroeconomic policy settings were inadequate, even though the RBA itself had scope to do more. The RBA eventually embraced quantitative easing (QE), from November 2020, with an aggressive program of longer-duration outright Commonwealth and semigovernment bond purchases. The RBA conceded that its failure to expand its balance sheet as had other central banks had put upward pressure on the exchange rate. While the RBA has committed to maintaining what it sees as accommodative policy settings until its inflation and full employment objectives are met, this commitment to the duration of accommodation has been allowed to substitute for the more aggressive policy action that would see the RBA meet its objectives more quickly. Extended periods of low interest rates are indicative not of ‘easy’ monetary policy, but of a monetary policy that is too tight. This article concludes with suggestions for improving the performance of Australian monetary policy—in particular, a nominal income-level target informed by a monetarist conception of monetary policy transmission. Pre-pandemic monetary policy and the ‘Lowe gap’ The RBA has failed consistently to meet its inflation target since the end of 2014. While small inflation target misses in any given quarter are unlikely to be consequential, a persistent multiyear miss gives rise to long-run drift in the price level relative to expectations conditioned on the inflation target. The long-run drift in the price level means the expectations for nominal income that inform long-term nominal contracting have been disappointed. THE RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA’S PANDEMIC RESPONSE AND THE NEW KEYNESIAN TRAP 107 The ‘Lowe gap’ is defined as the excess of a ‘trimmed mean’ measure of the (log) CPI over a counterfactual inflation target–consistent path for the period since Lowe became RBA Governor in the third quarter of 2016.2 Note that because the RBA was undershooting the inflation target before then, this starting point understates the long-run drift in the price level due to the RBA’s inflation target misses. In the first quarter of 2020, the Lowe gap was –3.9 per cent. In the period since, it has widened to –4.4 per cent, as of the second quarter 2021. Note that even if the RBA were to return inflation to the target range—something it has pencilled in from the middle of 2023—the price level will be permanently lower relative to a target-consistent counterfactual growth path. This is the sort of permanent nominal shock that flexible price-level targeting—what the US Federal Reserve calls average inflation targeting—seeks to offset. Targeting a forecast for the level of nominal GDP aims to avoid the long-run drift in nominal outcomes that can occur under the RBA’s let-bygones-be-bygones approach to inflation targeting (Kirchner, 2021). At its February 2020 meeting, just before the onset of the pandemic, the RBA Board decided to leave its official cash rate target unchanged at 0.75 per cent. The headline consumer price index inflation rate for the previous quarter was running at 1.8 per cent. Inflation had been below the target on most measures since the end of 2014 and was expected to remain so over the bank’s two-year forecast period. The unemployment rate for December 2019 was 5.1 per cent—virtually unchanged from a year earlier and above the RBA’s estimate of the full employment rate of around 4.5 per cent, having never recovered the lows around 4 per cent seen before the 2008 Global Financial Crisis. The RBA Governor told a parliamentary committee a few days later ‘there is a risk that further cuts in interest rates could encourage further borrowing. If people borrow more, then perhaps down the track we have problems’ (Lowe, 2020a). Lowe’s remarks were typical of numerous statements he made since becoming governor that explicitly traded-off the inflation target and full employment objectives against apprehended financial stability risks (Kirchner, 2018). Monetary policy during the pandemic Within weeks of Governor Lowe’s testimony, the Australian and world economies suffered a massive shock as the Covid-19 virus became a global pandemic. The RBA’s initial response to the pandemic shock was to lower the official cash rate target by 50 basis points in two moves over the course of March 2020, to 0.25 per 2 See Stephen Kirchner (2021). The Widening Lowe Gap. Institutional Economics, 29 July, stephenkirchner. substack.com/p/the-widening-lowe-gap. AGENDA, VOLUME 28, NUMBER 1, 2021 108 cent—a rate it had previously argued was an effective lower bound (ELB) given the floor of the usual 25-basis-point corridor around the cash rate target would then be 0 per cent (Lowe, 2020b). The reduction in the target cash rate was accompanied by a commitment (or forward guidance) not to raise the target ‘until progress is being made’ to restoring full employment and returning inflation to the target. This was little different to the RBA’s previous, pre-pandemic guidance, which was already committed to keeping interest rates ‘low’ for an extended period based on the same criteria. The ‘progress being made’ commitment was ambiguous, although stronger than the guidance usually offered by the bank. Any prospective improvement in the economy could be interpreted as ‘progress’ and see markets pricing in a premature increase in the cash rate, even in the absence of a change in the target rate. The RBA reinforced this commitment by undertaking to intervene in the bond market to keep the three-year bond yield close to 0.25 per cent, compared with a then prevailing market yield of around 0.50 per cent—an approach sometimes dubbed ‘yield curve control’ (YCC) or ‘yield curve targeting’ (YCT). By offering to buy government bonds at an implied target yield, the target effectively became the market yield, although Governor Lowe indicated the intervention was not a strong peg like that normally applied to the cash rate, allowing some flexibility. The aim of the yield curve target was to hold down the front and middle parts of the yield curve that serve as the risk-free benchmark for most retail and wholesale lending rates in Australia. It was complemented by a Term Funding Facility (TFF) designed to ensure banks could borrow at this rate. If the RBA’s commitment to hold the cash rate at 0.25 per cent ‘for some years’ were fully credible then intervention on the three-year bond would be unnecessary, and that mostly proved to be the case. After some initial outright bond purchases, the RBA did not intervene in the secondary bond market between early May and early August 2020, when threeyear yields rose modestly, triggering renewed intervention. Governor Lowe explicitly nominated three years as the likely time frame for keeping the cash rate at 0.25 per cent, reinforcing the loose peg on the three-year bond. Longer-term interest rates were still largely market-determined, although the RBA intervened heavily in the bond market in March 2020 to maintain liquidity amid a global bond market sell-off as investors sought to raise cash. The RBA’s preference for YCC reflected its aversion to both negative interest rates and major balance sheet expansion via large-scale asset purchases—the two main policy instruments that could have been employed in addition to forward guidance and instead of a yield target. Governor Lowe all but ruled out both options in a speech in November 2019 (Lowe, 2019), saying both options were very unlikely, raising the reputational c","PeriodicalId":41700,"journal":{"name":"Agenda-A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform","volume":" ","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.1000,"publicationDate":"2021-12-10","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Agenda-A Journal of Policy Analysis and Reform","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.22459/ag.28.01.2021.06","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

The Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) has been overly wedded to a New Keynesian conception of the monetary policy transmission mechanism, in which the official cash rate is seen as the main instrument for policy implementation and the main measure of the stance of monetary policy. The ‘effective lower bound’ on the official cash rate became an artificial, selfimposed constraint on the RBA’s initial response to the Covid-19 pandemic. By contrast, a monetarist conception of the monetary transmission mechanism would have encouraged more rapid adoption of alternative operating instruments. Reserve Bank of Australia Governor Phillip Lowe characterised the Covid-19 pandemic as the worst shock to the Australian economy in 100 years. Yet the bank’s initial response to the pandemic in March 2020 was limited, seeking to exhaust the possibilities of its pre-pandemic operating instruments. While Australia’s fiscal policy response was in line with that of other advanced economies, its monetary response, measured by the expansion in its balance sheet, lagged that of its G10 peers. Only in November 2020 did the RBA resort to alternative operating instruments to play catch-up with other central banks. In the intervening period, Australia’s fiscal and monetary policy mix saw the Australian dollar outperform its G10 peers—a classic case of open-economy crowding-out. 1 United States Studies Centre, University of Sydney; stephen.kirchner@sydney.edu.au. The author’s newsletter can be found at stephenkirchner.substack.com. AGENDA, VOLUME 28, NUMBER 1, 2021 106 This article will argue that the RBA was overly wedded to a New Keynesian conception of the monetary policy transmission mechanism, in which the official cash rate is seen as the main instrument for policy implementation and the main measure of the stance of monetary policy. The ‘effective lower bound’ on the official cash rate became an artificial, self-imposed constraint on the RBA’s initial pandemic response. In contrast, a monetarist conception of the monetary transmission mechanism would have encouraged more rapid adoption of alternative operating instruments. Before the pandemic, Governor Lowe signalled his reluctance to embrace alternative operating instruments, questioned their effectiveness and hinted vaguely at unwelcome costs associated with easier monetary policy (Lowe, 2019). Both before and during the pandemic, Lowe called on federal and state governments to do more with fiscal and structural policy, implicitly conceding that macroeconomic policy settings were inadequate, even though the RBA itself had scope to do more. The RBA eventually embraced quantitative easing (QE), from November 2020, with an aggressive program of longer-duration outright Commonwealth and semigovernment bond purchases. The RBA conceded that its failure to expand its balance sheet as had other central banks had put upward pressure on the exchange rate. While the RBA has committed to maintaining what it sees as accommodative policy settings until its inflation and full employment objectives are met, this commitment to the duration of accommodation has been allowed to substitute for the more aggressive policy action that would see the RBA meet its objectives more quickly. Extended periods of low interest rates are indicative not of ‘easy’ monetary policy, but of a monetary policy that is too tight. This article concludes with suggestions for improving the performance of Australian monetary policy—in particular, a nominal income-level target informed by a monetarist conception of monetary policy transmission. Pre-pandemic monetary policy and the ‘Lowe gap’ The RBA has failed consistently to meet its inflation target since the end of 2014. While small inflation target misses in any given quarter are unlikely to be consequential, a persistent multiyear miss gives rise to long-run drift in the price level relative to expectations conditioned on the inflation target. The long-run drift in the price level means the expectations for nominal income that inform long-term nominal contracting have been disappointed. THE RESERVE BANK OF AUSTRALIA’S PANDEMIC RESPONSE AND THE NEW KEYNESIAN TRAP 107 The ‘Lowe gap’ is defined as the excess of a ‘trimmed mean’ measure of the (log) CPI over a counterfactual inflation target–consistent path for the period since Lowe became RBA Governor in the third quarter of 2016.2 Note that because the RBA was undershooting the inflation target before then, this starting point understates the long-run drift in the price level due to the RBA’s inflation target misses. In the first quarter of 2020, the Lowe gap was –3.9 per cent. In the period since, it has widened to –4.4 per cent, as of the second quarter 2021. Note that even if the RBA were to return inflation to the target range—something it has pencilled in from the middle of 2023—the price level will be permanently lower relative to a target-consistent counterfactual growth path. This is the sort of permanent nominal shock that flexible price-level targeting—what the US Federal Reserve calls average inflation targeting—seeks to offset. Targeting a forecast for the level of nominal GDP aims to avoid the long-run drift in nominal outcomes that can occur under the RBA’s let-bygones-be-bygones approach to inflation targeting (Kirchner, 2021). At its February 2020 meeting, just before the onset of the pandemic, the RBA Board decided to leave its official cash rate target unchanged at 0.75 per cent. The headline consumer price index inflation rate for the previous quarter was running at 1.8 per cent. Inflation had been below the target on most measures since the end of 2014 and was expected to remain so over the bank’s two-year forecast period. The unemployment rate for December 2019 was 5.1 per cent—virtually unchanged from a year earlier and above the RBA’s estimate of the full employment rate of around 4.5 per cent, having never recovered the lows around 4 per cent seen before the 2008 Global Financial Crisis. The RBA Governor told a parliamentary committee a few days later ‘there is a risk that further cuts in interest rates could encourage further borrowing. If people borrow more, then perhaps down the track we have problems’ (Lowe, 2020a). Lowe’s remarks were typical of numerous statements he made since becoming governor that explicitly traded-off the inflation target and full employment objectives against apprehended financial stability risks (Kirchner, 2018). Monetary policy during the pandemic Within weeks of Governor Lowe’s testimony, the Australian and world economies suffered a massive shock as the Covid-19 virus became a global pandemic. The RBA’s initial response to the pandemic shock was to lower the official cash rate target by 50 basis points in two moves over the course of March 2020, to 0.25 per 2 See Stephen Kirchner (2021). The Widening Lowe Gap. Institutional Economics, 29 July, stephenkirchner. substack.com/p/the-widening-lowe-gap. AGENDA, VOLUME 28, NUMBER 1, 2021 108 cent—a rate it had previously argued was an effective lower bound (ELB) given the floor of the usual 25-basis-point corridor around the cash rate target would then be 0 per cent (Lowe, 2020b). The reduction in the target cash rate was accompanied by a commitment (or forward guidance) not to raise the target ‘until progress is being made’ to restoring full employment and returning inflation to the target. This was little different to the RBA’s previous, pre-pandemic guidance, which was already committed to keeping interest rates ‘low’ for an extended period based on the same criteria. The ‘progress being made’ commitment was ambiguous, although stronger than the guidance usually offered by the bank. Any prospective improvement in the economy could be interpreted as ‘progress’ and see markets pricing in a premature increase in the cash rate, even in the absence of a change in the target rate. The RBA reinforced this commitment by undertaking to intervene in the bond market to keep the three-year bond yield close to 0.25 per cent, compared with a then prevailing market yield of around 0.50 per cent—an approach sometimes dubbed ‘yield curve control’ (YCC) or ‘yield curve targeting’ (YCT). By offering to buy government bonds at an implied target yield, the target effectively became the market yield, although Governor Lowe indicated the intervention was not a strong peg like that normally applied to the cash rate, allowing some flexibility. The aim of the yield curve target was to hold down the front and middle parts of the yield curve that serve as the risk-free benchmark for most retail and wholesale lending rates in Australia. It was complemented by a Term Funding Facility (TFF) designed to ensure banks could borrow at this rate. If the RBA’s commitment to hold the cash rate at 0.25 per cent ‘for some years’ were fully credible then intervention on the three-year bond would be unnecessary, and that mostly proved to be the case. After some initial outright bond purchases, the RBA did not intervene in the secondary bond market between early May and early August 2020, when threeyear yields rose modestly, triggering renewed intervention. Governor Lowe explicitly nominated three years as the likely time frame for keeping the cash rate at 0.25 per cent, reinforcing the loose peg on the three-year bond. Longer-term interest rates were still largely market-determined, although the RBA intervened heavily in the bond market in March 2020 to maintain liquidity amid a global bond market sell-off as investors sought to raise cash. The RBA’s preference for YCC reflected its aversion to both negative interest rates and major balance sheet expansion via large-scale asset purchases—the two main policy instruments that could have been employed in addition to forward guidance and instead of a yield target. Governor Lowe all but ruled out both options in a speech in November 2019 (Lowe, 2019), saying both options were very unlikely, raising the reputational c
澳大利亚储备银行的流行病应对措施和新凯恩斯陷阱
澳大利亚储备银行(RBA)一直过度依赖于新凯恩斯主义的货币政策传导机制概念,其中官方现金利率被视为政策实施的主要工具和货币政策立场的主要衡量标准。官方现金利率的“有效下限”成为澳大利亚央行在应对Covid-19大流行的初步反应中人为的、自我强加的约束。相比之下,货币传导机制的货币主义概念将鼓励更迅速地采用替代操作工具。澳大利亚储备银行行长菲利普·洛将新冠肺炎大流行描述为100年来对澳大利亚经济最严重的冲击。然而,该银行在2020年3月对大流行的初步反应是有限的,试图用尽其大流行前操作工具的可能性。尽管澳大利亚的财政政策反应与其它发达经济体一致,但以其资产负债表的扩张来衡量,其货币反应落后于10国集团(G10)其他成员国。直到2020年11月,澳大利亚央行才求助于其他操作工具来追赶其他央行。在此期间,澳大利亚的财政和货币政策组合使澳元的表现优于其他10国集团货币——这是开放经济挤出的典型案例。1悉尼大学美国研究中心;stephen.kirchner@sydney.edu.au。作者的时事通讯可以在stephenkirchner.substack.com上找到。106本文将论证澳大利亚央行过度依赖于新凯恩斯主义的货币政策传导机制概念,其中官方现金利率被视为政策实施的主要工具和货币政策立场的主要衡量标准。官方现金利率的“有效下限”成为澳大利亚央行最初应对流行病时人为的、自我强加的约束。相比之下,货币传导机制的货币主义概念将鼓励更迅速地采用替代操作工具。在大流行之前,Lowe行长表示不愿接受替代操作工具,质疑其有效性,并模糊地暗示了宽松货币政策带来的不受欢迎的成本(Lowe, 2019)。在疫情爆发之前和期间,洛呼吁联邦和州政府在财政和结构性政策方面采取更多措施,他含蓄地承认宏观经济政策设置不足,尽管澳大利亚央行本身还有做更多事情的余地。从2020年11月起,澳大利亚央行最终采用了量化宽松政策(QE),推出了一项积极的长期直接购买联邦和半政府债券的计划。澳大利亚央行承认,它未能像其它央行那样扩大资产负债表,给澳元汇率带来了上行压力。虽然澳大利亚央行已经承诺维持其所认为的宽松政策设置,直到其通胀和充分就业目标得到满足,但这种对宽松持续时间的承诺已经被允许取代更激进的政策行动,这将使澳大利亚央行更快地实现其目标。长期的低利率并不意味着货币政策“宽松”,而是表明货币政策过于紧缩。本文最后提出了改善澳大利亚货币政策绩效的建议,特别是根据货币政策传导的货币主义概念制定名义收入水平目标。自2014年底以来,澳大利亚央行一直未能实现其通胀目标。尽管在任何一个特定季度,通胀目标的小幅偏离都不太可能造成后果,但持续多年的偏离会导致价格水平相对于以通胀目标为条件的预期出现长期漂移。价格水平的长期漂移意味着,预示长期名义收缩的名义收入预期已令人失望。澳大利亚储备银行的大流行应对和新凯恩斯陷阱107“劳差距”被定义为超过一个的削减意味着测量(日志)CPI的反事实的通货膨胀目标路径段自劳成为央行行长在第三季度2016.2的注意,因为澳大利亚央行略低于通胀目标在此之前,这个起点低估了物价水平的长期漂移由于央行的通胀目标失误。2020年第一季度,洛氏差距为- 3.9%。自那以来,截至2021年第二季度,这一差距已扩大至- 4.4%。值得注意的是,即使澳大利亚央行将通货膨胀率恢复到目标范围——这是它从2023年中期开始制定的——相对于与目标一致的反事实增长路径,价格水平将永远处于较低水平。 这是一种永久性的名义冲击,灵活的价格水平目标制——美联储称之为平均通胀目标制——试图抵消这种冲击。以名义GDP水平的预测为目标,旨在避免名义结果的长期漂移,这种漂移可能发生在澳大利亚央行的“让过去的事情过去”的通胀目标方法下(Kirchner, 2021)。在疫情爆发前的2020年2月会议上,澳大利亚央行董事会决定将其官方现金利率目标维持在0.75%不变。上一季度的总体消费者价格指数通胀率为1.8%。自2014年底以来,多数指标的通胀率一直低于目标水平,预计在央行的两年预测期内将保持这一水平。2019年12月的失业率为5.1%,几乎与一年前持平,高于澳大利亚央行估计的4.5%左右的充分就业率,从未恢复到2008年全球金融危机前4%左右的低点。几天后,澳大利亚央行行长对议会委员会表示,进一步降息可能会鼓励进一步借贷。如果人们借得更多,那么我们可能会遇到问题”(Lowe, 2020a)。Lowe的言论是他成为行长以来所做的众多声明中的典型,他明确地将通胀目标和充分就业目标与已知的金融稳定风险进行了权衡(Kirchner, 2018)。在Lowe行长作证的几周内,随着Covid-19病毒成为全球大流行,澳大利亚和世界经济遭受了巨大冲击。澳大利亚央行对疫情冲击的最初反应是,在2020年3月期间分两次将官方现金利率目标下调50个基点,至每2个0.25个基点。不断扩大的洛氏差距。制度经济学,7月29日,stephenkirchner。substack.com/p/the-widening-lowe-gap。鉴于现金利率目标周围通常的25个基点走廊的下限为0% (Lowe, 2020b),该机构此前认为108%的利率是有效的下限(ELB)。在降低目标现金利率的同时,还承诺(或前瞻指引)在恢复充分就业和通胀回到目标水平方面“取得进展”之前不会提高目标利率。这与澳大利亚央行之前在大流行前的指导意见没有什么不同,后者已经承诺根据相同的标准在较长时间内保持“低”利率。“正在取得进展”的承诺含糊不清,尽管比世行通常提供的指导要强。经济的任何预期改善都可以被解读为“进步”,市场认为即使在目标利率没有变化的情况下,现金利率也会过早上调。澳大利亚央行加强了这一承诺,承诺干预债券市场,将三年期债券收益率保持在接近0.25%的水平,而当时普遍的市场收益率约为0.50%——这种方法有时被称为“收益率曲线控制”(YCC)或“收益率曲线目标”(YCT)。通过提出以隐含目标收益率购买政府债券,目标实际上变成了市场收益率,尽管央行行长洛威表示,此次干预并非像通常适用于现金利率那样严格挂钩,允许一些灵活性。设定收益率曲线目标的目的是压低收益率曲线的前端和中间部分,这些部分是澳大利亚大多数零售和批发贷款利率的无风险基准。它还得到了一项定期融资工具(TFF)的补充,旨在确保银行能够以这一利率借款。如果澳大利亚央行将现金利率维持在0.25%“数年”的承诺是完全可信的,那么对3年期债券的干预就没有必要了,事实证明,情况基本就是如此。在最初的一些直接债券购买之后,澳大利亚央行在2020年5月初至8月初期间没有干预二级债券市场,当时三年期债券收益率小幅上升,引发了新一轮的干预。央行行长洛伊明确提出,将现金利率维持在0.25%的可能时间框架为3年,从而强化了对3年期债券的宽松挂钩。长期利率在很大程度上仍由市场决定,尽管澳大利亚央行在2020年3月大举干预债券市场,以维持流动性,因为投资者寻求筹集现金,全球债券市场出现抛售。澳大利亚央行对YCC的偏好反映了它对负利率和通过大规模资产购买来扩大资产负债表的厌恶——这两种主要的政策工具本可以在前瞻性指引之外使用,而不是收益率目标。 州长洛在2019年11月的一次演讲中几乎排除了这两种选择(Lowe, 2019),称这两种选择都非常不可能,这提高了声誉
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信