{"title":"On the Auction Block: The Garment Industry and the Deindustrialization of New York City","authors":"A. Battle","doi":"10.1017/S0147547922000059","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Abstract Several important studies of New York City's fiscal crisis of the 1970s identify the city's deindustrialization as a key component. The flight of manufacturers from New York fostered a racialized unemployment crisis while eroding the city's tax base, undermining its ability to meet increasing demands for social services, creating incentives for policymakers to focus on real estate development as the motor of the city's political economy, and weakening the institutions, especially labor unions, that had served as bulwarks of the city's unique (by American standards) brand of municipal social democracy. This article explores the roots of deindustrialization in one of New York City's most important industries, the manufacture of clothing. Capital flight, in the form of “runaway shops,” began as early as the teens, when the International Ladies' Garment Workers Union (ILG) established itself through a series of key battles. The handmaiden to runaway shops was the reemergence of contracting, whereby the assembly of garments was disaggregated in terms of time, space, and legal identity. The twin forces of contracting and runaways threatened the existence of the ILG by draining garment work out of its New York City stronghold. I trace efforts to combat it through their culmination in what I call the “New Deal settlement,” a stabilization of the industry across what contemporary analysts called the “New York Production Area.” This settlement, I argue, was at once geographical, political, cultural, and economic. Its goal was to limit competition and establish a new equilibrium in the garment industry, one that could permit manufacturers acceptable profits without resort to the sweatshop. I borrow the notion of a “regulating capital” from the economist Anwar Shaikh to describe these attempts to engineer a reproducible cost structure. As soon as the New Deal settlement emerged, manufacturers began working to collapse it. I trace the dispersion of garment work to places like northeastern Pennsylvania, where manufacturers enlisted the wives and daughters of unemployed anthracite miners to sew their garments. Factory owners, sometimes linked to organized crime, sought to establish a new regulating capital rooted in relationships of domination, protected by authoritarian local governments. When imported garments arrived in the 1950s, a new regulating capital rooted in a worldwide sweatshop economy forced manufacturers to leave Pennsylvania for the US South, the Caribbean, and beyond. In an attempt to link political economy with social history, I stress that the currency of regulating capitals, particularly in labor-intensive industries, is political domination. Throughout, I illustrate these processes with reference to Judy Bond, the blousemaker whose departure for the US South prompted a widely publicized but unsuccessful national boycott led by the ILG. In terms of the historiography of New York City's deindustrialization, this account offers an alternative emphasis to that of Robert Fitch, whose influential account emphasized “a conscious policy” to deindustrialize the city, overseen by the real estate industry. Instead, I show how deindustrialization was rooted in significant ways in the dynamics of competition themselves, shaped at each stage by particular social relationships, state policy, and world politics.","PeriodicalId":14353,"journal":{"name":"International Labor and Working-Class History","volume":"103 1","pages":"179 - 201"},"PeriodicalIF":0.5000,"publicationDate":"2022-10-20","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"International Labor and Working-Class History","FirstCategoryId":"98","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S0147547922000059","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"历史学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q1","JCRName":"HISTORY","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Abstract
Abstract Several important studies of New York City's fiscal crisis of the 1970s identify the city's deindustrialization as a key component. The flight of manufacturers from New York fostered a racialized unemployment crisis while eroding the city's tax base, undermining its ability to meet increasing demands for social services, creating incentives for policymakers to focus on real estate development as the motor of the city's political economy, and weakening the institutions, especially labor unions, that had served as bulwarks of the city's unique (by American standards) brand of municipal social democracy. This article explores the roots of deindustrialization in one of New York City's most important industries, the manufacture of clothing. Capital flight, in the form of “runaway shops,” began as early as the teens, when the International Ladies' Garment Workers Union (ILG) established itself through a series of key battles. The handmaiden to runaway shops was the reemergence of contracting, whereby the assembly of garments was disaggregated in terms of time, space, and legal identity. The twin forces of contracting and runaways threatened the existence of the ILG by draining garment work out of its New York City stronghold. I trace efforts to combat it through their culmination in what I call the “New Deal settlement,” a stabilization of the industry across what contemporary analysts called the “New York Production Area.” This settlement, I argue, was at once geographical, political, cultural, and economic. Its goal was to limit competition and establish a new equilibrium in the garment industry, one that could permit manufacturers acceptable profits without resort to the sweatshop. I borrow the notion of a “regulating capital” from the economist Anwar Shaikh to describe these attempts to engineer a reproducible cost structure. As soon as the New Deal settlement emerged, manufacturers began working to collapse it. I trace the dispersion of garment work to places like northeastern Pennsylvania, where manufacturers enlisted the wives and daughters of unemployed anthracite miners to sew their garments. Factory owners, sometimes linked to organized crime, sought to establish a new regulating capital rooted in relationships of domination, protected by authoritarian local governments. When imported garments arrived in the 1950s, a new regulating capital rooted in a worldwide sweatshop economy forced manufacturers to leave Pennsylvania for the US South, the Caribbean, and beyond. In an attempt to link political economy with social history, I stress that the currency of regulating capitals, particularly in labor-intensive industries, is political domination. Throughout, I illustrate these processes with reference to Judy Bond, the blousemaker whose departure for the US South prompted a widely publicized but unsuccessful national boycott led by the ILG. In terms of the historiography of New York City's deindustrialization, this account offers an alternative emphasis to that of Robert Fitch, whose influential account emphasized “a conscious policy” to deindustrialize the city, overseen by the real estate industry. Instead, I show how deindustrialization was rooted in significant ways in the dynamics of competition themselves, shaped at each stage by particular social relationships, state policy, and world politics.
关于20世纪70年代纽约市财政危机的几项重要研究认为,该市的去工业化是一个关键组成部分。制造商从纽约外逃,助长了一场种族化的失业危机,同时侵蚀了该市的税基,削弱了该市满足日益增长的社会服务需求的能力,促使政策制定者将重点放在房地产开发上,将其作为该市政治经济的发动机,并削弱了一些机构,尤其是工会,这些机构曾是纽约市独特的(按美国标准)城市社会民主的堡垒。本文探讨了纽约市最重要的产业之一服装制造业的去工业化根源。资本外逃,以“失控的商店”的形式,早在十几岁的时候就开始了,当时国际女装工人联盟(ILG)通过一系列关键的斗争建立了自己。脱手商店的女仆是契约的重新出现,在这种契约中,服装的组装按照时间、空间和法律身份进行了分解。合同和出走的双重力量威胁着ILG的存在,使其在纽约的大本营的服装业务流失。我追溯了与之斗争的努力,我称之为“新政解决方案”(New Deal settlement),这是当时分析家称之为“纽约生产区域”(New York Production Area)的行业稳定。我认为,这个聚落同时是地理、政治、文化和经济的聚落。它的目标是限制竞争,在服装行业建立一种新的平衡,这种平衡可以让制造商在不诉诸血汗工厂的情况下获得可接受的利润。我借用经济学家安瓦尔•谢赫(Anwar Shaikh)的“监管资本”(regulatory capital)概念,来描述这些设计可复制成本结构的尝试。新政的解决方案一出现,制造商们就开始努力瓦解它。我将服装业的分散追溯到宾夕法尼亚东北部等地,在那里,制造商招募失业的无烟煤矿工的妻子和女儿来缝制他们的服装。工厂主有时与有组织犯罪有关联,他们试图建立一种新的监管资本,这种资本植根于统治关系,受到威权的地方政府的保护。20世纪50年代,当进口服装到来时,一个植根于全球血汗工厂经济的新监管资本迫使制造商离开宾夕法尼亚州,前往美国南部、加勒比海和其他地区。在试图将政治经济学与社会历史联系起来的过程中,我强调规范资本的货币,特别是在劳动密集型产业中,是政治支配。在整个过程中,我以朱迪·邦德(Judy Bond)为例来说明这些过程。这位女衬衫制造商前往美国南方,引发了由ILG领导的广泛宣传但未成功的全国抵制。就纽约市去工业化的史学而言,这一描述提供了罗伯特·费奇(Robert Fitch)的另一种侧重点,后者颇具影响力的描述强调了由房地产行业监督的城市去工业化的“有意识政策”。相反,我展示了去工业化是如何以重要的方式植根于竞争本身的动态,在每个阶段都受到特定的社会关系、国家政策和世界政治的影响。
期刊介绍:
ILWCH has an international reputation for scholarly innovation and quality. It explores diverse topics from globalisation and workers’ rights to class and consumption, labour movements, class identities and cultures, unions, and working-class politics. ILWCH publishes original research, review essays, conference reports from around the world, and an acclaimed scholarly controversy section. Comparative and cross-disciplinary, the journal is of interest to scholars in history, sociology, political science, labor studies, global studies, and a wide range of other fields and disciplines. Published for International Labor and Working-Class History, Inc.