Review of Hanoch Dagan, A Liberal Theory of Property

IF 0.6 4区 社会学 Q2 LAW
Cathy Sherry
{"title":"Review of Hanoch Dagan, A Liberal Theory of Property","authors":"Cathy Sherry","doi":"10.1017/S1744552321000707","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"I read A Liberal Theory of Property through the lens of my own area of expertise – multi-owned housing – and I felt my heart lift as many of Dagan’s arguments unfolded. Dagan’s three-pillared liberal theory of property creates a profound and practical tool for ensuring that multi-owned properties manifest as their best, not worst, selves. In this review, I accept Dagan’s invitation to use his book ‘to examine the performance of existing property systems’ against his liberal theory, with a view to accurately identifying the source of problems and finding a clear path to reform (Dagan, 2021, p. 68). The rise of multi-owned properties is the most significant change in modern property landscapes in a century. I do not necessarily mean US-style common-interest communities, which, while important, have limited popularity in countries that lack a strong tradition of small-group autonomy and/or segregation. I mean condominiums. While people have long lived in apartment buildings, without modern engineering, those buildings were human-scale; load-bearing walls cannot go higher than twelve storeys. The invention of steel frames and curtain walls revolutionised our use of land, allowing owners to exploit vast tracts of airspace. High-rise residential buildings now soar 150 storeys into the air; include complex plant, equipment and facilities; and house hundreds of residents. Not only are modern buildings of a scale unknown in human history; the relationships between residents has radically altered. In the past, buildings were typically owned by a single landlord and occupied by tenants. The dominant legal relationship was vertical, and although clearly open to the interpersonal domination that Dagan rightly identifies as inherent to property, the landlord–tenant relationship is relatively easy to regulate with the right political will and/or is inherently limited if its conception is based on Dagan’s third pillar of relational justice. However, in the post-World War II period, countries around the world recognised that (1) increasing numbers of citizens were going to live in mediumor high-rise buildings, (2) that it was ideal for citizens to own their own home and so (3) legal mechanisms would be needed to facilitate this. In most of the common law world – with the notable exception of the US, Israel and Scotland – positive obligations (or ‘real covenants’) on freehold land are still impermissible. This is a fundamental impediment to creating freehold fee-simple titles to apartments, because those titles must be coupled with a necessary positive obligation to maintain the building. As a result, many jurisdictions needed legislation to overcome this prohibition. That legislation is variously called strata title, unit title, sectional title, community title, commonhold or condominiums. It can subdivide buildings or land, creating highor low-rise communities, and its fundamental purpose is to create fees simple coupled with positive obligations and restrictions. It is the legal equivalent of US condominiums and common-interest communities. Regardless of jurisdiction, all these legal structures radically change the legal relations inside a building. Whereas tenants have minimal control over each other through nuisance law or enforcement of the covenant for quiet enjoyment against a common landlord, a condominium structure grants private citizens enormous power over their neighbours’ lives. Control is exerted not simply over collectively owned spaces, but also over privately owned homes. Further, the creation of a separate governing body corporate or association, initially controlled by the developer, creates the potential","PeriodicalId":45455,"journal":{"name":"International Journal of Law in Context","volume":"18 1","pages":"241 - 244"},"PeriodicalIF":0.6000,"publicationDate":"2022-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"1","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"International Journal of Law in Context","FirstCategoryId":"90","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744552321000707","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"LAW","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 1

Abstract

I read A Liberal Theory of Property through the lens of my own area of expertise – multi-owned housing – and I felt my heart lift as many of Dagan’s arguments unfolded. Dagan’s three-pillared liberal theory of property creates a profound and practical tool for ensuring that multi-owned properties manifest as their best, not worst, selves. In this review, I accept Dagan’s invitation to use his book ‘to examine the performance of existing property systems’ against his liberal theory, with a view to accurately identifying the source of problems and finding a clear path to reform (Dagan, 2021, p. 68). The rise of multi-owned properties is the most significant change in modern property landscapes in a century. I do not necessarily mean US-style common-interest communities, which, while important, have limited popularity in countries that lack a strong tradition of small-group autonomy and/or segregation. I mean condominiums. While people have long lived in apartment buildings, without modern engineering, those buildings were human-scale; load-bearing walls cannot go higher than twelve storeys. The invention of steel frames and curtain walls revolutionised our use of land, allowing owners to exploit vast tracts of airspace. High-rise residential buildings now soar 150 storeys into the air; include complex plant, equipment and facilities; and house hundreds of residents. Not only are modern buildings of a scale unknown in human history; the relationships between residents has radically altered. In the past, buildings were typically owned by a single landlord and occupied by tenants. The dominant legal relationship was vertical, and although clearly open to the interpersonal domination that Dagan rightly identifies as inherent to property, the landlord–tenant relationship is relatively easy to regulate with the right political will and/or is inherently limited if its conception is based on Dagan’s third pillar of relational justice. However, in the post-World War II period, countries around the world recognised that (1) increasing numbers of citizens were going to live in mediumor high-rise buildings, (2) that it was ideal for citizens to own their own home and so (3) legal mechanisms would be needed to facilitate this. In most of the common law world – with the notable exception of the US, Israel and Scotland – positive obligations (or ‘real covenants’) on freehold land are still impermissible. This is a fundamental impediment to creating freehold fee-simple titles to apartments, because those titles must be coupled with a necessary positive obligation to maintain the building. As a result, many jurisdictions needed legislation to overcome this prohibition. That legislation is variously called strata title, unit title, sectional title, community title, commonhold or condominiums. It can subdivide buildings or land, creating highor low-rise communities, and its fundamental purpose is to create fees simple coupled with positive obligations and restrictions. It is the legal equivalent of US condominiums and common-interest communities. Regardless of jurisdiction, all these legal structures radically change the legal relations inside a building. Whereas tenants have minimal control over each other through nuisance law or enforcement of the covenant for quiet enjoyment against a common landlord, a condominium structure grants private citizens enormous power over their neighbours’ lives. Control is exerted not simply over collectively owned spaces, but also over privately owned homes. Further, the creation of a separate governing body corporate or association, initially controlled by the developer, creates the potential
汉诺克·达甘:《自由主义财产理论》述评
我通过自己的专业领域——多产权住房——的视角阅读了《自由财产理论》,当达根的许多论点展开时,我感到自己的心得到了提升。达根的三支柱自由主义财产理论创造了一个深刻而实用的工具,以确保多重财产表现出它们最好的自我,而不是最坏的自我。在这篇评论中,我接受达根的邀请,使用他的书来“检查现有财产制度的表现”,反对他的自由主义理论,以期准确地确定问题的根源,并找到一条明确的改革道路(达根,2021年,第68页)。多业主地产的兴起是一个世纪以来现代地产格局最显著的变化。我并不一定是指美国式的共同利益社区,这种社区虽然很重要,但在缺乏小团体自治和/或隔离传统的国家中,受欢迎程度有限。我是说公寓。虽然人们长期居住在公寓楼里,但没有现代工程,这些建筑是人性化的;承重墙的高度不能超过12层。钢框架和幕墙的发明彻底改变了我们对土地的使用,允许业主开发大片的空域。高层住宅楼现在高达150层;包括复杂厂房、设备和设施;并容纳数百名居民。不仅是人类历史上规模空前的现代建筑;居民之间的关系已经彻底改变。在过去,建筑物通常由一个房东所有,由租户居住。占主导地位的法律关系是垂直的,尽管显然对达根正确地认为是财产固有的人际支配开放,但房东-房客关系相对容易用正确的政治意愿来调节,并且/或者如果其概念基于达根的第三个支柱关系正义,则其本质上是有限的。然而,在第二次世界大战后,世界各国认识到:(1)越来越多的公民将住在中高层建筑中,(2)公民拥有自己的房子是理想的,因此(3)需要法律机制来促进这一点。在大多数普通法国家(美国、以色列和苏格兰除外),对永久业权土地的积极义务(或“实际契约”)仍然是不允许的。这从根本上阻碍了建立公寓的永久业权,因为这些所有权必须与维护建筑物的必要积极义务相结合。因此,许多司法管辖区需要立法来克服这一禁令。这种立法被称为分层产权、单位产权、分段产权、社区产权、公有产权或共管产权。它可以细分建筑物或土地,创造更高的低层社区,其基本目的是创造简单的费用,加上积极的义务和限制。它在法律上相当于美国的共管公寓和共同利益社区。无论管辖权如何,所有这些法律结构都从根本上改变了建筑物内部的法律关系。尽管租户通过妨害法或对共同房东的安静享受契约的执行,对彼此的控制微乎其微,但公寓结构赋予了私人公民对邻居生活的巨大权力。控制不仅适用于集体拥有的空间,也适用于私人拥有的住宅。此外,创建一个独立的管理机构,公司或协会,最初由开发人员控制,创造了潜力
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
CiteScore
1.60
自引率
12.50%
发文量
47
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信