{"title":"Revisiting Incentive-Based Contracts.","authors":"Wendy Netter Epstein","doi":"","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p><p>Incentive-based pay is rational, intuitive, and popular. Agency theory tells us\nthat a principal seeking to align its incentives with an agent's should be able to\nsimply pay the agent to achieve the principal's desired results. Indeed, this\nstrategy has long been used across diverse industries-from executive\ncompensation to education, professional sports to public service-but with mixed\nresults. Now a new convert to incentive compensation has appeared on the scene:\nthe United States' behemoth health-care industry. In many ways, the incentive\nmismatch story is the same. Insurance companies and employers are concerned\nabout constraining the cost of care, and patients are concerned about quality of\ncare. Physicians lack an adequate financial incentive to pay attention to either.\nHealth care's recent move away from the traditional fee-for-service\ncompensation model to incentive pay is perhaps unsurprising.\nBut there is a problem: mixed preliminary evidence and potential mal-effects\non vulnerable third-party patients. This Article employs a new lens-the legal\nand behavioral literature on optimal contract specificity-to suggest why\nincentive pay is problematic and why the health-care experience will be no\ndifferent than other industries. The use of incentive pay is a change in contractdrafting\nstrategy, a decision to write a more detailed, control-based contract\nrather than one that relies on discretion. The contracts literature suggests that this\nstrategy will only work well where simple compliance is the goal rather than\ncreativity or innovation. The health industry will not succeed in implementing\nincentive pay better than other industries have. What it needs is to recognize the\nlimits of incentive pay and implement it sparingly. The new Trump\nAdministration may be particularly primed to heed this call.</p>","PeriodicalId":85893,"journal":{"name":"Yale journal of health policy, law, and ethics","volume":"17 1","pages":"1-59"},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2017-01-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Yale journal of health policy, law, and ethics","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
Abstract
Incentive-based pay is rational, intuitive, and popular. Agency theory tells us
that a principal seeking to align its incentives with an agent's should be able to
simply pay the agent to achieve the principal's desired results. Indeed, this
strategy has long been used across diverse industries-from executive
compensation to education, professional sports to public service-but with mixed
results. Now a new convert to incentive compensation has appeared on the scene:
the United States' behemoth health-care industry. In many ways, the incentive
mismatch story is the same. Insurance companies and employers are concerned
about constraining the cost of care, and patients are concerned about quality of
care. Physicians lack an adequate financial incentive to pay attention to either.
Health care's recent move away from the traditional fee-for-service
compensation model to incentive pay is perhaps unsurprising.
But there is a problem: mixed preliminary evidence and potential mal-effects
on vulnerable third-party patients. This Article employs a new lens-the legal
and behavioral literature on optimal contract specificity-to suggest why
incentive pay is problematic and why the health-care experience will be no
different than other industries. The use of incentive pay is a change in contractdrafting
strategy, a decision to write a more detailed, control-based contract
rather than one that relies on discretion. The contracts literature suggests that this
strategy will only work well where simple compliance is the goal rather than
creativity or innovation. The health industry will not succeed in implementing
incentive pay better than other industries have. What it needs is to recognize the
limits of incentive pay and implement it sparingly. The new Trump
Administration may be particularly primed to heed this call.