Algorithmic Collusion Without Threats

Eshwar Ram Arunachaleswaran, Natalie Collina, Sampath Kannan, Aaron Roth, Juba Ziani
{"title":"Algorithmic Collusion Without Threats","authors":"Eshwar Ram Arunachaleswaran, Natalie Collina, Sampath Kannan, Aaron Roth, Juba Ziani","doi":"arxiv-2409.03956","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"There has been substantial recent concern that pricing algorithms might learn\nto ``collude.'' Supra-competitive prices can emerge as a Nash equilibrium of\nrepeated pricing games, in which sellers play strategies which threaten to\npunish their competitors who refuse to support high prices, and these\nstrategies can be automatically learned. In fact, a standard economic intuition\nis that supra-competitive prices emerge from either the use of threats, or a\nfailure of one party to optimize their payoff. Is this intuition correct? Would\npreventing threats in algorithmic decision-making prevent supra-competitive\nprices when sellers are optimizing for their own revenue? No. We show that\nsupra-competitive prices can emerge even when both players are using algorithms\nwhich do not encode threats, and which optimize for their own revenue. We study\nsequential pricing games in which a first mover deploys an algorithm and then a\nsecond mover optimizes within the resulting environment. We show that if the\nfirst mover deploys any algorithm with a no-regret guarantee, and then the\nsecond mover even approximately optimizes within this now static environment,\nmonopoly-like prices arise. The result holds for any no-regret learning\nalgorithm deployed by the first mover and for any pricing policy of the second\nmover that obtains them profit at least as high as a random pricing would --\nand hence the result applies even when the second mover is optimizing only\nwithin a space of non-responsive pricing distributions which are incapable of\nencoding threats. In fact, there exists a set of strategies, neither of which\nexplicitly encode threats that form a Nash equilibrium of the simultaneous\npricing game in algorithm space, and lead to near monopoly prices. This\nsuggests that the definition of ``algorithmic collusion'' may need to be\nexpanded, to include strategies without explicitly encoded threats.","PeriodicalId":501188,"journal":{"name":"arXiv - ECON - Theoretical Economics","volume":"129 1","pages":""},"PeriodicalIF":0.0000,"publicationDate":"2024-09-06","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"arXiv - ECON - Theoretical Economics","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/arxiv-2409.03956","RegionNum":0,"RegionCategory":null,"ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"","JCRName":"","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

There has been substantial recent concern that pricing algorithms might learn to ``collude.'' Supra-competitive prices can emerge as a Nash equilibrium of repeated pricing games, in which sellers play strategies which threaten to punish their competitors who refuse to support high prices, and these strategies can be automatically learned. In fact, a standard economic intuition is that supra-competitive prices emerge from either the use of threats, or a failure of one party to optimize their payoff. Is this intuition correct? Would preventing threats in algorithmic decision-making prevent supra-competitive prices when sellers are optimizing for their own revenue? No. We show that supra-competitive prices can emerge even when both players are using algorithms which do not encode threats, and which optimize for their own revenue. We study sequential pricing games in which a first mover deploys an algorithm and then a second mover optimizes within the resulting environment. We show that if the first mover deploys any algorithm with a no-regret guarantee, and then the second mover even approximately optimizes within this now static environment, monopoly-like prices arise. The result holds for any no-regret learning algorithm deployed by the first mover and for any pricing policy of the second mover that obtains them profit at least as high as a random pricing would -- and hence the result applies even when the second mover is optimizing only within a space of non-responsive pricing distributions which are incapable of encoding threats. In fact, there exists a set of strategies, neither of which explicitly encode threats that form a Nash equilibrium of the simultaneous pricing game in algorithm space, and lead to near monopoly prices. This suggests that the definition of ``algorithmic collusion'' may need to be expanded, to include strategies without explicitly encoded threats.
无威胁的算法合作
最近,定价算法可能学会 "垄断 "的问题引起了广泛关注。超竞争价格可以作为重复定价博弈的纳什均衡而出现,在这种博弈中,卖方采取的策略是威胁杀死拒绝支持高价的竞争对手,而这种策略可以自动学习。事实上,一个标准的经济学直觉是,超竞争价格的出现要么是由于威胁的使用,要么是由于一方未能优化其报酬。这种直觉正确吗?在算法决策中防止威胁会阻止卖方为自己的收益最优化而产生超竞争价格吗?我们的研究表明,即使双方都使用不包含威胁的算法,并为自己的收益进行优化,也会出现超竞争价格。我们研究了后继定价博弈,在这种博弈中,先行者部署一种算法,然后后继者在由此产生的环境中进行优化。我们的研究表明,如果第一推动者部署任何具有无悔保证的算法,然后这些第二推动者在现在的静态环境中进行近似优化,就会出现类似垄断的价格。这个结果适用于第一推动者部署的任何无悔学习算法,也适用于第二推动者的任何定价政策,只要这些政策能让他们获得至少与随机定价一样高的利润--因此,即使第二推动者只是在无法编码威胁的无响应定价分布空间内进行优化,这个结果也是适用的。事实上,存在一组策略,它们都没有明确地编码威胁,在算法空间中形成了同时定价博弈的纳什均衡,并导致接近垄断的价格。这表明 "算法合谋 "的定义可能需要扩展,以包括没有明确编码威胁的策略。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
自引率
0.00%
发文量
0
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信