Globalisation, migration, trade and growth: Honouring the contribution of Jeff Williamson to Australian and Asia-Pacific economic history—Guest Editor's introduction

0 ECONOMICS
Andrew J. Seltzer
{"title":"Globalisation, migration, trade and growth: Honouring the contribution of Jeff Williamson to Australian and Asia-Pacific economic history—Guest Editor's introduction","authors":"Andrew J. Seltzer","doi":"10.1111/aehr.12216","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>This issue of the <i>Australian Economic History Review</i> honours the many contributions of Jeffrey Gale Williamson. Although Jeff has worked on an extraordinarily wide range of topics, countries and time periods, he is perhaps best known for his work on globalisation and the world economy beyond Europe and the United States. As part of this work, he has written extensively on Australian and Asia-Pacific economic history, the primary remit of this journal. This special issue features papers by several of Jeff's former PhD students and long-time collaborators on topics related to shared research agendas in Asian, Australian and global economic history.</p><p>Jeff Williamson needs little in the way of introduction. He has spent his academic career at Vanderbilt University (1961–1963), University of Wisconsin (1963–1983) and Harvard University (1983–2008). Since 2008 he has been an emeritus professor at Harvard and held a variety of visiting positions across the globe. As a scholar, Jeff is nothing if not prolific. His first paper in a leading economic history journal was published in 1961. He continues to publish frequently in these journals, with little sign of slowing down since his “retirement” in 2008. As of 2021, Jeff has published over 50 articles in the “top five” economic history journals. In addition, he has published over 20 articles in the leading general economics journals and the leading field journals in urban and development economics. He has written or edited 31 books. Over 70 of his works have at least 100 citations on Google Scholar (as of 30 March 2021). His production ranks at or near the very top of the all-time list of economic historians in virtually every meaningful category of measurable research output.</p><p>However, Jeff's contribution to economic history cannot be measured solely by quantity of output. Jeff's research has influenced generations of scholars on such diverse topics as globalisation during the nineteenth century and beyond (Bordo et al., <span>2003</span>; Jacks et al., <span>2011</span>; O'Rourke &amp; Williamson, <span>1994</span>, <span>1999</span>; Taylor &amp; Williamson, <span>1994</span>; Williamson, <span>1996</span>); migration from the Old World to the New World (Hatton &amp; Williamson, <span>1991</span>, <span>1994</span>, <span>1998</span>, <span>2005</span>) and within the United States and United Kingdom (Weiss &amp; Williamson, <span>1972</span>; Williamson, <span>1986</span>); the early development of the United States (Lindert &amp; Williamson, <span>2013</span>; Williamson, <span>1961</span>, <span>1965</span>, <span>1974</span>); the consequences of the industrial revolution for quality of life (Lindert &amp; Williamson, <span>1983</span>; Williamson, <span>1981</span>, <span>1984</span>, <span>1990</span>); the development of various Asia-Pacific economies (Becker et al., <span>1986</span>; Kelley &amp; Williamson, <span>1971</span>, <span>1974</span>; Williamson, <span>1969</span>, <span>1979</span>); Australian economic history (Bhattacharyya &amp; Williamson, <span>2016</span>; Panza &amp; Williamson, <span>2019</span>, <span>2020</span>); and growth and inequality in the United States (Lindert &amp; Williamson, <span>1976</span>, <span>2016</span>; Williamson &amp; Lindert, <span>1980</span>), Great Britain (Williamson, <span>1980</span>, <span>1985</span>), and in a comparative perspective (Aghion &amp; Williamson, <span>1998</span>; Lindert &amp; Williamson, <span>1985</span>; Williamson, <span>1991</span>, <span>1997</span>, <span>2011</span>). He has been a pioneer in bringing new methodologies to economic history, particularly general equilibrium (Kelley &amp; Williamson, <span>1973</span>). Likewise, he was a leader in bringing the new economic history into economics (Kelley &amp; Williamson, <span>1973</span>; Kmenta &amp; Williamson, <span>1966</span>; Williamson, <span>1963</span>, <span>1971a</span>).</p><p>In addition to his many contributions to knowledge, Jeff has also been a pioneer in his approach to conducting research. At the start of his career a significant majority scholarship in economic history and economics more generally was sole authored (Seltzer &amp; Hamermesh, <span>2018</span>). Although Jeff has written many sole authored papers (as can be seen in the reference list), he has also engaged in <i>far</i> more collaborative research than any other economic historian of his generation. He has worked with an astonishingly large number of co-authors, several of whom have become long-term collaborators. The discipline has over time caught up to Jeff, and we now recognise that scholars often possess complementary skills and are able to do better work together than alone. In recent years, about 80% of the work in the top economics journals and the majority of work published in leading economic history journals have been co-authored.</p><p>The themes of collaboration and mentorship extend beyond the boundaries of published output. Jeff has been the supervisor or advisor of nearly 50 PhD students at Wisconsin and Harvard. He has also won several teaching awards, including the 2000 Jonathan Hughes Prize for Excellence in Teaching Economic History. He has held many leadership roles in the profession that helped advance the research of others, including editor of <i>Explorations in Economic History</i>, associate editor of <i>Review of Economics and Statistics</i> and <i>Journal of Development Economics</i>, member of the editorial boards for several journals, member of the AEA Committee on Education and Training of Minority Group Economists, President of the Economic History Association and Chair of the Economics Department at Harvard. In putting together this issue, I have the chance to talk to several of Jeff's long-term collaborators and they have all emphasised how working with Jeff shaped their careers. Several authors in this issue, including more than one who has never co-authored with Jeff, noted that he was one of the first senior people in the profession to take an interest in their work and provide support and feedback.</p><p>Jeff has held a lifetime interest in Asia, dating back to a year and a half spent at the University of the Philippines in the mid-1960s. He is probably one of very few living western scholars who visited Cambodia prior to the Secret Bombings of the Ho Chi Min Trail and the horrors of the Khmer Rouge regime. His lifetime interest in the region has led to an output consisting of dozens of papers covering aspects of the economic history or development of Japan (Kelley &amp; Williamson, <span>1971</span>, <span>1974</span>), India (Becker et al., <span>1986</span>, <span>1992</span>), the Philippines (Williamson, <span>1969</span>, <span>1971b</span>), Indonesia (Kelley &amp; Williamson, <span>1968</span>), Korea (Williamson, <span>1979</span>) and the Asia-Pacific region more generally (Kelley &amp; Williamson, <span>1971</span>; Williamson, <span>1968</span>, <span>2000</span>). Jeff was probably the first scholar to bring the cliometric approach to Asian economic history. His paper “Writing History Backwards: Meiji Japan Revisited” won the Cole Prize for best article published in the <i>Journal of Economic History</i> in 1971, the first time the prize was awarded for an article on a non-western country (Kelley &amp; Williamson, <span>1971</span>).</p><p>Jeff has also been a long-time friend to Australian economic history. He has had ongoing relationships with Australian National University and University of Melbourne extending over the past four decades. He first published in this Journal shortly after his first visit to ANU (Williamson, <span>1989</span>). He delivered the inaugural Butlin lecture in 2004 (Williamson, <span>2004</span>). His paper in this issue will be the fifth he has published in the AEHR, the most of anyone who has never held a full-time post in the Antipodes. He has been on the editorial board of this journal since 2003. As a personal comment, I will say that Jeff has always been the editors' best friend on the editorial board—every year he is among the very first to vote on the Coghlan Prize, his vote usually provides a preview of the mood of the rest of the editorial board, and when asked to referee he has been willing and constructive. Whenever I have seen him at Australian economic history events, he has always made an effort to spend much his time talking to younger scholars.</p><p>Each of the papers in this special issue have at least one author with a “Williamson Number” of one—a direct connection to Jeff as either a PhD student or collaborator. In each case, the main theme of the paper is drawn from earlier collaborations with Jeff. In putting together this issue, I have focused on Jeff's work and collaborations along the remit of this journal—Australian, Asia-Pacific and global economic history.</p><p>The first paper in this issue, “Emigration from the United Kingdom to the United States, Canada and Australia/New Zealand, 1870–1913: Quantity and Quality” is by one of Jeff's longest-term collaborators, Timothy Hatton. Jeff and Tim have published over 20 papers, chapters and books together, dating back to Hatton's visit to Harvard in 1988–1989. Most of these jointly authored works have examined different aspects of international migration, which is also the main theme of this paper. The focus of this paper is migrant destinations. This has been understudied in the literature, which typically focuses on a single destination country—usually the United States, as it received by far the most immigrants prior to the First World War (Abromitsky et al., <span>2012</span>; Borjas, <span>1994</span>). By focusing on a single destination country, the literature neglects the fact that, at the source, would-be migrants had a decision as to where to go. This paper examines the choice of destination by essentially reversing the normal approach in the literature. Rather than examining migrants to a single destination country from multiple source countries, this paper examines migrants from a single source country to multiple destination countries. The choice of the United States, Canada and the Antipodes is natural as these three destinations accounted for about 90% of migration from the United Kingdom over the time period of this study.</p><p>Most of the findings of the paper are in line with theoretical expectations. Emigrants chose their country of destination based on the cost of travel, previous migration and economic returns. Travel costs were determined by distance and, in the case of Australia/New Zealand, the extent of migration subsidies. Recent migrants were the primary source of information for perspective migrants back home. Thus, over time migrations rates were positively autocorrelated, for example, higher migration rates to a given destination in the previous year increased migration rates in the current year. The paper finds mixed evidence on the effects of returns. Emigrants responded to changes in wages in the destination country in the manner predicted by standard models of human capital. However, the pattern of migration by skill level is counter-intuitive in the context of the well-known Roy model of migration (Borjas, <span>1987</span>; Roy, <span>1951</span>) and remains an important unresolved puzzle. The skill premium (as measured by relative wages) for the United States was much higher than for Canada and particularly for Australia/New Zealand. However, the paper finds that Australia/New Zealand received a disproportionate share of skilled migrants.</p><p>The second paper “Four great Asian trade collapses” is by one of Jeff's former PhD students and longest collaborators, Kevin O'Rourke, along with three of Jeff's “intellectual grandchildren”—Alan de Bromhead, Alan Fernihough, and Markus Lampe. Jeff and Kevin have also published over 20 papers, chapters and books together, mostly on issues of the globalisation of the world economy. The paper in this issue is part of a larger project on the causes and economic consequences of anti-globalisation backlashes. Trade collapses are an important manifestation of anti-globalisation backlashes, as they may be an important mechanism for international contagion of recessions. While there exists a large literature on the trade collapse in the United States and Europe during the Great Depression (de Bromhead et al., <span>2019</span>; Kindleberger, <span>1973</span>), much less has been written about the rest of the world. This paper examines the collapse of trade over the period 1929–1933 for the four most populous Asian countries: China, the Dutch East Indies, Japan and India. For the first three of these countries, they construct a new data set of bilateral trade in 38 commodities with 42 partner countries. They then decompose the decline in the total value of trade into separate quantity and price effects and also examine the extent of decline in each country for different commodities and partner regions.</p><p>The Asian trade collapse was dramatic. Between 1929 and 1931, the nominal value of imports fell by about 40% in all four countries, about the same as the total decline in world trade. Thereafter, the paths of the four countries diverged sharply. Japan left gold in 1931 and its trade quickly recovered, surpassing 1929 levels by 1934. Trade stagnated or continued to decline in the other three countries, reaching as low as about 25% of 1929 levels in the Dutch East Indies in 1936. A simple decomposition shows that both quantities and prices mattered for the decline in trade over the periods 1929–1931 and 1929–1933, and the average share attributable to price declines was similar to that of the world average for both periods. By contrast, in the 2008–2009 trade collapse, the role of prices was far more important for these countries than for the world as a whole. The trade collapse was unbalanced in terms of composition and partner shares in each of these countries. Trade in durables dropped by more than trade in non-durables in Japan and the Dutch East Indies. The reverse was true in China, which the authors explain as a continuation of a pre-collapse trend, with China experiencing rapid industrialisation and growth in the export of durables immediately prior to 1929. The collapse also had a “colonial bias.” Trade with long-time colonisers (e.g., the United Kingdom in the case of India or the Netherlands in the case of the Dutch East Indies) dropped by more than trade with the United States.</p><p>The third paper “Commodity boom-bust cycles and the resource curse in Australia: 1900 to 2017” is by Jeff's first collaborator on Australian topics, Sambit Bhattacharya. Sambit and Jeff have previously written two papers on the effects of commodity price shocks on the Australian economy (Bhattacharyya &amp; Williamson, <span>2011</span>; Bhattacharyya &amp; Williamson, <span>2016</span>), and this is the main theme of this paper. The paper examines whether twentieth century Australia suffered from the “resource curse”—unfavourable reallocation of resources following commodity price booms, caused by changing factor prices. For example, rising mineral prices may lead to the reallocation of capital and labour to that sector, with the consequence of crowding out manufacturing. Under some theoretical conditions, the extent of this crowding out may be sufficiently large to lead to a decline in GDP. Given Australia's rich land endowment and history of export-led growth, it is perhaps not surprising that much of the early theoretical and applied work on resource curses was undertaken by Australian economists (Corden &amp; Neary, <span>1982</span>; Gregory, <span>1976</span>). However, impressionistically Australia seems not to have suffered from the resource curse—if anything, Australian GDP growth accelerated during commodity booms.</p><p>This paper examines this proposition more formally using time series methods, specifically single equation error correction models. The model is used to estimate the determinants of Australian GDP and the impact of commodity cycles. Of particular interest are three commodity booms over the “long-twentieth” century: increased demand for wool and agricultural products in the early 1920s; increased demand for mining output, wool and agricultural products during the Korean War; and the mining boom in the early twenty-first century caused by the expansion of the Chinese economy. The results show, to misappropriate a well-known Australian phrase, that Australia was indeed the “lucky country” (Horne, <span>1964</span>), experiencing a sustained increase in GDP over each of these episodes. Formal time series analysis shows that there was no resource curse, and over the entire period the economic effects of commodity price shocks are positive. Finally, the paper offers some speculations as to why Australia managed to avoid the resource curse, whereas so many other countries were impoverished by commodity booms.</p><p>The fourth paper “Dry bulk shipping and the evolution of maritime transport costs, 1850–2020” is by another of Jeff's collaborators on his globalisation research agenda and intellectual grandchildren, David Jacks, along with Martin Stuermer. This paper considers a factor identified in the literature as an important driver of globalisation, namely declining transportation costs (Harley, <span>1988</span>; North, <span>1958</span>). The focus is on shipping costs, specifically freight rates for dry bulk goods, which currently comprise about half of world trade by volume. The authors begin by constructing a new series of freight rates aggregated across different currencies, ports of origin and destination and goods. They then examine the determinants of movements in freight rates using a structural vector autoregressive model. Their objective is to identify the effects of different types of shocks on shipping rates, namely fuel prices, shipping demand, shipping supply and what they term a “residual shock.”</p><p>They show that over the period of their study, freight rates declined substantially, with rates at the end of the period barely 20% of those at the start. However, this decline was not linear and, consistent with a large literature arguing that the interwar period experienced substantial deglobalisation (James, <span>2009</span>; Kindleberger, <span>1973</span>) rates actually increased from about 1910 to 1950. Year-on-year changes could be quite substantial. These “spikes” in the data can be attributed to the four different types of shocks. For example, freight rates increased sharply between 1973 and 1979 due to the OPEC-led oil price surge. They show that over the entire period shipping demand shocks had the largest and most persistent effects. Demand shocks explain about half the total variation in world freight rates. The effects of shipping supply and fuel price shocks were in comparison quite modest, together accounting for slightly less variation in rates than demand shocks. Demand shocks were also the most persistent, with effects lasting for 10–15 years. The residual effect is minimal.</p><p>The final paper “Always egalitarian? Australian earnings inequality 1870–1910” is by Jeff Williamson himself, along with his most recent long-term co-author Laura Panza. The paper is part of a larger project on growth living standards and inequality in the New World since 1700. Jeff and Laura have written a series of papers exploring “Australian exceptionalism,” the combination of high average income and low inequality that characterised nineteenth and twentieth century Australia (Panza &amp; Williamson, <span>2019</span>, <span>2020</span>). It has long been known that the Australian growth experience in the nineteenth century was exceptional. Over the century, Australia went from a single European settlement—the penal colony in Sydney—to being the wealthiest country in the world. There exists a large literature on why Australia grew rich (McLean, <span>2007</span>, <span>2013</span>). Much less has been written about Australian inequality as it grew wealthy, and this literature only begins with the twentieth century (Atkinson &amp; Leigh, <span>2007</span>). This paper extends the literature on Australian inequality back into the nineteenth century.</p><p>The authors use data from the <i>Colonial Census</i>, the <i>Sessional Papers</i> and the <i>Official Yearbook of New South Wales</i> and the <i>Blue Books</i> to construct social tables of earnings by occupation for New South Wales and Victoria. They demonstrate that the social tables show that in 1870 Australia was more egalitarian than the United States, England or Europe. Moreover, the inequality gap between Australia and other wealthy nations widened over the next 40 years; earnings inequality fell in Australia, while it rose elsewhere. The decline in earnings inequality is apparent from several alternative measures: including the gini coefficient, the top 10% and 1% shares, and the ratio of the top 10% share to bottom 10% share. They argue that the reason behind the simultaneous increase in income and decrease in inequality was an increase in the supply of skilled labour, driven by education and immigration.</p>","PeriodicalId":100132,"journal":{"name":"Asia‐Pacific Economic History Review","volume":"61 2","pages":"128-135"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2021-07-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://sci-hub-pdf.com/10.1111/aehr.12216","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Asia‐Pacific Economic History Review","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/aehr.12216","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"0","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

This issue of the Australian Economic History Review honours the many contributions of Jeffrey Gale Williamson. Although Jeff has worked on an extraordinarily wide range of topics, countries and time periods, he is perhaps best known for his work on globalisation and the world economy beyond Europe and the United States. As part of this work, he has written extensively on Australian and Asia-Pacific economic history, the primary remit of this journal. This special issue features papers by several of Jeff's former PhD students and long-time collaborators on topics related to shared research agendas in Asian, Australian and global economic history.

Jeff Williamson needs little in the way of introduction. He has spent his academic career at Vanderbilt University (1961–1963), University of Wisconsin (1963–1983) and Harvard University (1983–2008). Since 2008 he has been an emeritus professor at Harvard and held a variety of visiting positions across the globe. As a scholar, Jeff is nothing if not prolific. His first paper in a leading economic history journal was published in 1961. He continues to publish frequently in these journals, with little sign of slowing down since his “retirement” in 2008. As of 2021, Jeff has published over 50 articles in the “top five” economic history journals. In addition, he has published over 20 articles in the leading general economics journals and the leading field journals in urban and development economics. He has written or edited 31 books. Over 70 of his works have at least 100 citations on Google Scholar (as of 30 March 2021). His production ranks at or near the very top of the all-time list of economic historians in virtually every meaningful category of measurable research output.

However, Jeff's contribution to economic history cannot be measured solely by quantity of output. Jeff's research has influenced generations of scholars on such diverse topics as globalisation during the nineteenth century and beyond (Bordo et al., 2003; Jacks et al., 2011; O'Rourke & Williamson, 1994, 1999; Taylor & Williamson, 1994; Williamson, 1996); migration from the Old World to the New World (Hatton & Williamson, 1991, 1994, 1998, 2005) and within the United States and United Kingdom (Weiss & Williamson, 1972; Williamson, 1986); the early development of the United States (Lindert & Williamson, 2013; Williamson, 1961, 1965, 1974); the consequences of the industrial revolution for quality of life (Lindert & Williamson, 1983; Williamson, 1981, 1984, 1990); the development of various Asia-Pacific economies (Becker et al., 1986; Kelley & Williamson, 1971, 1974; Williamson, 1969, 1979); Australian economic history (Bhattacharyya & Williamson, 2016; Panza & Williamson, 2019, 2020); and growth and inequality in the United States (Lindert & Williamson, 1976, 2016; Williamson & Lindert, 1980), Great Britain (Williamson, 1980, 1985), and in a comparative perspective (Aghion & Williamson, 1998; Lindert & Williamson, 1985; Williamson, 1991, 1997, 2011). He has been a pioneer in bringing new methodologies to economic history, particularly general equilibrium (Kelley & Williamson, 1973). Likewise, he was a leader in bringing the new economic history into economics (Kelley & Williamson, 1973; Kmenta & Williamson, 1966; Williamson, 1963, 1971a).

In addition to his many contributions to knowledge, Jeff has also been a pioneer in his approach to conducting research. At the start of his career a significant majority scholarship in economic history and economics more generally was sole authored (Seltzer & Hamermesh, 2018). Although Jeff has written many sole authored papers (as can be seen in the reference list), he has also engaged in far more collaborative research than any other economic historian of his generation. He has worked with an astonishingly large number of co-authors, several of whom have become long-term collaborators. The discipline has over time caught up to Jeff, and we now recognise that scholars often possess complementary skills and are able to do better work together than alone. In recent years, about 80% of the work in the top economics journals and the majority of work published in leading economic history journals have been co-authored.

The themes of collaboration and mentorship extend beyond the boundaries of published output. Jeff has been the supervisor or advisor of nearly 50 PhD students at Wisconsin and Harvard. He has also won several teaching awards, including the 2000 Jonathan Hughes Prize for Excellence in Teaching Economic History. He has held many leadership roles in the profession that helped advance the research of others, including editor of Explorations in Economic History, associate editor of Review of Economics and Statistics and Journal of Development Economics, member of the editorial boards for several journals, member of the AEA Committee on Education and Training of Minority Group Economists, President of the Economic History Association and Chair of the Economics Department at Harvard. In putting together this issue, I have the chance to talk to several of Jeff's long-term collaborators and they have all emphasised how working with Jeff shaped their careers. Several authors in this issue, including more than one who has never co-authored with Jeff, noted that he was one of the first senior people in the profession to take an interest in their work and provide support and feedback.

Jeff has held a lifetime interest in Asia, dating back to a year and a half spent at the University of the Philippines in the mid-1960s. He is probably one of very few living western scholars who visited Cambodia prior to the Secret Bombings of the Ho Chi Min Trail and the horrors of the Khmer Rouge regime. His lifetime interest in the region has led to an output consisting of dozens of papers covering aspects of the economic history or development of Japan (Kelley & Williamson, 1971, 1974), India (Becker et al., 1986, 1992), the Philippines (Williamson, 1969, 1971b), Indonesia (Kelley & Williamson, 1968), Korea (Williamson, 1979) and the Asia-Pacific region more generally (Kelley & Williamson, 1971; Williamson, 1968, 2000). Jeff was probably the first scholar to bring the cliometric approach to Asian economic history. His paper “Writing History Backwards: Meiji Japan Revisited” won the Cole Prize for best article published in the Journal of Economic History in 1971, the first time the prize was awarded for an article on a non-western country (Kelley & Williamson, 1971).

Jeff has also been a long-time friend to Australian economic history. He has had ongoing relationships with Australian National University and University of Melbourne extending over the past four decades. He first published in this Journal shortly after his first visit to ANU (Williamson, 1989). He delivered the inaugural Butlin lecture in 2004 (Williamson, 2004). His paper in this issue will be the fifth he has published in the AEHR, the most of anyone who has never held a full-time post in the Antipodes. He has been on the editorial board of this journal since 2003. As a personal comment, I will say that Jeff has always been the editors' best friend on the editorial board—every year he is among the very first to vote on the Coghlan Prize, his vote usually provides a preview of the mood of the rest of the editorial board, and when asked to referee he has been willing and constructive. Whenever I have seen him at Australian economic history events, he has always made an effort to spend much his time talking to younger scholars.

Each of the papers in this special issue have at least one author with a “Williamson Number” of one—a direct connection to Jeff as either a PhD student or collaborator. In each case, the main theme of the paper is drawn from earlier collaborations with Jeff. In putting together this issue, I have focused on Jeff's work and collaborations along the remit of this journal—Australian, Asia-Pacific and global economic history.

The first paper in this issue, “Emigration from the United Kingdom to the United States, Canada and Australia/New Zealand, 1870–1913: Quantity and Quality” is by one of Jeff's longest-term collaborators, Timothy Hatton. Jeff and Tim have published over 20 papers, chapters and books together, dating back to Hatton's visit to Harvard in 1988–1989. Most of these jointly authored works have examined different aspects of international migration, which is also the main theme of this paper. The focus of this paper is migrant destinations. This has been understudied in the literature, which typically focuses on a single destination country—usually the United States, as it received by far the most immigrants prior to the First World War (Abromitsky et al., 2012; Borjas, 1994). By focusing on a single destination country, the literature neglects the fact that, at the source, would-be migrants had a decision as to where to go. This paper examines the choice of destination by essentially reversing the normal approach in the literature. Rather than examining migrants to a single destination country from multiple source countries, this paper examines migrants from a single source country to multiple destination countries. The choice of the United States, Canada and the Antipodes is natural as these three destinations accounted for about 90% of migration from the United Kingdom over the time period of this study.

Most of the findings of the paper are in line with theoretical expectations. Emigrants chose their country of destination based on the cost of travel, previous migration and economic returns. Travel costs were determined by distance and, in the case of Australia/New Zealand, the extent of migration subsidies. Recent migrants were the primary source of information for perspective migrants back home. Thus, over time migrations rates were positively autocorrelated, for example, higher migration rates to a given destination in the previous year increased migration rates in the current year. The paper finds mixed evidence on the effects of returns. Emigrants responded to changes in wages in the destination country in the manner predicted by standard models of human capital. However, the pattern of migration by skill level is counter-intuitive in the context of the well-known Roy model of migration (Borjas, 1987; Roy, 1951) and remains an important unresolved puzzle. The skill premium (as measured by relative wages) for the United States was much higher than for Canada and particularly for Australia/New Zealand. However, the paper finds that Australia/New Zealand received a disproportionate share of skilled migrants.

The second paper “Four great Asian trade collapses” is by one of Jeff's former PhD students and longest collaborators, Kevin O'Rourke, along with three of Jeff's “intellectual grandchildren”—Alan de Bromhead, Alan Fernihough, and Markus Lampe. Jeff and Kevin have also published over 20 papers, chapters and books together, mostly on issues of the globalisation of the world economy. The paper in this issue is part of a larger project on the causes and economic consequences of anti-globalisation backlashes. Trade collapses are an important manifestation of anti-globalisation backlashes, as they may be an important mechanism for international contagion of recessions. While there exists a large literature on the trade collapse in the United States and Europe during the Great Depression (de Bromhead et al., 2019; Kindleberger, 1973), much less has been written about the rest of the world. This paper examines the collapse of trade over the period 1929–1933 for the four most populous Asian countries: China, the Dutch East Indies, Japan and India. For the first three of these countries, they construct a new data set of bilateral trade in 38 commodities with 42 partner countries. They then decompose the decline in the total value of trade into separate quantity and price effects and also examine the extent of decline in each country for different commodities and partner regions.

The Asian trade collapse was dramatic. Between 1929 and 1931, the nominal value of imports fell by about 40% in all four countries, about the same as the total decline in world trade. Thereafter, the paths of the four countries diverged sharply. Japan left gold in 1931 and its trade quickly recovered, surpassing 1929 levels by 1934. Trade stagnated or continued to decline in the other three countries, reaching as low as about 25% of 1929 levels in the Dutch East Indies in 1936. A simple decomposition shows that both quantities and prices mattered for the decline in trade over the periods 1929–1931 and 1929–1933, and the average share attributable to price declines was similar to that of the world average for both periods. By contrast, in the 2008–2009 trade collapse, the role of prices was far more important for these countries than for the world as a whole. The trade collapse was unbalanced in terms of composition and partner shares in each of these countries. Trade in durables dropped by more than trade in non-durables in Japan and the Dutch East Indies. The reverse was true in China, which the authors explain as a continuation of a pre-collapse trend, with China experiencing rapid industrialisation and growth in the export of durables immediately prior to 1929. The collapse also had a “colonial bias.” Trade with long-time colonisers (e.g., the United Kingdom in the case of India or the Netherlands in the case of the Dutch East Indies) dropped by more than trade with the United States.

The third paper “Commodity boom-bust cycles and the resource curse in Australia: 1900 to 2017” is by Jeff's first collaborator on Australian topics, Sambit Bhattacharya. Sambit and Jeff have previously written two papers on the effects of commodity price shocks on the Australian economy (Bhattacharyya & Williamson, 2011; Bhattacharyya & Williamson, 2016), and this is the main theme of this paper. The paper examines whether twentieth century Australia suffered from the “resource curse”—unfavourable reallocation of resources following commodity price booms, caused by changing factor prices. For example, rising mineral prices may lead to the reallocation of capital and labour to that sector, with the consequence of crowding out manufacturing. Under some theoretical conditions, the extent of this crowding out may be sufficiently large to lead to a decline in GDP. Given Australia's rich land endowment and history of export-led growth, it is perhaps not surprising that much of the early theoretical and applied work on resource curses was undertaken by Australian economists (Corden & Neary, 1982; Gregory, 1976). However, impressionistically Australia seems not to have suffered from the resource curse—if anything, Australian GDP growth accelerated during commodity booms.

This paper examines this proposition more formally using time series methods, specifically single equation error correction models. The model is used to estimate the determinants of Australian GDP and the impact of commodity cycles. Of particular interest are three commodity booms over the “long-twentieth” century: increased demand for wool and agricultural products in the early 1920s; increased demand for mining output, wool and agricultural products during the Korean War; and the mining boom in the early twenty-first century caused by the expansion of the Chinese economy. The results show, to misappropriate a well-known Australian phrase, that Australia was indeed the “lucky country” (Horne, 1964), experiencing a sustained increase in GDP over each of these episodes. Formal time series analysis shows that there was no resource curse, and over the entire period the economic effects of commodity price shocks are positive. Finally, the paper offers some speculations as to why Australia managed to avoid the resource curse, whereas so many other countries were impoverished by commodity booms.

The fourth paper “Dry bulk shipping and the evolution of maritime transport costs, 1850–2020” is by another of Jeff's collaborators on his globalisation research agenda and intellectual grandchildren, David Jacks, along with Martin Stuermer. This paper considers a factor identified in the literature as an important driver of globalisation, namely declining transportation costs (Harley, 1988; North, 1958). The focus is on shipping costs, specifically freight rates for dry bulk goods, which currently comprise about half of world trade by volume. The authors begin by constructing a new series of freight rates aggregated across different currencies, ports of origin and destination and goods. They then examine the determinants of movements in freight rates using a structural vector autoregressive model. Their objective is to identify the effects of different types of shocks on shipping rates, namely fuel prices, shipping demand, shipping supply and what they term a “residual shock.”

They show that over the period of their study, freight rates declined substantially, with rates at the end of the period barely 20% of those at the start. However, this decline was not linear and, consistent with a large literature arguing that the interwar period experienced substantial deglobalisation (James, 2009; Kindleberger, 1973) rates actually increased from about 1910 to 1950. Year-on-year changes could be quite substantial. These “spikes” in the data can be attributed to the four different types of shocks. For example, freight rates increased sharply between 1973 and 1979 due to the OPEC-led oil price surge. They show that over the entire period shipping demand shocks had the largest and most persistent effects. Demand shocks explain about half the total variation in world freight rates. The effects of shipping supply and fuel price shocks were in comparison quite modest, together accounting for slightly less variation in rates than demand shocks. Demand shocks were also the most persistent, with effects lasting for 10–15 years. The residual effect is minimal.

The final paper “Always egalitarian? Australian earnings inequality 1870–1910” is by Jeff Williamson himself, along with his most recent long-term co-author Laura Panza. The paper is part of a larger project on growth living standards and inequality in the New World since 1700. Jeff and Laura have written a series of papers exploring “Australian exceptionalism,” the combination of high average income and low inequality that characterised nineteenth and twentieth century Australia (Panza & Williamson, 2019, 2020). It has long been known that the Australian growth experience in the nineteenth century was exceptional. Over the century, Australia went from a single European settlement—the penal colony in Sydney—to being the wealthiest country in the world. There exists a large literature on why Australia grew rich (McLean, 2007, 2013). Much less has been written about Australian inequality as it grew wealthy, and this literature only begins with the twentieth century (Atkinson & Leigh, 2007). This paper extends the literature on Australian inequality back into the nineteenth century.

The authors use data from the Colonial Census, the Sessional Papers and the Official Yearbook of New South Wales and the Blue Books to construct social tables of earnings by occupation for New South Wales and Victoria. They demonstrate that the social tables show that in 1870 Australia was more egalitarian than the United States, England or Europe. Moreover, the inequality gap between Australia and other wealthy nations widened over the next 40 years; earnings inequality fell in Australia, while it rose elsewhere. The decline in earnings inequality is apparent from several alternative measures: including the gini coefficient, the top 10% and 1% shares, and the ratio of the top 10% share to bottom 10% share. They argue that the reason behind the simultaneous increase in income and decrease in inequality was an increase in the supply of skilled labour, driven by education and immigration.

全球化、移民、贸易和增长:表彰杰夫·威廉姆森对澳大利亚和亚太经济史的贡献——特邀编辑简介
本期《澳大利亚经济史评论》向杰弗里·盖尔·威廉姆森的诸多贡献致敬。虽然杰夫的研究范围非常广泛,涉及国家和时期,但他最出名的可能是他在全球化和欧洲和美国以外的世界经济方面的工作。作为这项工作的一部分,他撰写了大量关于澳大利亚和亚太经济史的文章,这是本刊的主要职责。这期特刊刊登了Jeff的几位前博士生和长期合作者的论文,主题涉及亚洲、澳大利亚和全球经济史的共同研究议程。杰夫·威廉姆森(Jeff Williamson)几乎不需要介绍。他的学术生涯曾在范德比尔特大学(1961-1963)、威斯康星大学(1963-1983)和哈佛大学(1983-2008)度过。自2008年以来,他一直是哈佛大学的名誉教授,并在全球范围内担任过各种访问职位。作为一名学者,杰夫的著作非常多。1961年,他在一家重要的经济史杂志上发表了第一篇论文。他继续频繁地在这些期刊上发表文章,自2008年“退休”以来,几乎没有放慢脚步的迹象。截至2021年,杰夫在“五大”经济史期刊上发表了50多篇文章。此外,他还在领先的普通经济学期刊和领先的城市与发展经济学领域期刊上发表了20多篇文章。他撰写或编辑了31本书。他的70多篇作品在b谷歌Scholar上被引用至少100次(截至2021年3月30日)。在几乎所有有意义的、可衡量的研究成果类别中,他的著作都位居或接近历史经济史学家的榜首。然而,杰夫对经济史的贡献不能仅仅用产出的数量来衡量。杰夫的研究影响了几代学者对19世纪及以后的全球化等不同主题的研究(Bordo et al., 2003;Jacks等人,2011;O’rourke和Williamson, 1994,1999;泰勒,威廉姆森,1994;威廉姆森,1996);从旧大陆到新大陆的迁徙(哈顿&;Williamson, 1991,1994,1998,2005)以及在美国和英国(Weiss &威廉姆森,1972;威廉姆森,1986);美国的早期发展(林德特&;威廉姆森,2013;威廉姆森(1961,1965,1974);工业革命对生活质量的影响(林德尔)威廉姆森,1983;威廉姆森,1981年,1984年,1990年);亚太各经济体的发展(Becker et al., 1986;凯利,威廉姆森,1971,1974;Williamson, 1969, 1979);澳大利亚经济史(巴塔查里亚&;威廉姆森,2016;潘,Williamson, 2019, 2020);以及美国的经济增长和不平等(林德特&;威廉姆森,1976,2016;威廉姆森,Lindert, 1980),英国(Williamson, 1980, 1985),并从比较的角度来看(Aghion &;威廉姆森,1998;兰德博士,威廉姆森,1985;Williamson, 1991,1997,2011)。他是将新方法引入经济史的先驱,特别是一般均衡(Kelley &;威廉姆森,1973)。同样,他也是将新经济史引入经济学的领导者(凯利&;威廉姆森,1973;Kmenta,威廉姆森,1966;Williamson, 1963, 1971)。除了他对知识的许多贡献之外,杰夫也是他进行研究方法的先驱。在他的职业生涯开始时,大部分关于经济史和经济学的学术研究都是独自撰写的(萨尔茨& &;哈默梅什,2018)。尽管杰夫撰写了许多单独撰写的论文(从参考文献列表中可以看出),但他也参与了比同时代任何其他经济历史学家多得多的合作研究。他曾与数量惊人的合著者合作,其中一些人已成为长期合作者。随着时间的推移,这门学科赶上了杰夫,我们现在认识到,学者们往往拥有互补的技能,在一起工作比单独工作能做得更好。近年来,在顶级经济学期刊上发表的约80%的文章和在主要经济史期刊上发表的大部分文章都是合作撰写的。合作和指导的主题超越了出版成果的界限。Jeff是威斯康星大学和哈佛大学近50名博士生的导师或顾问。他还获得了多个教学奖项,包括2000年乔纳森·休斯经济史教学卓越奖。 他曾担任过许多领导职务,帮助推动了其他人的研究,包括《经济史探索》的编辑、《经济与统计评论》和《发展经济学杂志》的副主编、几家期刊的编辑委员会成员、美国经济学会少数群体经济学家教育和培训委员会成员、经济史协会主席和哈佛大学经济系主席。在整理本期杂志的过程中,我有机会与Jeff的几位长期合作伙伴交谈,他们都强调了与Jeff的合作如何塑造了他们的职业生涯。本期杂志的几位作者,包括不止一位从未与Jeff合作过的作者,都指出他是这个行业中第一个对他们的工作感兴趣并提供支持和反馈的资深人士之一。Jeff对亚洲有着毕生的兴趣,可以追溯到20世纪60年代中期在菲律宾大学度过的一年半。他可能是在胡志明小道秘密轰炸和红色高棉政权的恐怖统治之前访问过柬埔寨的为数不多的西方学者之一。他一生对该地区的兴趣导致了数十篇论文的产出,涵盖了日本经济史或发展的各个方面(Kelley &;威廉姆森,1971年,1974年),印度(贝克等人,1986年,1992年),菲律宾(威廉姆森,1969年,1971年b),印度尼西亚(凯利和;Williamson, 1968),韩国(Williamson, 1979)以及更广泛的亚太地区(Kelley &威廉姆森,1971;Williamson, 1968, 2000)。Jeff可能是第一个将计量经济学方法引入亚洲经济史的学者。他的论文《逆向书写历史:重新审视明治日本》(Writing History Backwards: Meiji Japan Revisited)获得1971年《经济史杂志》(Journal of Economic History)最佳文章奖,这是该奖项首次颁发给有关非西方国家的文章。威廉姆森,1971)。杰夫也是澳大利亚经济史的长期朋友。在过去的四十年里,他一直与澳大利亚国立大学和墨尔本大学保持着持续的合作关系。在他第一次访问澳大利亚国立大学后不久,他首次在本刊上发表了文章(Williamson, 1989)。他在2004年发表了首届布特林讲座(Williamson, 2004)。他在这期杂志上发表的论文将是他在《美国医学健康杂志》上发表的第五篇论文,是从未在澳洲担任过全职工作的人中发表论文最多的。自2003年以来,他一直是该杂志的编辑委员会成员。作为个人评论,我想说Jeff一直是编委会中编辑们最好的朋友——每年他都是Coghlan奖的第一批投票者之一,他的投票通常提供了编委会其他成员情绪的预览,当被要求担任裁判时,他一直很愿意和建设性。每当我在澳大利亚经济史活动上看到他时,他总是努力花大量时间与年轻学者交谈。本期特刊的每篇论文都至少有一位作者的“威廉姆森号”为1——与杰夫有直接联系,要么是博士生,要么是合作者。在每个案例中,论文的主题都来自于与Jeff的早期合作。在整理本期杂志的过程中,我把重点放在了杰夫在澳大利亚、亚太和全球经济史方面的工作和合作上。这期的第一篇论文,“1870-1913年,从英国到美国、加拿大和澳大利亚/新西兰的移民:数量和质量”是杰夫的长期合作者之一蒂莫西·哈顿写的。从1988-1989年哈顿访问哈佛开始,杰夫和蒂姆共同发表了20多篇论文、章节和书籍。这些共同撰写的作品大多研究了国际移民的不同方面,这也是本文的主题。本文的研究重点是移民目的地。这一点在文献中没有得到充分的研究,这些文献通常集中在单一目的地国家-通常是美国,因为它在第一次世界大战之前接收了最多的移民(Abromitsky et al., 2012;周岁以下,1994)。通过关注单一目的地国家,文献忽略了这样一个事实,即在源头上,潜在移民有一个决定,即去哪里。本文从根本上扭转了文献中的正常方法来研究目的地的选择。本文不是考察从多个来源国向单一目的国的移民,而是考察从单一来源国向多个目的国的移民。选择美国、加拿大和澳大利亚是很自然的,因为在本研究期间,这三个目的地约占英国移民的90%。论文的大部分研究结果符合理论预期。 移民根据旅行成本、以前的移民和经济回报选择目的地国。旅行费用是由距离决定的,就澳大利亚/新西兰而言,是由移徙补贴的程度决定的。最近的移徙者是回乡的准移徙者的主要信息来源。因此,随着时间的推移,迁移率是正自相关的,例如,前一年到给定目的地的较高迁移率增加了本年度的迁移率。这篇论文发现了关于回报效应的混合证据。移民对目的国工资变化的反应与人力资本标准模型预测的方式一致。然而,在著名的Roy迁移模型(Borjas, 1987;Roy, 1951),这仍然是一个重要的未解之谜。美国的技能溢价(以相对工资衡量)远高于加拿大,尤其是澳大利亚/新西兰。然而,论文发现澳大利亚/新西兰接收了不成比例的技术移民。第二篇论文《亚洲四大贸易崩溃》的作者是杰夫的一位前博士生和长期合作伙伴凯文•奥鲁克,以及杰夫的三位“知识分子孙子”——艾伦•德•布罗姆黑德、艾伦•费尼霍夫和马库斯•兰普。杰夫和凯文还共同发表了20多篇论文、章节和书籍,主要是关于世界经济全球化的问题。本期的文章是一个更大项目的一部分,该项目研究反全球化反弹的原因和经济后果。贸易崩溃是反全球化反弹的重要表现,因为它们可能是经济衰退在国际上蔓延的重要机制。虽然存在大量关于大萧条期间美国和欧洲贸易崩溃的文献(de Bromhead et al., 2019;Kindleberger, 1973),关于世界其他地区的文章就少得多了。本文考察了1929-1933年期间亚洲人口最多的四个国家(中国、荷属东印度群岛、日本和印度)的贸易崩溃。对于前三个国家,他们构建了与42个伙伴国的38种大宗商品双边贸易的新数据集。然后,他们将贸易总值的下降分解为单独的数量和价格影响,并检查每个国家对不同商品和伙伴地区的下降程度。亚洲贸易的崩溃是戏剧性的。1929年至1931年间,这四个国家的名义进口价值下降了约40%,与世界贸易的总下降幅度大致相同。此后,这四个国家的道路出现了巨大的分歧。日本在1931年退出金本位制,其贸易迅速恢复,到1934年超过了1929年的水平。其他三个国家的贸易停滞或继续下降,1936年荷属东印度群岛的贸易水平低至1929年水平的25%左右。一个简单的分解表明,1929-1931年和1929-1933年期间,数量和价格对贸易下降都有影响,价格下降所占的平均份额与这两个时期的世界平均水平相似。相比之下,在2008-2009年的贸易崩溃中,价格对这些国家的作用远比对整个世界的作用重要。就这些国家的贸易构成和伙伴份额而言,贸易崩溃是不平衡的。在日本和荷属东印度群岛,耐用品贸易的降幅大于非耐用品贸易。中国的情况正好相反,作者将其解释为崩溃前趋势的延续,中国在1929年之前经历了快速的工业化和耐用品出口的增长。这次崩溃也有“殖民偏见”。与长期殖民者的贸易(例如,英国对印度的贸易或荷兰对荷属东印度群岛的贸易)下降的幅度大于与美国的贸易。第三篇论文《澳大利亚的商品盛衰周期和资源诅咒:1900年至2017年》是杰夫在澳大利亚主题方面的第一位合作者萨姆比特·巴塔查里亚(Sambit Bhattacharya)撰写的。Sambit和Jeff之前写过两篇关于商品价格冲击对澳大利亚经济影响的论文(Bhattacharyya &威廉姆森,2011;Bhattacharyya,Williamson, 2016),这是本文的主题。本文考察了20世纪的澳大利亚是否遭受了“资源诅咒”——由要素价格变化引起的商品价格暴涨后资源的不利再分配。例如,矿物价格上涨可能导致资本和劳动力重新分配到该部门,其结果是排挤制造业。在某些理论条件下,这种挤出的程度可能大到足以导致GDP下降。 考虑到澳大利亚丰富的土地禀赋和出口导向型增长的历史,澳大利亚经济学家承担了许多关于资源诅咒的早期理论和应用工作,这也许并不奇怪。尼瑞,1982;格里高利,1976)。然而,令人印象深刻的是,澳大利亚似乎没有受到资源诅咒的影响——如果有的话,澳大利亚的GDP增长在商品繁荣期间加速了。本文使用时间序列方法,特别是单方程误差修正模型,更正式地检验了这一命题。该模型用于估计澳大利亚GDP的决定因素和商品周期的影响。特别令人感兴趣的是“长20世纪”的三次商品繁荣:20世纪20年代初对羊毛和农产品需求的增加;朝鲜战争期间对矿产、羊毛和农产品的需求增加;以及21世纪初中国经济扩张带来的采矿业繁荣。结果表明,套用一句澳大利亚人熟知的短语,澳大利亚确实是一个“幸运的国家”(Horne, 1964),在每一个时期都经历了GDP的持续增长。正式的时间序列分析表明,不存在资源诅咒,在整个时期内,商品价格冲击的经济影响是积极的。最后,本文提出了一些关于为什么澳大利亚能够避免资源诅咒的猜测,而其他许多国家却因大宗商品繁荣而陷入贫困。第四篇论文《干散货航运和海运成本的演变,1850-2020》是杰夫全球化研究议程上的另一位合作者、知识分子孙辈戴维•杰克斯(David Jacks)与马丁•斯图默(Martin Stuermer)合著的。本文考虑了文献中确定的全球化的重要驱动因素,即运输成本下降(哈雷,1988;北,1958)。重点是航运成本,特别是干散货的运费,目前干散货占世界贸易量的一半左右。作者首先构建了一系列新的运费,这些运费综合了不同货币、始发港、目的地港和货物。然后,他们使用结构向量自回归模型检查运费变动的决定因素。他们的目标是确定不同类型的冲击对航运费率的影响,即燃料价格、航运需求、航运供应以及他们所谓的“剩余冲击”。他们发现,在研究期间,运费大幅下降,研究结束时的运费仅为研究开始时的20%。然而,这种下降不是线性的,并且与大量文献一致,认为两次世界大战之间的时期经历了实质性的去全球化(James, 2009;Kindleberger, 1973),实际上从1910年到1950年是增加的。同比变化可能相当可观。数据中的这些“峰值”可归因于四种不同类型的冲击。例如,1973年至1979年间,由于石油输出国组织(opec)主导的油价飙升,运费大幅上涨。他们表明,在整个时期,航运需求冲击的影响最大,也最持久。需求冲击可以解释全球运费总波动的一半左右。相比之下,航运供应和燃料价格冲击的影响相当温和,两者加起来对费率的影响略小于需求冲击。需求冲击也是最持久的,其影响会持续10-15年。残余效应是最小的。期末论文《总是平等主义?》《澳大利亚收入不平等1870-1910》是杰夫·威廉姆森本人和他最近的长期合著者劳拉·潘扎合著的。这篇论文是一个更大的项目的一部分,该项目研究1700年以来新大陆的增长、生活水平和不平等。杰夫和劳拉写了一系列关于“澳大利亚例外论”的论文,即高平均收入和低不平等的结合,是19世纪和20世纪澳大利亚的特征。Williamson, 2019, 2020)。人们早就知道,澳大利亚在19世纪的增长经历是例外的。一个世纪以来,澳大利亚从一个单一的欧洲殖民地——悉尼的流放地——变成了世界上最富有的国家。有大量的文献关于为什么澳大利亚变得富有(麦克莱恩,2007年,2013年)。关于澳大利亚在富裕过程中的不平等现象的著述要少得多,而且这方面的文献只从20世纪开始(阿特金森&利,2007)。本文将有关澳大利亚不平等的文献追溯至19世纪。作者使用来自殖民地人口普查、会期论文、新南威尔士州官方年鉴和蓝皮书的数据,构建了新南威尔士州和维多利亚州按职业划分的社会收入表。 他们指出,社会表格显示,在1870年,澳大利亚比美国、英国或欧洲更平等。此外,在接下来的40年里,澳大利亚与其他富裕国家之间的不平等差距扩大了;收入不平等在澳大利亚有所下降,而在其他地方有所上升。收入不平等的下降可以从几个替代指标中明显看出:包括基尼系数、收入最高的10%和1%的份额、收入最高的10%的份额与收入最低的10%的份额之比。他们认为,在教育和移民的推动下,收入增加和不平等减少背后的原因是熟练劳动力供应的增加。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
CiteScore
1.00
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信