Liz Truss: More than a lettuce?

IF 1.8 Q3 ECONOMICS
J R Shackleton
{"title":"Liz Truss: More than a lettuce?","authors":"J R Shackleton","doi":"10.1111/ecaf.12695","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"<p>\n <span>Anthony Seldon</span> (with Jonathan Meakin), <span>Truss at 10: How Not to Be Prime Minister</span>. Atlantic Books. <span>2024</span>. 366 + xvi pp. £22.00 (hbk). ISBN: 978-1805462132. £12.99 (pbk). ISBN: 978-1805462163. £11.99 (ebk). ISBN: 978-1805462156</p><p>\n <span>Liz Truss</span>, <span>Ten Years to Save the West: Lessons from the Only Conservative in the Room</span>. Biteback Publishing. <span>320</span> pp. £20.00 (hbk). ISBN: 978-1785908576. £10.99 (pbk). ISBN: 978-1785909238. £14.99 (ebk). ISBN: 978-1785908637</p><p>On 6 September 2022, Liz Truss replaced Boris Johnson to become Queen Elizabeth II's 15th and last prime minister of the United Kingdom. Two days later, the queen was dead. Following a short period of official mourning, Truss and her Chancellor of the Exchequer<sup>1</sup> Kwasi Kwarteng launched a ‘mini-budget’ which was intended to cut taxes dramatically without any immediate matching spending cuts. Coming on top of an earlier (and potentially extremely expensive) commitment to subsidising energy prices, this sparked a serious financial crisis. This led to Truss dismissing Kwarteng and installing a new chancellor, who then scrapped almost the entire proposed fiscal package. This U-turn, together with bond-buying by the Bank of England to stave off a potential collapse of pension funds, stabilised the markets. However, she had been compromised by this reversal of her signature policy, became subject to public ridicule, and quickly lost the support of the parliamentary Conservative Party. She had little option but to resign as Conservative leader and prime minister on 20 October after just 44 days in 10 Downing Street. Five days later she was replaced as prime minister by Rishi Sunak. This was the shortest period of office of any British prime minister.</p><p>On 11 October, <i>The Economist</i> (<span>2024</span>) had published a leader column which compared Truss's expected shelf-life to that of an iceberg lettuce. This image was seized upon by the tabloid <i>Daily Star</i>, which began to livestream a wilting supermarket lettuce, soon attracting a huge number of viewers and becoming a meme which persisted well after her resignation. In August 2024, for example, Truss walked out of a stage appearance to promote <i>Ten Years to Save the West</i> after some jokers unfurled a remote control banner with a picture of a lettuce and the legend ‘I crashed the economy’ (<i>BBC News</i>, <span>2024</span>). She was reportedly unamused.</p><p>The Truss government was certainly something of a fiasco. But why? These two books offer contrasting reasons. While Sir Anthony Seldon largely blames the personal inadequacies of Britain's 56th prime minister, Truss herself sees her administration as fatally undermined by ‘the Blob’, an amorphous grouping including “the quangocracy, an unaccountable judiciary and undemocratic international institutions” (p. 286). She argues that her experience suggests that bringing about radical change to a political consensus that is stifling economic growth in Britain and elsewhere in the West faces formidable obstacles.</p><p>So was the Truss episode no more significant than a tired lettuce? Or was her failure symptomatic of a deeper malaise?</p><p>Both Seldon and Truss were fairly prominent public figures well before her brief premiership, but they had never spoken until a summer party in July 2023. Seldon recounts the occasion:</p><p>Seldon's book, and his method of approach, need contextualising. He is a prolific author, having written or edited 50 books (conveniently listed at the back of his Truss volume). He has written on a variety of subjects, but many of his books concern the role of prime minister, a job which he calls ‘the Impossible Office’ (Seldon et al., <span>2021</span>). He has covered most post-war British PMs: volumes have appeared on Winston Churchill, Edward Heath, Margaret Thatcher, John Major, Tony Blair, Gordon Brown, David Cameron, Theresa May, Boris Johnson and now Truss. I imagine he is already working on Truss's successor, Rishi Sunak. Each of the volumes from Gordon Brown onwards have been titled ‘So-and-so at 10’.</p><p>Seldon is not the typical twenty-first-century senior academic, with time and a large research grant on his hands. He has been, for much of his adult life, a part-time historian. His day job was for many years as the Master of Wellington College, a leading independent school. Subsequently he headed the University of Buckingham (where I work and made his acquaintance) for a five-year stint, and then went back to secondary education, taking over a school whose head had been murdered in tragic circumstances. Apart from these commitments, Seldon has for years been a busy media commentator on the political scene. So the production of this substantial book, only 18 months after the activities it chronicles, is an impressive achievement – as were his previous volumes of instant history.</p><p>So how does he do it? Well, he's not quite the lone author and in <i>Truss at 10</i> he explains (pp. 15–16, 331–2) how his publications are a team effort. In this case his team was fronted by Jonathan Meakin, with whom Seldon has collaborated on previous occasions. With the team, he sets out the structure – chapter heads – for the book. He then carries out the interviews, 120 in this case, with participants in the events covered. These constitute, he says, about 80 per cent of the content of the book. The team “produces briefings for each chapter, integrating these with other published and documented material”. He then has “the easy and fun part, writing the book” (p. 331).</p><p>The structure chosen for this volume is interesting. Seldon has previously – in his book <i>The Impossible Office?</i> (Seldon et al., <span>2021</span>) and in a <i>New Statesman</i> article (Seldon, <span>2022</span>) – set out conditions which he believes are necessary for a prime minister to be successful in office, and which most inevitably fail to achieve. In the Truss book he offers a variant of these approaches. Although there is a semi-chronological sequencing, it is the conditions for success, ten in all, which provide the chapter headings.</p><p>The first requirement is to ‘Secure the Power Base’, which in Truss's case was the Parliamentary Conservative Party. As Seldon points out, right from the start Truss's position was shaky. She had only a very limited following amongst MPs and was not the parliamentary party's choice for leader; in the first ballot she came third, and after a series of eliminations she was still well behind Rishi Sunak in the final vote. Her accession to the leadership depended on the votes of Conservative Party members in the country, and a substantial block of MPs never really supported her and indeed were hostile from the start.</p><p>Then, says Seldon, prime ministers need to have ‘A Clear and Realistic Plan for Government’. Unlike her three immediate predecessors (Johnson, May, Cameron), Truss had strong ideological priors, and her strategy was clear: it involved tax cuts, deregulation and shrinking the state. But she had not established a consensus amongst her MPs for rapid action. Seldon argues that her haste in producing the mini-budget, her insistence on bypassing or disregarding the establishment (the Bank of England, the Treasury and the Office for Budget Responsibility) and an ill-thought-out energy price guarantee were unrealistic.</p><p>A prime minister must ‘Appoint the Best Cabinet/Team’. Seldon is of the opinion that Liz Truss should have brought in the most talented and most representative members of the party, irrespective of their political stance, to give her a chance of maintaining a strong government. Instead of choosing a broad-based cabinet, she chose a mediocre team which largely consisted of friends and supporters and left out many experienced and substantial figures (p. 103).</p><p>Prime ministers must ‘Command the Big Events’. In her first weeks, Truss faced two such big events: the death of the queen, and the energy crisis – sharply rising gas prices consequent on the Ukraine war. While Seldon concedes that Truss conducted herself with dignity over the transition to the new monarch, she lacked a “sense of history and personal gravitas” (p. 143), which meant that she did not rise to the occasion with the flourish and unifying rhetoric of a Churchill but rather shrank into the background, worrying about tripping up during ceremonial duties. As for energy, having first ruled out any support package, Truss was “spooked” (p. 121) by briefings and went to the opposite extreme, announcing support which threatened at the time to cost up to £150 billion, though in the end it cost more like £40 billion.</p><p>Seldon also thinks a successful prime minister must ‘Be Credible and Highly Regarded Abroad’. Despite her experience as foreign secretary, Truss is seen as failing this test. She was solid on Ukraine, and a robust critic of China. But Seldon sees her as failing to get on with the Europeans and, particularly, the Americans. President Biden, he says (on no quoted evidence, incidentally) “viewed Truss sceptically as a know-nothing upstart” (p. 159).</p><p>You must ‘Learn How to be Prime Minister’ by being prepared to listen and take advice. Here Seldon sees Truss as constitutionally incapable of taking on board and really hearing views which conflict with her own. She is fundamentally lacking in judgment (p. 184).</p><p>It goes almost without saying that PMs should ‘Avoid Major Policy Failures’. Seldon can hardly avoid seeing the mini-budget as a massive policy error. He calls it the “greatest example of its kind in modern history” (p. 216). Part of this was its timing, for it “might have worked earlier in the year, but not with inflation running at 9.9 per cent and the expectation of it rising to between 11 and 12 per cent” (p. 216).</p><p>Of course, a PM must ‘Maintain a Reputation for Economic Competence’, and the fallout from the mini-budget appears to be Truss's most obvious failing. The expensive energy price cap commitment, followed by cutting taxes without accompanying spending cuts,<sup>2</sup> led to a domestic financial crisis, with bond yields shooting up, and a run on sterling which left the pound at its lowest-ever value against the dollar.</p><p>Seldon's ninth rule of premiership is ‘Avoid U-turns’ on major policy issues. In light of the reaction to the mini-budget, Seldon believes Truss had no option but to scrap the proposals. But this is “beside the point. She implemented the biggest U-turn in modern prime ministerial history and it didn't work for her” (p. 284).</p><p>Finally, a PM must ‘Retain the Confidence of the Party’. As noted earlier, Truss never had a strong base in the parliamentary party, and did nothing to build one. With the mini-budget crisis, followed by resignations and a botched vote on fracking, the febrile mood of Conservative MPs made her continuation in office impossible.</p><p>While it is difficult to dispute some of this analysis, there is a rather predictable feel to it all. Seldon clearly doesn't think much of Liz Truss, or of her project of radical free-market economics. Sir Anthony is, as many readers will know, the son of Arthur Seldon. Arthur was, together with Ralph Harris, a key figure in the development of the IEA (and the founding editor of this journal). He was a leading influence in the revival of policy-directed classical economic thinking in the UK and the wider world from the 1950s to the 1980s. It is interesting to speculate whether he would have been more sympathetic to Truss than his son, who incidentally doesn't seem to think much of today's IEA.<sup>3</sup> Sir Anthony's politics are rarely explicit but are broadly centrist. He was strongly against Brexit, and he has a very low opinion of Boris Johnson. He respects the expertise of the Treasury and the Bank of England. He's probably not a fan of Donald Trump.</p><p>To be fair, Seldon does occasionally try to balance his criticisms of Truss by mentioning some of her strengths. He thinks she was making a tolerable fist of her role as foreign secretary, and emphasises that she was good at appreciating intelligence and reading reports (p. 163). He credits her “irrepressible optimism” (p. 168), her energy (p. 170) and (in sharp contrast to Johnson) her hard work (p. 172).</p><p>Nevertheless, the overall impression is very strongly negative. It is fed on page after page by comments usually attributed to ‘an aide’ or ‘an official’, which are simply opinions or speculation with little factual basis. Thus Truss is “robotic, brain-dead” (p. 28) “stupid and capricious” (p. 38), she displays “verbal incontinence” and “preening” (p. 61), her grasp of market economics is “superficial” (p. 68). She is said to suffer from “a deep inner anxiety” (p. 78), she is “a figure of ridicule” (p. 104), is “plain bonkers” (p. 169), “irritable, paranoid and even unhinged” (p. 179) and possibly autistic (p. 181). She is “intolerant and suspicious” (p. 179). She seems “positively to rejoice in aggravating colleagues” (p. 60), and enjoys “humiliating her team in front of others” (p. 79). Referring to her support for the cut in international development spending under Johnson, Seldon himself says that “any human damage caused by these cuts was of no apparent concern to her” (p. 151). Elsewhere, rubbishing two birds with one stone, he writes that “her vanity, neediness and willingness to trample over others was of Johnsonian proportions” (p. 184). Remember that, although Seldon has evidently listened to a lot of people bad-mouthing these successive prime ministers, he has not spoken to either Truss or Johnson about their careers and experience.</p><p>Occasionally this sort of stuff takes us into dangerous territory. For example, there is speculation about a dossier said to contain details of “her indiscretions, her drinking and even cocaine use by others among her team” (p. 43). This is just a possibility mentioned in passing as a fear expressed by “one of her team”, and there is no evidence that such a dossier ever existed or that its alleged contents have any substance. But there is a smear there which cannot avoid leaving an impression on the reader.</p><p>An even more egregious example refers to the hectic hours when Truss and Kwasi Kwarteng were considering spending cuts to offset their planned tax reductions. Alex Boyd, a civil servant, is met by colleagues who tell him that “We've been told that they're looking at stopping cancer treatment on the [National Health Service]” (p. 245). It's not easy to make out who is saying what, but this appears to be Boyd telling Seldon that he was told by colleagues that they had been told that Truss and Kwarteng<sup>4</sup> were considering this. Needless to say, this several-degrees-of-separation hearsay found its way into the media on the book's publication (e.g. Stacey, <span>2024</span>), forcing Truss to deny that such an implausible policy was ever considered. Possibly some advisor or even one of the principals themselves made a joke in poor taste, but the idea that Truss was seriously prepared to put lives at risk in such a manner is just another example of the way in which she is repeatedly painted in the worst possible light.</p><p>As I have said, Seldon's method involves a heavy reliance on interviews with nameless individuals. We have no way of knowing who these witnesses were, or how much credence should be given to them. Many will have been relatively junior (and probably now rather disillusioned) members of Truss's entourage; many will have been political opponents or otherwise have an axe to grind. While obviously needing to protect his sources, it is a pity Seldon could not have given us some indication of the proportions who were MPs, officials or advisors, and how exactly they were recruited. Did they volunteer, or were they approached by Seldon's team? If the latter, how many of those approached refused? And it would be useful to know how the interviews were structured: was there a set of standard questions, or were they more free-flowing?</p><p>It would also be interesting to know the extent to which the drafts produced by his researchers shaped Seldon's conclusions. Were the extensive negative remarks I have noted chosen to support a prior view, or were they forced to his attention because so many interviewees were critical of Truss?</p><p>This is not, therefore, a study of the kind which leads to refereed articles in academic journals. It's not necessarily the worse for that, as the general reader will find it flows along nicely, but Seldon is not a trained political scientist. Nor, of course, is he an economist: one of the weaknesses of this book is its neglect of economics. There is no analysis of the UK's poor economic performance to which Truss and Kwarteng were reacting, and no serious examination – which could already have drawn on extensive official and academic sources – of what they were proposing. The financial market reaction to the mini-budget is barely covered, and in particular the issue of the liability-driven investments (LDIs)<sup>5</sup> is only sketched very briefly.</p><p>I admire Sir Anthony, and this rapidly-produced book is a considerable achievement. But it is essentially long-form journalism, rushed out to meet a demand for in-depth storytelling and comment before the brief Truss government is forgotten by opinion-formers and the media. A first draft of history? Maybe, but there is surely much more to be said about this episode as time passes and the dust settles.</p><p>It is worth emphasising that Liz Truss was better-prepared to be a prime minister than many people think; better-prepared indeed than several of her predecessors and the majority of her rivals for the Conservative leadership.</p><p>After university (where she was a Liberal Democrat rather than a Conservative), she worked in the private sector and qualified as a chartered management accountant, later becoming economic director at Cable &amp; Wireless, a telecoms company. After unsuccessful attempts at standing for Parliament, she became deputy director of Reform – a centre-right think tank, not the political party currently headed by Nigel Farage. There she wrote several pamphlets, developing her ideas about educational reform.</p><p>I should say here that it was at Reform that I first met Liz Truss, when we discussed a report she had written on mathematical education. I am certainly not a personal friend, but we have met a few times over the years, sufficient perhaps to form a view of her abilities which predates her dramatic rise and fall. I find it difficult to square my impressions of her, as a clever and funny – albeit sometimes rather socially awkward – hard-working political animal, with the deranged Cruella de Vil portrayed in Seldon's volume.</p><p>Following her stint at Reform, and a spell as a local councillor, Truss entered Parliament in 2010. She was an active backbench MP, organising several local initiatives, and became a co-founder of the Free Enterprise Group, a Thatcherite tribute act which included several MPs who would later become prominent, including Kwasi Kwarteng, Priti Patel and Dominic Raab. The Group published <i>After the Coalition</i> and <i>Britannia Unchained</i>, lively books that advocated tax cuts and reducing the power of the state, themes which underlay her time in Downing Street.</p><p>David Cameron appointed her to be education under-secretary in 2012 and from then on she had an unbroken record of ten years' service in government under three prime ministers, including appointments as environment secretary, justice secretary, chief secretary to the treasury, international trade secretary and foreign secretary.</p><p><i>Ten Years to Save the West</i> is a dramatic title. However, much of Liz Truss's book is a relatively low-key account of her experiences as a politician. Of the 14 chapters, only three cover her time as prime minister. The book is straightforwardly written, without the huge apparatus of dates, quotations and footnotes which make many politicians' memoirs unreadable. As far as I can tell, it is all her own work.</p><p>The chapters about her earlier ministerial roles are revealing, for her frustrations tell us a good deal about the confrontational way she would later approach her prime ministership. Her earliest role in government was as a junior education minister – to which role she was in principle well suited, having devoted a good deal of time and thought to education and childcare while at Reform. However she found that it was difficult to get civil servants to rethink entrenched positions or do anything in a timely manner. She writes:</p><p>She soon ran into vested interests such as commercial nurseries and the influential Mumsnet website, when she tried to push a modest dose of childcare deregulation. She also found political difficulties with the Liberal Democrats (then in coalition with the Conservatives), who eventually blocked her proposals. There were also considerable difficulties with the drive – led by Secretary of State for Education Michael Gove, with whom she was later to fall out – to raise educational standards, with teachers' unions and professional bodies resisting moves to reverse the ‘progressive’ orthodoxy.</p><p>Her next job was with the Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs. In writing about her experience there, Truss develops a favourite theme – the hijacking of the agenda of departments by non-governmental organisations (NGOs), often ‘charities’ with symbiotic relationships with the government which largely funds them:</p><p>In the chapter covering her short (just 11 months) stint as justice secretary, she found it difficult to make progress, and was dragged into an argument about the independence of the judiciary. Again she finds that non-governmental bodies and civil servants control too much of the agenda while here-today-gone-tomorrow politicians struggle to master their brief and determine policy before they are moved on in the next reshuffle.</p><p>She continues in a similar vein when discussing her time as international trade secretary and foreign secretary. Reflecting on the latter role, she widens her criticism of the UK's failings to international institutions such as the World Health Organization and the United Nations, and to the COP26 jamboree and foreign-aid disbursement. But her chief criticism is focused on the way in which the UK economy has been held back by the Treasury's grip on macroeconomic policy and its ‘abacus accounting’ (her term) which she believed was preventing the radical tax-cutting measures and deregulation which she favoured.</p><p>Opposition to the Treasury's influence is of long standing. Back in the 1920s and 1930s Keynes was a critic of the ‘Treasury View’ (Clarke, <span>2005</span>) which rejected the expansionary fiscal policy he advocated. Then in the 1960s Labour's Prime Minister Harold Wilson was so determined to weaken the Treasury's power that he set up a short-lived rival Department of Economic Affairs.</p><p>Part of Truss's criticism of the modern Treasury is that it combines both the economic and the accounting functions of the government, something which is unusual internationally. Under Labour Party former Prime Ministers Tony Blair and Gordon Brown, she asserts, “the Treasury orthodoxy had shifted to the left and away from the free-market economics we wished to pursue” (p. 233). Moreover, the Treasury had “spread its tentacles over domestic policy”. Rather than simply imposing spending caps on departments, it increasingly controls what money is spent on.</p><p>Furthermore, the Bank of England's independence, granted under Gordon Brown in 1997, took monetary policy out of the politicians' hands. And Chancellor of the Exchequer George Osborne, under the 2010–15 coalition government, set up the Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR): this is a body providing independent forecasts of the effects of changes in government policy. Despite an underwhelming performance as a forecaster, the OBR “gradually developed a life of its own and now essentially sets fiscal policy” (p. 234).</p><p>In Truss's view the Treasury, the Bank of England and the OBR are all adherents to a high-tax, big government, high-regulation consensus which has held back the economy. She and Kwarteng were determined to break with this consensus as they pursued their project to boost growth through economic liberalisation. Ideally Truss would have liked to “go in very hard, abolish the OBR and appoint senior leaders in the Bank of England and Treasury who were prepared to challenge the orthodoxy” (p. 241). But abolishing the OBR would have required legislation, and the governor of the Bank of England could not be sacked, so the only immediate change of substance was the replacement of Permanent Secretary to the Treasury Sir Tom Scholar. However, Truss and Kwarteng initially kept the governor of the Bank of England at arms' length and did not involve the OBR in assessing the likely impact of the mini-budget.</p><p>There are no great revelations in the chapters on Truss's weeks as prime minister, though she argues (p. 242) that the costs associated with the mini-budget were exaggerated and that nobody in the Treasury had told her team about the notorious liability-driven investments (pp. 252–3). She admits that she could have handled some things better, but there is little suggestion of repentance. On the contrary, she sees the apparent reactions of ‘the market’ to her government as being the result of the lack of support she received from the Bank, the Treasury and other elements of the establishment, including those sections of the Conservative Party who had not accepted the legitimacy of her leadership. She writes:</p><p>We probably shouldn't quibble too much about terminology, but is conservatism really what we are talking about here? Conservatives, almost by definition, are averse to change. Indeed Truss's criticisms of her own Conservative Party make the point that too many of her colleagues – the twenty-first century equivalent of Mrs Thatcher's ‘wets’ – were content with the status quo, not prepared to challenge the orthodoxies which had grown up since the time of Tony Blair and Gordon Brown and paying only lip service to belief in free markets, controls on immigration, and free speech. What Truss really wants is an approach much closer to classical liberalism. In our time this means a radical break with the big state, high taxes and government regulation and control of every area of economic life.</p><p>Be that as it may, what are the lessons she wishes to impart?</p><p><i>Lesson 1: We must be conservatives</i>. This means starting from conservative principles about individuals and families controlling their own lives. “It means defending property rights, free speech and the rule of law. It means standing up for sovereignty, the nation state and British exceptionalism” (p. 290). It also means rejecting “net zero zealotry” and “wokeism”, and avoiding “compromise and triangulation”.</p><p><i>Lesson 2: We must dismantle the leftist state</i>. Truss asserts that “we are not going to succeed in implementing conservative policies while the leftist state apparatus remains intact” (p. 292). The Human Rights Act, the Equality Act and the Climate Change Act are “totems of left-wing belief, which have too readily been accepted by conservatives as immoveable. We should be prepared to abolish them” (p. 293).</p><p><i>Lesson 3: We must restore democratic accountability</i>. “As trust in the political system has been eroded, politicians have ceded yet more authority to unelected officials” (p. 293). The Bank of England must be more accountable to elected politicians while quangos such as the OBR must be abolished. As in the United States, the government should have the power to appoint senior civil servants (p. 294).</p><p><i>Lesson 4: Conservatives must win across the free world, particularly in the United States of America</i>. Truss believes that “The left is much more adept at organising across the globe and has done so all too effectively to roll back the achievements of conservatives … Those of us on the right need allies if we are to change attitudes and win the battle of ideas once again” (p. 298). This seems to involve creating alliances between political groupings in different countries.</p><p><i>Lesson 5: We must reassert the nation state</i>. If informal political links across borders between like-minded politicians are to be encouraged, international economic institutions such as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (the latter criticised the mini-budget) should definitely not be. Nor should the World Trade Organization, the World Health Organization, and the UN, on which UK taxpayers spend too much money. And the UN Refugee Convention and the European Court of Human Rights are “no longer fit for purpose as they stand” (p. 299): they are “increasingly being used and abused by activist lawyers” to subvert policies to limit immigration or to deport criminals.</p><p><i>Lesson 6: We must end appeasement</i>. “Appeasing our enemies does not work … we seem still to be at risk of repeating the mistakes of the 1930s, this time with China, Russia and Iran” (p. 300). In particular, we should deny China access to our markets and treat as a pariah anybody doing business with China. “We also need to be much tougher on those in our own countries who are supporters of hostile regimes” (p. 301). Britain should designate Iran's Revolutionary Guard Corps as a terrorist organisation, and “closing down the Confucius Institutes<sup>6</sup> is long overdue”.</p><p>It's all strong stuff, but a long way from deciding whether to reduce corporation tax or set an energy price gap, which were Liz Truss's immediate concerns when she came to power. Is it overblown? Will it age well?</p><p>If, as Harold Wilson may or may not have said, a week is a long time in politics, the time since Liz Truss's government expired seems an eternity. The political scene has changed considerably.</p><p>Her view of the international ‘turn to the left’ turns out to require considerable qualification. Two days before Truss resigned, Giorgia Meloni led the right-wing Brothers of Italy into government. In December 2023 the chainsaw-wielding free-market economist Javier Milei became president of Argentina. In November 2024 Donald Trump won a second term as US president and, with the energetic assistance of billionaire Elon Musk, plans an assault on big government. Meanwhile, there have been electoral gains for the right in countries such as France, Germany, the Netherlands and New Zealand.</p><p>Britain, perhaps temporarily, bucked the trend by electing a Labour government in July 2024. This was unsurprising: the fratricidal Conservative Party, having burned through four leaders in six years, ended up appointing Rishi Sunak, who had lost to Truss in the Conservative contest only two months previously, without any further mandate from the membership. Although Sunak's leadership calmed markets and was associated with a slight upturn in growth, the inability of his government to control immigration – especially the highly visible channel-crossings in small boats – fuelled continual unrest, and in a surprise move he called a general election six months earlier than he needed to. The result was a massive victory for the Labour Party, with the Conservative Party winning its smallest number of parliamentary seats since its emergence in the early nineteenth century.</p><p>Yet the new government achieved its parliamentary majority with less than a third of the total votes cast and it has rapidly run into problems of its own. Rachel Reeves, the Labour chancellor of the exchequer, produced a budget in October 2024 which was almost a mirror image of the Kwasi Kwarteng proposals. Despite agreeing with the Truss government that the prime aim must be to increase growth, Labour raised taxes and government spending rather than reducing them. Like the Truss–Kwarteng mini-budget, however, it proposed a big increase in government borrowing. This has led to the financial markets turning against it, with gilt (government bond) yields now at their highest level since the 2007–08 global financial crisis, exceeding the levels reached immediately after the mini-budget. This has led Truss to claim that this vindicates her position in 2022. Indeed, she has even had the chutzpah to get her lawyers to send a ‘cease and desist’ letter to Prime Minster Keir Starmer, requiring him to stop the “false and defamatory” claim that she “crashed the economy” (Riley-Smith &amp; Wallace, <span>2025</span>).</p><p>It is doubtful whether legal threats will stop the general public from making up their own minds. But it is probably worth making the point that the charge of having crashed the economy is greatly overblown (<i>Europe Economics</i>, <span>2024</span>). There was never really any significant negative impact outside the financial markets. Output and employment remained stable. As Professor Stephen Millward, of the usually politically neutral National Institute of Economic and Social Research, put it a year after the event, the only group that permanently lost out was those remortgaging in the month after the mini-budget, when mortgage rates shot up (Millward, <span>2023</span>).</p><p>While the problems facing Rachel Reeves may suggest that the Truss–Kwarteng proposals were not uniquely destabilising, they do perhaps rather undermine Truss's belief that the reaction against the mini-budget was orchestrated by the Blob's antipathy towards free market policies. If a package of big state–big tax measures met a similar reaction, it does rather undermine a simple conspiracist story.</p><p>But leaving aside the political point-scoring, there have been developments in our understanding of the mechanics of the autumn 2022 financial crisis now that the number-crunchers have got to work.</p><p>In the immediate aftermath of the collapse of the Truss government, a number of commentators claimed that, as most of the mini-budget proposals had been pre-announced during Truss's campaign for the Conservative leadership, they would have been ‘priced in’ to market expectations. While there would have been some effect as a result of the energy price cap announcement and the unheralded proposal to scrap the top rate of income tax, the market volatility went beyond what would reasonably be expected (Moynihan, <span>2023</span>). On this view, implicating the amplifying effect of liability-driven investments, the Bank of England was at least partly responsible for the crisis through poor financial regulation and its own policy actions.</p><p>Pension funds need to match predictable liabilities with assets. The financial authorities had encouraged them to invest in gilts, which are needed to finance government borrowing. Gilts have a relatively low return, as they are extremely safe assets. The authorities turned a blind, or at least benevolent, eye to investing in LDI funds which used holdings of gilts as collateral for borrowing to buy more government bonds and derivatives on credit. This enabled them to make higher profits. However, this is a source of potential instability, as if interest rates rise lenders will demand more collateral. As rising interest rates imply falling bond prices, holders will attempt to sell the gilts to minimise capital losses. Thus the potential for a ‘doom loop’ – which led the Bank of England to step into the market to buy bonds and shore up the price.</p><p>Critics argued that rising US interest rates and the expectation that the Bank of England was about to embark on ‘quantitative tightening’<sup>7</sup> meant that we had a situation where a crisis was just waiting to happen. In this view, the mini-budget was the spark that lit a larger crisis than was justified by its actual content. And some blame attaches to the Bank and financial regulators for not realising this until it was too late.</p><p>This was the theory. Research published by the Bank of England has now put some empirical flesh on these theoretical bones. A paper by Pinter et al. (<span>2024</span>) has suggested that at least half the fall in gilt prices during the mini-budget crisis was the result of LDI selling, while a study using a different approach by Alfaro et al. (<span>2024</span>) attributed two-thirds of the rise in 30-year borrowing costs to the fallout from LDIs.</p><p>While this research may mitigate the opprobrium attached to Liz Truss and Kwasi Kwarteng by suggesting that the market reaction to the mini-budget was exaggerated and perhaps, as Seldon suggested, to some degree a matter of unfortunate timing, there still remain serious questions about the speed with which it was rushed out, and the wisdom of announcing tax cuts without at least some indication of eventually matched expenditure cuts. Truss and Kwarteng seem to have believed that, because the markets had been willing to countenance vast increases in public debt during the Covid lockdown, they'd be as accepting of fiscal incontinence under more normal conditions. Making big tax cuts would produce ‘shock and awe’, a sign that they really meant business. They were overly optimistic – as, for that matter, Rachel Reeves has been. As a result, a real opportunity to make some progress in boosting growth in the moribund British economy by cutting back the size of the state and hacking away the knotweed of regulation was lost in pursuit of the sugar rush of tax cuts.</p><p>These issues will be mulled over for some time. Meanwhile, bloodied but unbowed, Liz Truss remains up for the fight and is rarely out of the news both in Britain and the USA. Despite losing her parliamentary seat, and still facing widespread vilification, ridicule and humiliation, she remains, as she told the House of Commons as her government collapsed, “a fighter, not a quitter”.</p><p>A wilting lettuce she is not.</p>","PeriodicalId":44825,"journal":{"name":"ECONOMIC AFFAIRS","volume":"45 1","pages":"147-159"},"PeriodicalIF":1.8000,"publicationDate":"2025-02-03","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/epdf/10.1111/ecaf.12695","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"ECONOMIC AFFAIRS","FirstCategoryId":"91","ListUrlMain":"https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/ecaf.12695","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q3","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

Anthony Seldon (with Jonathan Meakin), Truss at 10: How Not to Be Prime Minister. Atlantic Books. 2024. 366 + xvi pp. £22.00 (hbk). ISBN: 978-1805462132. £12.99 (pbk). ISBN: 978-1805462163. £11.99 (ebk). ISBN: 978-1805462156

Liz Truss, Ten Years to Save the West: Lessons from the Only Conservative in the Room. Biteback Publishing. 320 pp. £20.00 (hbk). ISBN: 978-1785908576. £10.99 (pbk). ISBN: 978-1785909238. £14.99 (ebk). ISBN: 978-1785908637

On 6 September 2022, Liz Truss replaced Boris Johnson to become Queen Elizabeth II's 15th and last prime minister of the United Kingdom. Two days later, the queen was dead. Following a short period of official mourning, Truss and her Chancellor of the Exchequer1 Kwasi Kwarteng launched a ‘mini-budget’ which was intended to cut taxes dramatically without any immediate matching spending cuts. Coming on top of an earlier (and potentially extremely expensive) commitment to subsidising energy prices, this sparked a serious financial crisis. This led to Truss dismissing Kwarteng and installing a new chancellor, who then scrapped almost the entire proposed fiscal package. This U-turn, together with bond-buying by the Bank of England to stave off a potential collapse of pension funds, stabilised the markets. However, she had been compromised by this reversal of her signature policy, became subject to public ridicule, and quickly lost the support of the parliamentary Conservative Party. She had little option but to resign as Conservative leader and prime minister on 20 October after just 44 days in 10 Downing Street. Five days later she was replaced as prime minister by Rishi Sunak. This was the shortest period of office of any British prime minister.

On 11 October, The Economist (2024) had published a leader column which compared Truss's expected shelf-life to that of an iceberg lettuce. This image was seized upon by the tabloid Daily Star, which began to livestream a wilting supermarket lettuce, soon attracting a huge number of viewers and becoming a meme which persisted well after her resignation. In August 2024, for example, Truss walked out of a stage appearance to promote Ten Years to Save the West after some jokers unfurled a remote control banner with a picture of a lettuce and the legend ‘I crashed the economy’ (BBC News2024). She was reportedly unamused.

The Truss government was certainly something of a fiasco. But why? These two books offer contrasting reasons. While Sir Anthony Seldon largely blames the personal inadequacies of Britain's 56th prime minister, Truss herself sees her administration as fatally undermined by ‘the Blob’, an amorphous grouping including “the quangocracy, an unaccountable judiciary and undemocratic international institutions” (p. 286). She argues that her experience suggests that bringing about radical change to a political consensus that is stifling economic growth in Britain and elsewhere in the West faces formidable obstacles.

So was the Truss episode no more significant than a tired lettuce? Or was her failure symptomatic of a deeper malaise?

Both Seldon and Truss were fairly prominent public figures well before her brief premiership, but they had never spoken until a summer party in July 2023. Seldon recounts the occasion:

Seldon's book, and his method of approach, need contextualising. He is a prolific author, having written or edited 50 books (conveniently listed at the back of his Truss volume). He has written on a variety of subjects, but many of his books concern the role of prime minister, a job which he calls ‘the Impossible Office’ (Seldon et al., 2021). He has covered most post-war British PMs: volumes have appeared on Winston Churchill, Edward Heath, Margaret Thatcher, John Major, Tony Blair, Gordon Brown, David Cameron, Theresa May, Boris Johnson and now Truss. I imagine he is already working on Truss's successor, Rishi Sunak. Each of the volumes from Gordon Brown onwards have been titled ‘So-and-so at 10’.

Seldon is not the typical twenty-first-century senior academic, with time and a large research grant on his hands. He has been, for much of his adult life, a part-time historian. His day job was for many years as the Master of Wellington College, a leading independent school. Subsequently he headed the University of Buckingham (where I work and made his acquaintance) for a five-year stint, and then went back to secondary education, taking over a school whose head had been murdered in tragic circumstances. Apart from these commitments, Seldon has for years been a busy media commentator on the political scene. So the production of this substantial book, only 18 months after the activities it chronicles, is an impressive achievement – as were his previous volumes of instant history.

So how does he do it? Well, he's not quite the lone author and in Truss at 10 he explains (pp. 15–16, 331–2) how his publications are a team effort. In this case his team was fronted by Jonathan Meakin, with whom Seldon has collaborated on previous occasions. With the team, he sets out the structure – chapter heads – for the book. He then carries out the interviews, 120 in this case, with participants in the events covered. These constitute, he says, about 80 per cent of the content of the book. The team “produces briefings for each chapter, integrating these with other published and documented material”. He then has “the easy and fun part, writing the book” (p. 331).

The structure chosen for this volume is interesting. Seldon has previously – in his book The Impossible Office? (Seldon et al., 2021) and in a New Statesman article (Seldon, 2022) – set out conditions which he believes are necessary for a prime minister to be successful in office, and which most inevitably fail to achieve. In the Truss book he offers a variant of these approaches. Although there is a semi-chronological sequencing, it is the conditions for success, ten in all, which provide the chapter headings.

The first requirement is to ‘Secure the Power Base’, which in Truss's case was the Parliamentary Conservative Party. As Seldon points out, right from the start Truss's position was shaky. She had only a very limited following amongst MPs and was not the parliamentary party's choice for leader; in the first ballot she came third, and after a series of eliminations she was still well behind Rishi Sunak in the final vote. Her accession to the leadership depended on the votes of Conservative Party members in the country, and a substantial block of MPs never really supported her and indeed were hostile from the start.

Then, says Seldon, prime ministers need to have ‘A Clear and Realistic Plan for Government’. Unlike her three immediate predecessors (Johnson, May, Cameron), Truss had strong ideological priors, and her strategy was clear: it involved tax cuts, deregulation and shrinking the state. But she had not established a consensus amongst her MPs for rapid action. Seldon argues that her haste in producing the mini-budget, her insistence on bypassing or disregarding the establishment (the Bank of England, the Treasury and the Office for Budget Responsibility) and an ill-thought-out energy price guarantee were unrealistic.

A prime minister must ‘Appoint the Best Cabinet/Team’. Seldon is of the opinion that Liz Truss should have brought in the most talented and most representative members of the party, irrespective of their political stance, to give her a chance of maintaining a strong government. Instead of choosing a broad-based cabinet, she chose a mediocre team which largely consisted of friends and supporters and left out many experienced and substantial figures (p. 103).

Prime ministers must ‘Command the Big Events’. In her first weeks, Truss faced two such big events: the death of the queen, and the energy crisis – sharply rising gas prices consequent on the Ukraine war. While Seldon concedes that Truss conducted herself with dignity over the transition to the new monarch, she lacked a “sense of history and personal gravitas” (p. 143), which meant that she did not rise to the occasion with the flourish and unifying rhetoric of a Churchill but rather shrank into the background, worrying about tripping up during ceremonial duties. As for energy, having first ruled out any support package, Truss was “spooked” (p. 121) by briefings and went to the opposite extreme, announcing support which threatened at the time to cost up to £150 billion, though in the end it cost more like £40 billion.

Seldon also thinks a successful prime minister must ‘Be Credible and Highly Regarded Abroad’. Despite her experience as foreign secretary, Truss is seen as failing this test. She was solid on Ukraine, and a robust critic of China. But Seldon sees her as failing to get on with the Europeans and, particularly, the Americans. President Biden, he says (on no quoted evidence, incidentally) “viewed Truss sceptically as a know-nothing upstart” (p. 159).

You must ‘Learn How to be Prime Minister’ by being prepared to listen and take advice. Here Seldon sees Truss as constitutionally incapable of taking on board and really hearing views which conflict with her own. She is fundamentally lacking in judgment (p. 184).

It goes almost without saying that PMs should ‘Avoid Major Policy Failures’. Seldon can hardly avoid seeing the mini-budget as a massive policy error. He calls it the “greatest example of its kind in modern history” (p. 216). Part of this was its timing, for it “might have worked earlier in the year, but not with inflation running at 9.9 per cent and the expectation of it rising to between 11 and 12 per cent” (p. 216).

Of course, a PM must ‘Maintain a Reputation for Economic Competence’, and the fallout from the mini-budget appears to be Truss's most obvious failing. The expensive energy price cap commitment, followed by cutting taxes without accompanying spending cuts,2 led to a domestic financial crisis, with bond yields shooting up, and a run on sterling which left the pound at its lowest-ever value against the dollar.

Seldon's ninth rule of premiership is ‘Avoid U-turns’ on major policy issues. In light of the reaction to the mini-budget, Seldon believes Truss had no option but to scrap the proposals. But this is “beside the point. She implemented the biggest U-turn in modern prime ministerial history and it didn't work for her” (p. 284).

Finally, a PM must ‘Retain the Confidence of the Party’. As noted earlier, Truss never had a strong base in the parliamentary party, and did nothing to build one. With the mini-budget crisis, followed by resignations and a botched vote on fracking, the febrile mood of Conservative MPs made her continuation in office impossible.

While it is difficult to dispute some of this analysis, there is a rather predictable feel to it all. Seldon clearly doesn't think much of Liz Truss, or of her project of radical free-market economics. Sir Anthony is, as many readers will know, the son of Arthur Seldon. Arthur was, together with Ralph Harris, a key figure in the development of the IEA (and the founding editor of this journal). He was a leading influence in the revival of policy-directed classical economic thinking in the UK and the wider world from the 1950s to the 1980s. It is interesting to speculate whether he would have been more sympathetic to Truss than his son, who incidentally doesn't seem to think much of today's IEA.3 Sir Anthony's politics are rarely explicit but are broadly centrist. He was strongly against Brexit, and he has a very low opinion of Boris Johnson. He respects the expertise of the Treasury and the Bank of England. He's probably not a fan of Donald Trump.

To be fair, Seldon does occasionally try to balance his criticisms of Truss by mentioning some of her strengths. He thinks she was making a tolerable fist of her role as foreign secretary, and emphasises that she was good at appreciating intelligence and reading reports (p. 163). He credits her “irrepressible optimism” (p. 168), her energy (p. 170) and (in sharp contrast to Johnson) her hard work (p. 172).

Nevertheless, the overall impression is very strongly negative. It is fed on page after page by comments usually attributed to ‘an aide’ or ‘an official’, which are simply opinions or speculation with little factual basis. Thus Truss is “robotic, brain-dead” (p. 28) “stupid and capricious” (p. 38), she displays “verbal incontinence” and “preening” (p. 61), her grasp of market economics is “superficial” (p. 68). She is said to suffer from “a deep inner anxiety” (p. 78), she is “a figure of ridicule” (p. 104), is “plain bonkers” (p. 169), “irritable, paranoid and even unhinged” (p. 179) and possibly autistic (p. 181). She is “intolerant and suspicious” (p. 179). She seems “positively to rejoice in aggravating colleagues” (p. 60), and enjoys “humiliating her team in front of others” (p. 79). Referring to her support for the cut in international development spending under Johnson, Seldon himself says that “any human damage caused by these cuts was of no apparent concern to her” (p. 151). Elsewhere, rubbishing two birds with one stone, he writes that “her vanity, neediness and willingness to trample over others was of Johnsonian proportions” (p. 184). Remember that, although Seldon has evidently listened to a lot of people bad-mouthing these successive prime ministers, he has not spoken to either Truss or Johnson about their careers and experience.

Occasionally this sort of stuff takes us into dangerous territory. For example, there is speculation about a dossier said to contain details of “her indiscretions, her drinking and even cocaine use by others among her team” (p. 43). This is just a possibility mentioned in passing as a fear expressed by “one of her team”, and there is no evidence that such a dossier ever existed or that its alleged contents have any substance. But there is a smear there which cannot avoid leaving an impression on the reader.

An even more egregious example refers to the hectic hours when Truss and Kwasi Kwarteng were considering spending cuts to offset their planned tax reductions. Alex Boyd, a civil servant, is met by colleagues who tell him that “We've been told that they're looking at stopping cancer treatment on the [National Health Service]” (p. 245). It's not easy to make out who is saying what, but this appears to be Boyd telling Seldon that he was told by colleagues that they had been told that Truss and Kwarteng4 were considering this. Needless to say, this several-degrees-of-separation hearsay found its way into the media on the book's publication (e.g. Stacey, 2024), forcing Truss to deny that such an implausible policy was ever considered. Possibly some advisor or even one of the principals themselves made a joke in poor taste, but the idea that Truss was seriously prepared to put lives at risk in such a manner is just another example of the way in which she is repeatedly painted in the worst possible light.

As I have said, Seldon's method involves a heavy reliance on interviews with nameless individuals. We have no way of knowing who these witnesses were, or how much credence should be given to them. Many will have been relatively junior (and probably now rather disillusioned) members of Truss's entourage; many will have been political opponents or otherwise have an axe to grind. While obviously needing to protect his sources, it is a pity Seldon could not have given us some indication of the proportions who were MPs, officials or advisors, and how exactly they were recruited. Did they volunteer, or were they approached by Seldon's team? If the latter, how many of those approached refused? And it would be useful to know how the interviews were structured: was there a set of standard questions, or were they more free-flowing?

It would also be interesting to know the extent to which the drafts produced by his researchers shaped Seldon's conclusions. Were the extensive negative remarks I have noted chosen to support a prior view, or were they forced to his attention because so many interviewees were critical of Truss?

This is not, therefore, a study of the kind which leads to refereed articles in academic journals. It's not necessarily the worse for that, as the general reader will find it flows along nicely, but Seldon is not a trained political scientist. Nor, of course, is he an economist: one of the weaknesses of this book is its neglect of economics. There is no analysis of the UK's poor economic performance to which Truss and Kwarteng were reacting, and no serious examination – which could already have drawn on extensive official and academic sources – of what they were proposing. The financial market reaction to the mini-budget is barely covered, and in particular the issue of the liability-driven investments (LDIs)5 is only sketched very briefly.

I admire Sir Anthony, and this rapidly-produced book is a considerable achievement. But it is essentially long-form journalism, rushed out to meet a demand for in-depth storytelling and comment before the brief Truss government is forgotten by opinion-formers and the media. A first draft of history? Maybe, but there is surely much more to be said about this episode as time passes and the dust settles.

It is worth emphasising that Liz Truss was better-prepared to be a prime minister than many people think; better-prepared indeed than several of her predecessors and the majority of her rivals for the Conservative leadership.

After university (where she was a Liberal Democrat rather than a Conservative), she worked in the private sector and qualified as a chartered management accountant, later becoming economic director at Cable & Wireless, a telecoms company. After unsuccessful attempts at standing for Parliament, she became deputy director of Reform – a centre-right think tank, not the political party currently headed by Nigel Farage. There she wrote several pamphlets, developing her ideas about educational reform.

I should say here that it was at Reform that I first met Liz Truss, when we discussed a report she had written on mathematical education. I am certainly not a personal friend, but we have met a few times over the years, sufficient perhaps to form a view of her abilities which predates her dramatic rise and fall. I find it difficult to square my impressions of her, as a clever and funny – albeit sometimes rather socially awkward – hard-working political animal, with the deranged Cruella de Vil portrayed in Seldon's volume.

Following her stint at Reform, and a spell as a local councillor, Truss entered Parliament in 2010. She was an active backbench MP, organising several local initiatives, and became a co-founder of the Free Enterprise Group, a Thatcherite tribute act which included several MPs who would later become prominent, including Kwasi Kwarteng, Priti Patel and Dominic Raab. The Group published After the Coalition and Britannia Unchained, lively books that advocated tax cuts and reducing the power of the state, themes which underlay her time in Downing Street.

David Cameron appointed her to be education under-secretary in 2012 and from then on she had an unbroken record of ten years' service in government under three prime ministers, including appointments as environment secretary, justice secretary, chief secretary to the treasury, international trade secretary and foreign secretary.

Ten Years to Save the West is a dramatic title. However, much of Liz Truss's book is a relatively low-key account of her experiences as a politician. Of the 14 chapters, only three cover her time as prime minister. The book is straightforwardly written, without the huge apparatus of dates, quotations and footnotes which make many politicians' memoirs unreadable. As far as I can tell, it is all her own work.

The chapters about her earlier ministerial roles are revealing, for her frustrations tell us a good deal about the confrontational way she would later approach her prime ministership. Her earliest role in government was as a junior education minister – to which role she was in principle well suited, having devoted a good deal of time and thought to education and childcare while at Reform. However she found that it was difficult to get civil servants to rethink entrenched positions or do anything in a timely manner. She writes:

She soon ran into vested interests such as commercial nurseries and the influential Mumsnet website, when she tried to push a modest dose of childcare deregulation. She also found political difficulties with the Liberal Democrats (then in coalition with the Conservatives), who eventually blocked her proposals. There were also considerable difficulties with the drive – led by Secretary of State for Education Michael Gove, with whom she was later to fall out – to raise educational standards, with teachers' unions and professional bodies resisting moves to reverse the ‘progressive’ orthodoxy.

Her next job was with the Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs. In writing about her experience there, Truss develops a favourite theme – the hijacking of the agenda of departments by non-governmental organisations (NGOs), often ‘charities’ with symbiotic relationships with the government which largely funds them:

In the chapter covering her short (just 11 months) stint as justice secretary, she found it difficult to make progress, and was dragged into an argument about the independence of the judiciary. Again she finds that non-governmental bodies and civil servants control too much of the agenda while here-today-gone-tomorrow politicians struggle to master their brief and determine policy before they are moved on in the next reshuffle.

She continues in a similar vein when discussing her time as international trade secretary and foreign secretary. Reflecting on the latter role, she widens her criticism of the UK's failings to international institutions such as the World Health Organization and the United Nations, and to the COP26 jamboree and foreign-aid disbursement. But her chief criticism is focused on the way in which the UK economy has been held back by the Treasury's grip on macroeconomic policy and its ‘abacus accounting’ (her term) which she believed was preventing the radical tax-cutting measures and deregulation which she favoured.

Opposition to the Treasury's influence is of long standing. Back in the 1920s and 1930s Keynes was a critic of the ‘Treasury View’ (Clarke, 2005) which rejected the expansionary fiscal policy he advocated. Then in the 1960s Labour's Prime Minister Harold Wilson was so determined to weaken the Treasury's power that he set up a short-lived rival Department of Economic Affairs.

Part of Truss's criticism of the modern Treasury is that it combines both the economic and the accounting functions of the government, something which is unusual internationally. Under Labour Party former Prime Ministers Tony Blair and Gordon Brown, she asserts, “the Treasury orthodoxy had shifted to the left and away from the free-market economics we wished to pursue” (p. 233). Moreover, the Treasury had “spread its tentacles over domestic policy”. Rather than simply imposing spending caps on departments, it increasingly controls what money is spent on.

Furthermore, the Bank of England's independence, granted under Gordon Brown in 1997, took monetary policy out of the politicians' hands. And Chancellor of the Exchequer George Osborne, under the 2010–15 coalition government, set up the Office for Budget Responsibility (OBR): this is a body providing independent forecasts of the effects of changes in government policy. Despite an underwhelming performance as a forecaster, the OBR “gradually developed a life of its own and now essentially sets fiscal policy” (p. 234).

In Truss's view the Treasury, the Bank of England and the OBR are all adherents to a high-tax, big government, high-regulation consensus which has held back the economy. She and Kwarteng were determined to break with this consensus as they pursued their project to boost growth through economic liberalisation. Ideally Truss would have liked to “go in very hard, abolish the OBR and appoint senior leaders in the Bank of England and Treasury who were prepared to challenge the orthodoxy” (p. 241). But abolishing the OBR would have required legislation, and the governor of the Bank of England could not be sacked, so the only immediate change of substance was the replacement of Permanent Secretary to the Treasury Sir Tom Scholar. However, Truss and Kwarteng initially kept the governor of the Bank of England at arms' length and did not involve the OBR in assessing the likely impact of the mini-budget.

There are no great revelations in the chapters on Truss's weeks as prime minister, though she argues (p. 242) that the costs associated with the mini-budget were exaggerated and that nobody in the Treasury had told her team about the notorious liability-driven investments (pp. 252–3). She admits that she could have handled some things better, but there is little suggestion of repentance. On the contrary, she sees the apparent reactions of ‘the market’ to her government as being the result of the lack of support she received from the Bank, the Treasury and other elements of the establishment, including those sections of the Conservative Party who had not accepted the legitimacy of her leadership. She writes:

We probably shouldn't quibble too much about terminology, but is conservatism really what we are talking about here? Conservatives, almost by definition, are averse to change. Indeed Truss's criticisms of her own Conservative Party make the point that too many of her colleagues – the twenty-first century equivalent of Mrs Thatcher's ‘wets’ – were content with the status quo, not prepared to challenge the orthodoxies which had grown up since the time of Tony Blair and Gordon Brown and paying only lip service to belief in free markets, controls on immigration, and free speech. What Truss really wants is an approach much closer to classical liberalism. In our time this means a radical break with the big state, high taxes and government regulation and control of every area of economic life.

Be that as it may, what are the lessons she wishes to impart?

Lesson 1: We must be conservatives. This means starting from conservative principles about individuals and families controlling their own lives. “It means defending property rights, free speech and the rule of law. It means standing up for sovereignty, the nation state and British exceptionalism” (p. 290). It also means rejecting “net zero zealotry” and “wokeism”, and avoiding “compromise and triangulation”.

Lesson 2: We must dismantle the leftist state. Truss asserts that “we are not going to succeed in implementing conservative policies while the leftist state apparatus remains intact” (p. 292). The Human Rights Act, the Equality Act and the Climate Change Act are “totems of left-wing belief, which have too readily been accepted by conservatives as immoveable. We should be prepared to abolish them” (p. 293).

Lesson 3: We must restore democratic accountability. “As trust in the political system has been eroded, politicians have ceded yet more authority to unelected officials” (p. 293). The Bank of England must be more accountable to elected politicians while quangos such as the OBR must be abolished. As in the United States, the government should have the power to appoint senior civil servants (p. 294).

Lesson 4: Conservatives must win across the free world, particularly in the United States of America. Truss believes that “The left is much more adept at organising across the globe and has done so all too effectively to roll back the achievements of conservatives … Those of us on the right need allies if we are to change attitudes and win the battle of ideas once again” (p. 298). This seems to involve creating alliances between political groupings in different countries.

Lesson 5: We must reassert the nation state. If informal political links across borders between like-minded politicians are to be encouraged, international economic institutions such as the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (the latter criticised the mini-budget) should definitely not be. Nor should the World Trade Organization, the World Health Organization, and the UN, on which UK taxpayers spend too much money. And the UN Refugee Convention and the European Court of Human Rights are “no longer fit for purpose as they stand” (p. 299): they are “increasingly being used and abused by activist lawyers” to subvert policies to limit immigration or to deport criminals.

Lesson 6: We must end appeasement. “Appeasing our enemies does not work … we seem still to be at risk of repeating the mistakes of the 1930s, this time with China, Russia and Iran” (p. 300). In particular, we should deny China access to our markets and treat as a pariah anybody doing business with China. “We also need to be much tougher on those in our own countries who are supporters of hostile regimes” (p. 301). Britain should designate Iran's Revolutionary Guard Corps as a terrorist organisation, and “closing down the Confucius Institutes6 is long overdue”.

It's all strong stuff, but a long way from deciding whether to reduce corporation tax or set an energy price gap, which were Liz Truss's immediate concerns when she came to power. Is it overblown? Will it age well?

If, as Harold Wilson may or may not have said, a week is a long time in politics, the time since Liz Truss's government expired seems an eternity. The political scene has changed considerably.

Her view of the international ‘turn to the left’ turns out to require considerable qualification. Two days before Truss resigned, Giorgia Meloni led the right-wing Brothers of Italy into government. In December 2023 the chainsaw-wielding free-market economist Javier Milei became president of Argentina. In November 2024 Donald Trump won a second term as US president and, with the energetic assistance of billionaire Elon Musk, plans an assault on big government. Meanwhile, there have been electoral gains for the right in countries such as France, Germany, the Netherlands and New Zealand.

Britain, perhaps temporarily, bucked the trend by electing a Labour government in July 2024. This was unsurprising: the fratricidal Conservative Party, having burned through four leaders in six years, ended up appointing Rishi Sunak, who had lost to Truss in the Conservative contest only two months previously, without any further mandate from the membership. Although Sunak's leadership calmed markets and was associated with a slight upturn in growth, the inability of his government to control immigration – especially the highly visible channel-crossings in small boats – fuelled continual unrest, and in a surprise move he called a general election six months earlier than he needed to. The result was a massive victory for the Labour Party, with the Conservative Party winning its smallest number of parliamentary seats since its emergence in the early nineteenth century.

Yet the new government achieved its parliamentary majority with less than a third of the total votes cast and it has rapidly run into problems of its own. Rachel Reeves, the Labour chancellor of the exchequer, produced a budget in October 2024 which was almost a mirror image of the Kwasi Kwarteng proposals. Despite agreeing with the Truss government that the prime aim must be to increase growth, Labour raised taxes and government spending rather than reducing them. Like the Truss–Kwarteng mini-budget, however, it proposed a big increase in government borrowing. This has led to the financial markets turning against it, with gilt (government bond) yields now at their highest level since the 2007–08 global financial crisis, exceeding the levels reached immediately after the mini-budget. This has led Truss to claim that this vindicates her position in 2022. Indeed, she has even had the chutzpah to get her lawyers to send a ‘cease and desist’ letter to Prime Minster Keir Starmer, requiring him to stop the “false and defamatory” claim that she “crashed the economy” (Riley-Smith & Wallace, 2025).

It is doubtful whether legal threats will stop the general public from making up their own minds. But it is probably worth making the point that the charge of having crashed the economy is greatly overblown (Europe Economics2024). There was never really any significant negative impact outside the financial markets. Output and employment remained stable. As Professor Stephen Millward, of the usually politically neutral National Institute of Economic and Social Research, put it a year after the event, the only group that permanently lost out was those remortgaging in the month after the mini-budget, when mortgage rates shot up (Millward, 2023).

While the problems facing Rachel Reeves may suggest that the Truss–Kwarteng proposals were not uniquely destabilising, they do perhaps rather undermine Truss's belief that the reaction against the mini-budget was orchestrated by the Blob's antipathy towards free market policies. If a package of big state–big tax measures met a similar reaction, it does rather undermine a simple conspiracist story.

But leaving aside the political point-scoring, there have been developments in our understanding of the mechanics of the autumn 2022 financial crisis now that the number-crunchers have got to work.

In the immediate aftermath of the collapse of the Truss government, a number of commentators claimed that, as most of the mini-budget proposals had been pre-announced during Truss's campaign for the Conservative leadership, they would have been ‘priced in’ to market expectations. While there would have been some effect as a result of the energy price cap announcement and the unheralded proposal to scrap the top rate of income tax, the market volatility went beyond what would reasonably be expected (Moynihan, 2023). On this view, implicating the amplifying effect of liability-driven investments, the Bank of England was at least partly responsible for the crisis through poor financial regulation and its own policy actions.

Pension funds need to match predictable liabilities with assets. The financial authorities had encouraged them to invest in gilts, which are needed to finance government borrowing. Gilts have a relatively low return, as they are extremely safe assets. The authorities turned a blind, or at least benevolent, eye to investing in LDI funds which used holdings of gilts as collateral for borrowing to buy more government bonds and derivatives on credit. This enabled them to make higher profits. However, this is a source of potential instability, as if interest rates rise lenders will demand more collateral. As rising interest rates imply falling bond prices, holders will attempt to sell the gilts to minimise capital losses. Thus the potential for a ‘doom loop’ – which led the Bank of England to step into the market to buy bonds and shore up the price.

Critics argued that rising US interest rates and the expectation that the Bank of England was about to embark on ‘quantitative tightening’7 meant that we had a situation where a crisis was just waiting to happen. In this view, the mini-budget was the spark that lit a larger crisis than was justified by its actual content. And some blame attaches to the Bank and financial regulators for not realising this until it was too late.

This was the theory. Research published by the Bank of England has now put some empirical flesh on these theoretical bones. A paper by Pinter et al. (2024) has suggested that at least half the fall in gilt prices during the mini-budget crisis was the result of LDI selling, while a study using a different approach by Alfaro et al. (2024) attributed two-thirds of the rise in 30-year borrowing costs to the fallout from LDIs.

While this research may mitigate the opprobrium attached to Liz Truss and Kwasi Kwarteng by suggesting that the market reaction to the mini-budget was exaggerated and perhaps, as Seldon suggested, to some degree a matter of unfortunate timing, there still remain serious questions about the speed with which it was rushed out, and the wisdom of announcing tax cuts without at least some indication of eventually matched expenditure cuts. Truss and Kwarteng seem to have believed that, because the markets had been willing to countenance vast increases in public debt during the Covid lockdown, they'd be as accepting of fiscal incontinence under more normal conditions. Making big tax cuts would produce ‘shock and awe’, a sign that they really meant business. They were overly optimistic – as, for that matter, Rachel Reeves has been. As a result, a real opportunity to make some progress in boosting growth in the moribund British economy by cutting back the size of the state and hacking away the knotweed of regulation was lost in pursuit of the sugar rush of tax cuts.

These issues will be mulled over for some time. Meanwhile, bloodied but unbowed, Liz Truss remains up for the fight and is rarely out of the news both in Britain and the USA. Despite losing her parliamentary seat, and still facing widespread vilification, ridicule and humiliation, she remains, as she told the House of Commons as her government collapsed, “a fighter, not a quitter”.

A wilting lettuce she is not.

莉斯·特拉斯:不仅仅是莴苣?
安东尼·塞尔登(与乔纳森·米金),《10岁的特拉斯:如何不成为首相》。大西洋出版社,2024。366 + xvi页,22.00英镑(英镑)。ISBN: 978 - 1805462132。£12.99 (pbk)。ISBN: 978 - 1805462163。£11.99(订购)。利兹·特拉斯,《拯救西方的十年:来自房间里唯一保守派的教训》。Biteback出版社,320页,20.00英镑。ISBN: 978 - 1785908576。£10.99 (pbk)。ISBN: 978 - 1785909238。£14.99(订购)。2022年9月6日,利兹·特拉斯取代鲍里斯·约翰逊,成为英国女王伊丽莎白二世的第15任、也是最后一任首相。两天后,王后死了。在短暂的官方哀悼之后,特拉斯和她的财政大臣夸西·夸滕(Kwasi Kwarteng)推出了一项“迷你预算”,旨在大幅减税,但不会立即削减相应的支出。在早先(可能极其昂贵)补贴能源价格的承诺之上,这引发了一场严重的金融危机。这导致特拉斯解雇了Kwarteng,并任命了一位新总理,这位新总理随后几乎取消了整个拟议的财政方案。这一180度大转弯,加上英国央行为避免养老基金可能崩溃而购买债券,稳定了市场。然而,她因这一标志性政策的逆转而受到损害,成为公众嘲笑的对象,并很快失去了议会保守党的支持。她别无选择,只能在10月20日辞去保守党领袖和首相的职务,此前她在唐宁街10号只待了44天。五天后,她的总理职位被理希·苏纳克(Rishi Sunak)取代。这是英国首相任期最短的一次。10月11日,《经济学人》(2024)发表了一篇领导专栏文章,将特拉斯的预期保质期与冰山生菜的保质期进行了比较。小报《每日星报》(Daily Star)抓住了这张照片,开始直播一颗枯萎的超市生菜,很快吸引了大量观众,并成为一个在她辞职后一直持续的梗。例如,在2024年8月,特拉斯在宣传“拯救西部十年”的舞台上露面,因为一些开玩笑的人展开了一个遥控器横幅,上面有一棵生菜的图片和“我摧毁了经济”的字样。据报道,她很不高兴。特拉斯政府无疑是一场惨败。但是为什么呢?这两本书提供了截然相反的理由。虽然安东尼·塞尔登爵士主要指责英国第56任首相的个人不足,但特拉斯本人认为,她的政府受到了“Blob”的致命破坏,这是一个无定形的团体,包括“泛政府、不负责任的司法机构和不民主的国际机构”(第286页)。她认为,她的经验表明,要彻底改变正在扼杀英国和西方其他国家经济增长的政治共识,面临着巨大的障碍。那么,特拉斯那一集不比一棵累了的莴苣更重要吗?还是她的失败预示着更深层次的疾病?早在她短暂的首相任期之前,塞尔登和特拉斯都是相当著名的公众人物,但直到2023年7月的一个夏季聚会,他们才发表过讲话。塞尔顿讲述了当时的情景:塞尔顿的书和他的方法需要背景化。他是一位多产的作家,撰写或编辑了50本书(方便地列在他的Truss卷的后面)。他写过各种各样的主题,但他的许多书都涉及首相的角色,他称之为“不可能的办公室”(Seldon et al., 2021)。他报道过战后大多数英国首相:温斯顿·丘吉尔、爱德华·希思、玛格丽特·撒切尔、约翰·梅杰、托尼·布莱尔、戈登·布朗、大卫·卡梅伦、特蕾莎·梅、鲍里斯·约翰逊,现在是特拉斯。我想他已经在开发Truss的继任者Rishi Sunak了。从戈登·布朗开始的每一卷都被命名为“某某十岁”。塞尔顿并不是典型的21世纪资深学者,拥有充裕的时间和大笔的研究经费。他成年后的大部分时间都是兼职历史学家。多年来,他的日常工作是惠灵顿学院的院长,这是一所领先的私立学校。随后,他在白金汉大学(University of Buckingham,我在那里工作,他是在那里认识的)当了五年的校长,然后又回到中学,接管了一所校长在悲惨的情况下被谋杀的学校。除了这些承诺,塞尔顿多年来一直是政治舞台上忙碌的媒体评论员。因此,这本内容丰富的书,在它记录这些活动的18个月之后出版,是一项令人印象深刻的成就——就像他之前的几卷即时历史一样。那么他是怎么做到的呢?好吧,他并不是唯一的作者,在《Truss at 10》一书中,他解释了(第15-16页,第331-2页)他的出版是一个团队的努力。 这一次,他的团队由乔纳森·米金(Jonathan Meakin)领衔,塞尔登之前曾与他合作过。与团队一起,他为这本书设定了结构——章节标题。然后,他对所报道事件的参与者进行了120次采访。他表示,这些内容约占全书内容的80%。该小组“为每章编写简报,并将其与其他已出版和记录的材料结合起来”。然后他开始了“轻松有趣的部分,写书”(第331页)。这个体量选择的结构很有趣。塞尔顿之前在他的书《不可能的办公室?》(Seldon et al., 2021)和《新政治家》(New Statesman)的一篇文章(Seldon, 2022)——列出了他认为总理成功执政所必需的条件,这些条件最不可避免地无法实现。在Truss的书中,他提供了这些方法的一种变体。虽然有半时间顺序,但成功的条件,总共十个,提供了章节标题。第一个要求是“确保权力基础”,在特拉斯的情况下,权力基础是议会保守党。正如Seldon所指出的,从一开始,Truss的位置就不稳定。她在国会议员中只有非常有限的追随者,也不是议会党的领袖人选;在第一轮投票中,她获得第三名,在经过一系列的淘汰之后,她在最后一轮投票中仍然远远落后于Rishi Sunak。她能否成为首相取决于国内保守党成员的投票,而相当一部分议员从未真正支持她,甚至从一开始就对她怀有敌意。然后,塞尔顿说,首相们需要有一个“清晰而现实的政府计划”。与她的三位前任(约翰逊、梅和卡梅伦)不同,特拉斯有着强烈的意识形态倾向,她的策略也很明确:包括减税、放松管制和缩减政府规模。但她未能在国会议员中就迅速采取行动达成共识。塞尔顿认为,她匆忙制定小型预算,坚持绕过或无视现有机构(英格兰银行、财政部和预算责任办公室),以及考虑不周的能源价格保证,这些都是不现实的。首相必须“任命最好的内阁/团队”。塞尔顿认为,利兹•特拉斯应该把党内最有才华、最具代表性的成员带进来,不管他们的政治立场如何,这样她才有机会维持一个强大的政府。她没有选择一个基础广泛的内阁,而是选择了一个主要由朋友和支持者组成的平庸团队,遗漏了许多经验丰富的重要人物(第103页)。总理必须“指挥重大事件”。在上任的头几周,特拉斯面临着两件大事:女王去世,以及能源危机——乌克兰战争导致的天然气价格急剧上涨。虽然塞尔登承认,特拉斯在向新君主过渡的过程中表现得很有尊严,但她缺乏“历史感和个人的庄重感”(第143页),这意味着她没有像丘吉尔那样华丽而团结的言辞,而是退缩在后台,担心在仪式上绊倒。在能源方面,特拉斯起初排除了任何支持方案,但他被简报“吓坏了”(第121页),走向了相反的极端,宣布支持,当时威胁要花费高达1500亿英镑,尽管最终花费了大约400亿英镑。塞尔顿还认为,一个成功的首相必须“在国外具有可信度和高度声誉”。尽管特拉斯有担任外交大臣的经历,但她被认为没有通过这项考验。她在乌克兰问题上立场坚定,对中国持强烈批评态度。但塞尔顿认为,她未能与欧洲人,尤其是美国人相处融洽。他说,拜登总统(顺便说一句,没有引用任何证据)“怀疑地将特拉斯视为一个一无所知的暴发户”(第159页)。你必须通过准备好倾听和接受建议来“学习如何成为首相”。在这里,塞尔顿认为特拉斯天生就不能接受和真正倾听与她自己冲突的观点。她根本缺乏判断力(第184页)。不用说,总理应该“避免重大政策失败”。塞尔顿很难不把这个小预算视为一个巨大的政策错误。他称之为“现代历史上同类作品中最伟大的典范”(第216页)。部分原因在于它的时机,因为它“在今年早些时候可能奏效,但在通胀率达到9.9%、预期将升至11%至12%的情况下就行不通了”(第216页)。当然,首相必须“保持经济能力的声誉”,而小预算的影响似乎是特拉斯最明显的失败。 高昂的能源价格上限承诺,以及随后在不削减开支的情况下减税,导致了国内金融危机,债券收益率飙升,英镑兑美元跌至历史最低水平。塞尔顿担任首相的第九个原则是在重大政策问题上“避免180度大转弯”。鉴于人们对小预算的反应,塞尔登认为特拉斯别无选择,只能放弃这些提议。但这是“无关紧要的”。她实施了现代首相历史上最大的180度大转弯,但这对她来说并不奏效。”最后,总理必须“保持党的信任”。如前所述,特拉斯在议会党内从来没有一个强大的基础,也没有采取任何行动来建立一个。由于小型预算危机,随之而来的是辞职和对水力压裂法的拙劣投票,保守党议员的狂热情绪使她无法继续执政。虽然很难对这些分析提出异议,但这一切都有一种相当可预测的感觉。显然,塞尔顿对利兹•特拉斯或她的激进自由市场经济计划评价不高。很多读者都知道,安东尼爵士是亚瑟·塞尔登的儿子。亚瑟与拉尔夫·哈里斯(Ralph Harris)是国际能源署(IEA)发展的关键人物(也是本刊的创刊编辑)。20世纪50年代至80年代,他是英国乃至世界范围内政策导向古典经济思想复兴的主要影响人物。推测他是否会比他的儿子更同情特拉斯是一件有趣的事,顺便说一句,他的儿子似乎对今天的国际原子能机构不太感兴趣。他强烈反对英国脱欧,他对鲍里斯·约翰逊的评价很低。他尊重英国财政部和英国央行的专业知识。他可能不是唐纳德·特朗普的粉丝。公平地说,塞尔顿偶尔会提到特拉斯的一些优点,以此来平衡他对特拉斯的批评。他认为她作为外交大臣还算过得去,并强调她善于欣赏情报和阅读报告(第163页)。他称赞她“抑制不住的乐观”(第168页)、精力充沛(第170页)和(与约翰逊形成鲜明对比的)勤奋工作(第172页)。然而,总的印象是非常消极的。一页又一页的评论通常被认为是“助手”或“官员”的评论,这些评论只是一些观点或猜测,几乎没有事实依据。因此,特拉斯是“机械的、脑残的”(第28页)、“愚蠢的、反复无常的”(第38页)、她表现出“语言失禁”和“自我修饰”(第61页)、她对市场经济学的理解是“肤浅的”(第68页)。据说她患有“内心深处的焦虑”(第78页),她是“一个被嘲笑的人物”(第104页),是“纯粹的疯子”(第169页),“易怒,偏执,甚至精神错乱”(第179页),可能患有自闭症(第181页)。她“心胸狭窄,多疑”(第179页)。她似乎“积极地以激怒同事为乐”(第60页),并享受“在其他人面前羞辱她的团队”(第79页)。谈到她对约翰逊政府削减国际发展开支的支持时,塞尔登自己说,“她显然不关心这些削减造成的任何人身伤害”(第151页)。在其他地方,他一举两得,写道“她的虚荣、需要和践踏他人的意愿是约翰逊式的”(第184页)。请记住,尽管塞尔登显然听了很多人说这几任首相的坏话,但他没有和特拉斯或约翰逊谈论过他们的职业和经历。有时候,这类事情会把我们带入危险的境地。例如,有人猜测一份据称载有“她的轻率行为、她的饮酒甚至她的团队中其他人吸食可卡因”细节的档案(第43页)。这只是“她的一个团队”出于担心而顺便提到的一种可能性,没有证据表明这样的档案曾经存在过,也没有证据表明其所谓的内容有任何实质内容。但这里有一种污蔑,不免给读者留下印象。一个更令人震惊的例子是,当特拉斯和夸西·夸滕考虑削减开支以抵消他们计划的减税时,他们忙得不可开交。亚历克斯·博伊德是一名公务员,同事们见到他时告诉他:“我们被告知,他们正在考虑停止使用[国民健康服务]进行癌症治疗”(第245页)。要弄清楚谁在说什么并不容易,但这似乎是博伊德告诉塞尔登,他的同事告诉他,他们被告知特拉斯和克瓦登正在考虑这个问题。不用说,这种“几度分离”的传闻在书出版时就进入了媒体(例如Stacey, 2024),迫使Truss否认曾经考虑过这样一个不合理的政策。 可能是一些顾问,甚至是其中一位校长自己开了一个低级趣味的玩笑,但特拉斯认真准备以这种方式将生命置于危险之中的想法只是她被反复描绘成最糟糕的一面的另一个例子。正如我说过的,塞尔顿的方法严重依赖于对匿名人士的采访。我们不知道这些证人是谁,也不知道应该给予他们多少信任。许多人将是特拉斯的随行人员中资历相对较低的(现在可能相当失望);其中许多人要么是政治对手,要么是别有用心。虽然塞尔顿显然需要保护他的消息来源,但遗憾的是,他没能告诉我们议员、官员或顾问的比例,以及他们是如何被招募的。他们是自愿的,还是塞尔登的团队找来的?如果是后者,有多少人拒绝了?了解面试的结构是很有用的:是有一套标准问题,还是更自由的问题?同样有趣的是,他的研究人员制作的草稿在多大程度上影响了塞尔登的结论。我所注意到的大量负面评论是为了支持先前的观点,还是因为太多的受访者对特拉斯持批评态度而被迫引起他的注意?因此,这不是一项能在学术期刊上发表论文的研究。这并不一定是更糟的,因为一般读者会发现它很流畅,但塞尔顿不是一个训练有素的政治学家。当然,他也不是经济学家:这本书的弱点之一是对经济学的忽视。书中没有特拉斯和夸滕对英国糟糕的经济表现所作的分析,也没有对他们的提议进行认真的审查——这些审查本可以借鉴大量的官方和学术资料。金融市场对小型预算的反应几乎没有涉及,特别是债务驱动投资(ldi)的问题,只是非常简要地概述了一下。我很钦佩安东尼爵士,这本快速出版的书是一项相当大的成就。但它本质上是长篇新闻,在短暂的特拉斯政府被舆论领袖和媒体遗忘之前,匆忙推出是为了满足人们对深度叙事和评论的需求。历史的初稿?也许吧,但随着时间的流逝和尘埃落定,关于这一事件肯定还有更多可说的。值得强调的是,利兹·特拉斯比许多人认为的更适合当首相;比她的几位前任和保守党领袖的大多数竞争对手准备得更好。大学毕业后(她是自由民主党人,而不是保守党人),她在私营部门工作,并获得了特许管理会计师的资格,后来成为Cable &amp;无线,一家电信公司。在参加议会竞选失败后,她成为了改革组织的副主任,这是一个中右翼智库,而不是目前由奈杰尔·法拉奇领导的政党。在那里,她写了几本小册子,阐述了她关于教育改革的想法。我应该说,我第一次见到利兹·特拉斯是在改革学院,当时我们讨论了她写的一份关于数学教育的报告。我当然不是她的私人朋友,但多年来我们见过几次面,也许足以对她的能力形成一种看法,这种看法早于她戏剧性的起落。我发现很难将我对她的印象——一个聪明、有趣——尽管有时在社交上相当笨拙——勤奋的政治动物——与塞尔顿书中描绘的精神错乱的库伊拉·德维尔(Cruella de Vil)相吻合。在经历了改革和一段时间的地方议员生涯后,特拉斯于2010年进入议会。她是一名活跃的后座议员,组织了几项地方倡议,并成为自由企业集团(Free Enterprise Group)的联合创始人,这是撒切尔夫人的致敬行动,其中包括几名后来变得杰出的议员,包括夸西·夸滕(Kwasi Kwarteng)、普里蒂·帕特尔(Priti Patel)和多米尼克·拉布(Dominic Raab)。该集团出版了《联合执政后》和《解放不列颠》等生动的书籍,主张减税和减少国家权力,这些主题奠定了她在唐宁街的基础。2012年,大卫·卡梅伦任命她为教育部副大臣,从那时起,她在三任首相手下连续服务了10年,包括环境大臣、司法大臣、财政首席大臣、国际贸易大臣和外交大臣。《拯救西方的十年》是一个戏剧性的标题。然而,莉兹·特拉斯的书中的大部分内容都相对低调地描述了她作为一名政治家的经历。在14章中,只有3章讲述了她担任首相的时间。 这本书写得很直白,没有大量的日期、引文和脚注,这些都让许多政治家的回忆录难以读懂。据我所知,这都是她自己的作品。书中有关她早期部长角色的章节很有启发性,因为她的挫折在很大程度上告诉我们,她后来担任首相时采取了一种对抗的方式。她最早在政府担任的职位是初级教育部长——原则上她非常适合这个职位,因为她在改革时期为教育和儿童保育投入了大量的时间和精力。然而,她发现很难让公务员重新思考根深蒂固的立场或及时做任何事情。她写道:当她试图推动适度放松托儿监管时,很快就遇到了既得利益集团,比如商业托儿所和有影响力的Mumsnet网站。她也遇到了与自由民主党(当时与保守党联合执政)的政治困难,后者最终阻止了她的提案。在教育大臣迈克尔·戈夫(Michael Gove)的领导下,提高教育水平的努力也遇到了相当大的困难,教师工会和专业团体抵制扭转“进步”正统的举措,后来她与戈夫发生了争执。她的下一份工作是在环境、食品和农村事务部。在写她在那里的经历时,特拉斯提出了一个最喜欢的主题——非政府组织(ngo)对部门议程的劫持,通常是与政府有共生关系的“慈善机构”,而政府主要为它们提供资金。在她担任司法部长的短暂(仅11个月)任期的章节中,她发现很难取得进展,并被拖入一场关于司法独立的争论中。她再次发现,非政府机构和公务员控制了太多的议程,而政客们则在下一次改组前努力掌握他们的简报并确定政策。在谈到她担任国际贸易大臣和外交大臣的经历时,她继续用类似的口吻。在反思后一个角色时,她将对英国失败的批评扩大到世界卫生组织(World Health Organization)和联合国(United Nations)等国际机构,以及COP26大会和外援支出。但她的主要批评集中在英国经济被财政部对宏观经济政策的控制和“算盘会计”(她的术语)所阻碍的方式上,她认为这阻碍了她所支持的激进减税措施和放松管制。对财政部影响力的反对由来已久。早在20世纪20年代和30年代,凯恩斯是“财政部观点”(Clarke, 2005)的批评者,该观点拒绝了他所倡导的扩张性财政政策。然后,在20世纪60年代,工党首相哈罗德•威尔逊(Harold Wilson)决心削弱财政部的权力,于是他成立了一个短暂的经济事务部(Department of Economic Affairs),与之竞争。特拉斯对现代财政部的部分批评是,它将政府的经济和会计职能结合在一起,这在国际上是不寻常的。她断言,在工党前首相托尼•布莱尔(Tony Blair)和戈登•布朗(Gordon Brown)的领导下,“财政部的正统观念已经转向左翼,远离了我们希望追求的自由市场经济”(第233页)。此外,财政部已经“将触角伸向了国内政策”。政府不再简单地给各部门设置开支上限,而是越来越多地控制资金的用途。此外,1997年戈登•布朗(Gordon Brown)授予英格兰银行(Bank of England)的独立性,使其摆脱了政客们对货币政策的掌控。财政大臣乔治·奥斯本(George Osborne)在2010-15年联合政府期间成立了预算责任办公室(OBR):这是一个对政府政策变化的影响提供独立预测的机构。尽管作为预测者表现平平,但OBR“逐渐形成了自己的生命,现在基本上制定了财政政策”(第234页)。在特拉斯看来,财政部、英格兰银行和预算责任办公室都是高税收、大政府、高监管共识的追随者,这种共识阻碍了经济发展。她和Kwarteng决心打破这种共识,因为他们追求通过经济自由化促进增长的项目。理想情况下,特拉斯希望“非常努力地废除OBR,任命英格兰银行和财政部准备挑战正统的高级领导人”(第241页)。但废除OBR需要立法,而英格兰银行行长又不能被解雇,因此唯一的实质改变就是更换财政部常任秘书汤姆·斯考特爵士。 然而,特拉斯和夸滕最初与英格兰银行行长保持距离,并没有让预算责任办公室参与评估微型预算可能产生的影响。在关于特拉斯担任首相几周的章节中,没有什么重大的启示,尽管她辩称(第242页),与小预算相关的成本被夸大了,财政部没有人告诉她的团队有关臭名昭著的负债驱动投资(第252-3页)。她承认,有些事情她本可以处理得更好,但几乎没有任何忏悔的迹象。相反,她认为,“市场”对她的政府的明显反应,是由于她没有得到央行、财政部和其他当权派的支持,包括保守党中那些不承认她领导合法性的人的支持。她写道:我们可能不应该在术语上纠缠太多,但我们在这里谈论的真的是保守主义吗?保守主义者,几乎顾名思义,是反对改变的。的确,特拉斯对她自己的保守党的批评表明,她的太多同僚——21世纪相当于撒切尔夫人的“湿派”——满足于现状,不准备挑战自托尼·布莱尔和戈登·布朗时代以来形成的正统观念,对自由市场、控制移民和言论自由的信仰只是口头上的。特拉斯真正想要的是一种更接近古典自由主义的方法。在我们这个时代,这意味着与大国家、高税收和政府对经济生活各个领域的监管和控制彻底决裂。尽管如此,她希望传授什么教训呢?第一课:我们必须做保守主义者。这意味着从个人和家庭控制自己生活的保守原则开始。“这意味着捍卫财产权、言论自由和法治。它意味着捍卫主权、民族国家和英国的例外主义”(第290页)。它还意味着拒绝“净零狂热”和“工作主义”,避免“妥协和三角关系”。教训二:我们必须瓦解左派国家。特拉斯断言,“如果左派国家机器保持完整,我们就不会成功地实施保守政策”(第292页)。《人权法案》、《平等法案》和《气候变化法案》是“左翼信仰的图腾,保守派很容易接受它们,认为它们是不可动摇的。”我们应该准备废除它们”(第293页)。教训3:我们必须恢复民主问责制。“由于对政治制度的信任已经被侵蚀,政治家们已经把更多的权力交给了未经选举的官员”(第293页)。英国央行(Bank of England)必须对民选政客更负责任,同时必须废除OBR等半官方机构。与美国一样,政府应该有权任命高级公务员(第294页)。教训4:保守派必须在整个自由世界取得胜利,尤其是在美国。特拉斯认为,“左派更善于在全球范围内组织起来,而且他们的行动非常有效,足以推翻保守派的成就……如果我们要改变态度,再次赢得思想之战,我们这些右翼人士需要盟友”(第298页)。这似乎涉及到在不同国家的政治集团之间建立联盟。教训5:我们必须重申民族国家。如果要鼓励志同道合的政治家之间的跨境非正式政治联系,那么世界银行(World Bank)和国际货币基金组织(imf)等国际经济机构就绝对不应该受到鼓励(后者批评了迷你预算)。世界贸易组织(wto)、世界卫生组织(who)和联合国(UN)也不应该这么做,因为英国纳税人在它们身上花了太多钱。《联合国难民公约》(UN Refugee Convention)和欧洲人权法院(European Court of Human Rights)“不再符合它们目前的目的”(第299页):它们“越来越多地被维权律师利用和滥用”,以颠覆限制移民或驱逐罪犯的政策。第六课:我们必须结束绥靖政策。“绥靖我们的敌人是行不通的……我们似乎仍然面临着重复上世纪30年代错误的风险,这次是中国、俄罗斯和伊朗”(第300页)。特别是,我们应该拒绝中国进入我们的市场,并将任何与中国做生意的人视为贱民。“我们还需要对我们自己国家中支持敌对政权的人采取更强硬的态度”(第301页)。英国应该将伊朗革命卫队列为恐怖组织,并且“早就应该关闭孔子学院”。这些都是强有力的东西,但距离决定是否降低公司税或设定能源价格差距还有很长的路要走,这是利兹·特拉斯(Liz Truss)上台时最关心的问题。 是不是言过其实了?它能很好地陈化吗?如果说,正如哈罗德•威尔逊(Harold Wilson)可能说过(也可能没有说过),一周在政治上是很长的一段时间,那么利兹•特拉斯(Liz Truss)政府下台以来的时间似乎是永恒的。政治形势发生了很大变化。事实证明,她对国际社会“向左转”的看法需要相当的资格。在特拉斯辞职的两天前,乔治娅·梅洛尼领导右翼的意大利兄弟党进入政府。2023年12月,挥舞电锯的自由市场经济学家哈维尔•米莱(Javier Milei)成为阿根廷总统。2024年11月,唐纳德•特朗普(Donald Trump)赢得了美国总统第二任期,在亿万富翁埃隆•马斯克(Elon Musk)的大力支持下,他计划对“大政府”发起攻击。与此同时,右翼在法国、德国、荷兰和新西兰等国的选举中取得了胜利。英国(或许是暂时的)在2024年7月选举了工党政府,扭转了这一趋势。这并不令人意外:在六年内换掉了四位党魁的自相残杀的保守党,最终任命了两个月前在保守党竞选中输给特拉斯的苏纳克(Rishi Sunak),而没有得到党员的进一步授权。尽管苏纳克的领导使市场平静下来,经济增长也出现了小幅好转,但他的政府在控制移民方面的无能——尤其是小船越境的情况非常明显——加剧了持续的动荡,他出人意料地提前6个月宣布举行大选。结果是工党取得了巨大的胜利,保守党赢得了自19世纪初成立以来最少的议会席位。然而,新政府以不到总票数的三分之一获得了议会多数席位,并迅速陷入了自己的问题。工党财政大臣雷切尔·里夫斯(Rachel Reeves)在2024年10月提出了一份预算,几乎是夸西夸滕提案的镜像。尽管工党同意特拉斯政府的首要目标必须是促进经济增长,但工党提高了税收和政府支出,而不是减少它们。然而,就像俄罗斯-夸滕省的迷你预算一样,它提议大幅增加政府借贷。这导致金融市场转而反对它,金边债券(政府债券)的收益率目前处于2007-08年全球金融危机以来的最高水平,超过了小预算出台后立即达到的水平。这使得特拉斯声称,这证明她在2022年的立场是正确的。事实上,她甚至厚颜无耻地让她的律师给总理基尔·斯塔默(Keir Starmer)发了一封“停止”信,要求他停止对她“破坏经济”的“虚假和诽谤性”指控(莱利-史密斯&amp;华莱士,2025)。法律上的威胁能否阻止普通民众做出自己的决定,令人怀疑。但可能值得指出的是,对经济崩溃的指控被大大夸大了(欧洲经济学,2024)。在金融市场之外,从来没有任何重大的负面影响。产出和就业保持稳定。正如通常在政治上保持中立的英国国家经济与社会研究所(National Institute of Economic and Social Research)的斯蒂芬•米尔沃德(Stephen Millward)教授在事件发生一年后所说的那样,唯一一个永久性损失的群体是那些在小预算出台后一个月进行再抵押贷款的人,当时抵押贷款利率飙升(Millward, 2023)。虽然瑞秋·里夫斯面临的问题可能表明,特拉斯和瓜滕的提议并不是唯一破坏稳定的因素,但它们确实可能会削弱特拉斯的信念,即反对微型预算的反应是由Blob对自由市场政策的厌恶精心策划的。如果一揽子大的州-大的税收措施遇到了类似的反应,它确实破坏了一个简单的阴谋论的故事。但撇开政治得分不谈,我们对2022年秋季金融危机机制的理解有了新的发展,因为数字计算器必须发挥作用。在特拉斯政府垮台后不久,许多评论员声称,由于特拉斯竞选保守党领袖期间,大多数迷你预算提案都已预先宣布,它们将“定价”到市场预期中。虽然能源价格上限的宣布和取消所得税最高税率的提议会产生一些影响,但市场波动超出了合理的预期(Moynihan, 2023)。根据这一观点(暗示负债驱动型投资的放大效应),英国央行(Bank of England)通过糟糕的金融监管和自身的政策行动,至少对这场危机负有部分责任。养老基金需要将可预测的负债与资产相匹配。金融当局曾鼓励它们投资于金边债券,这是为政府借款融资所必需的。 英国国债的回报率相对较低,因为它们是极其安全的资产。当局对LDI基金的投资睁一只眼闭一只眼,至少是睁一只眼闭一只眼。LDI基金利用持有的英国国债作为贷款抵押品,购买更多的政府债券和信贷衍生品。这使他们能够获得更高的利润。然而,这是一个潜在的不稳定因素,因为如果利率上升,银行将要求更多的抵押品。由于利率上升意味着债券价格下跌,持有者将试图出售金边债券,以尽量减少资本损失。因此有可能出现“厄运循环”——这导致英国央行(Bank of England)介入市场购买债券并支撑价格。批评人士认为,美国利率上升,加上人们预期英国央行(Bank of England)即将开始“量化紧缩”,意味着我们面临着一场危机即将发生的局面。在这种观点中,小预算是点燃比其实际内容更大的危机的火花。一些人指责英国央行和金融监管机构直到为时已晚才意识到这一点。这就是理论。英国央行(Bank of England)发表的研究成果,如今为这些理论骨架增添了一些实证内容。Pinter等人(2024)的一篇论文表明,在小预算危机期间,至少有一半的金边债券价格下跌是LDI抛售的结果,而Alfaro等人(2024)使用不同方法的一项研究将30年期借款成本上升的三分之二归因于LDI的影响。虽然这项研究表明,市场对微型预算的反应被夸大了,也许,正如Seldon所指出的,在某种程度上,这是一个不幸的时机问题,可能会减轻对Liz Truss和Kwasi Kwarteng的指责,但仍然存在严重的问题,即它匆忙出台的速度,以及在没有至少一些迹象表明最终会有相应的支出削减的情况下宣布减税是否明智。特拉斯和夸滕似乎认为,由于市场愿意在疫情封锁期间支持公共债务的大幅增加,在更正常的情况下,他们也会接受财政上的不节制。大幅减税将产生“震慑效应”,表明他们是认真的。他们过于乐观了——就像瑞秋·里夫斯(Rachel Reeves)一样。其结果是,为了追求减税带来的甜头,政府失去了一个真正的机会,本来可以通过缩减政府规模和去除繁冗的监管措施,来推动停滞不前的英国经济取得一些进展。这些问题还需要考虑一段时间。与此同时,浑身是血但并未屈服的利兹·特拉斯仍然坚持战斗,在英国和美国的新闻中都很少缺席。尽管失去了议会席位,仍然面临着广泛的诽谤、嘲笑和羞辱,但正如她在政府垮台时告诉下议院的那样,她仍然是“一个斗士,而不是一个放弃者”。她不是枯萎的莴苣。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
ECONOMIC AFFAIRS
ECONOMIC AFFAIRS ECONOMICS-
CiteScore
1.40
自引率
14.30%
发文量
0
期刊介绍: Economic Affairs is a journal for those interested in the application of economic principles to practical affairs. It aims to stimulate debate on economic and social problems by asking its authors, while analysing complex issues, to make their analysis and conclusions accessible to a wide audience. Each issue has a theme on which the main articles focus, providing a succinct and up-to-date review of a particular field of applied economics. Themes in 2008 included: New Perspectives on the Economics and Politics of Ageing, Housing for the Poor: the Role of Government, The Economic Analysis of Institutions, and Healthcare: State Failure. Academics are also invited to submit additional articles on subjects related to the coverage of the journal. There is section of double blind refereed articles and a section for shorter pieces that are reviewed by our Editorial Board (Economic Viewpoints). Please contact the editor for full submission details for both sections.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:604180095
Book学术官方微信