INTRODUCTION TO THE SPECIAL ISSUE ON REACHING NET ZERO BY 2050

IF 2.3 4区 经济学 0 ECONOMICS
Robert Mendelsohn, David Maddison, Daigee Shaw
{"title":"INTRODUCTION TO THE SPECIAL ISSUE ON REACHING NET ZERO BY 2050","authors":"Robert Mendelsohn, David Maddison, Daigee Shaw","doi":"10.1142/s201000782303001x","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Climate Change EconomicsOnline Ready Free AccessINTRODUCTION TO THE SPECIAL ISSUE ON REACHING NET ZERO BY 2050Robert Mendelsohn, David Maddison, and Daigee ShawRobert MendelsohnYale School of the Environment, New Haven, CT, USA, David MaddisonDepartment of Economics, University of Birmingham, Birmingham, UK, and Daigee ShawInstitute of Economics, Academia Sinica, Taiwanhttps://doi.org/10.1142/S201000782303001XCited by:0 Next AboutSectionsPDF/EPUB ToolsAdd to favoritesDownload CitationsTrack CitationsRecommend to Librarian ShareShare onFacebookTwitterLinked InRedditEmail The Paris Agreement on Climate Change is a binding International Treaty signed by 196 parties (countries) in 2015. The Paris Agreement stated a desire to hold warming to well below 2.0∘C with a preferred warming target of 1.5∘C. These targets were chosen to prevent harmful global warming. In order to reach these temperature targets, global greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions need to fall toward zero this century.Several economic studies have explored the cost of holding global warming to 2∘C by 2100. Although economic studies of the damage caused by GHGs have explored a wide range of economic scenarios (SSP1 through SSP5), economic studies of the mitigation cost of holding temperatures to 2∘C or less have relied solely on a single scenario (SSP1). The economic growth rate in SSP1 is 2.3%. In contrast, the economic growth rate needed for the high emission RCP8.5 scenario is 3.1%/yr. By 2100, a 3.1% growth rate leads to a global economy of 1100 trillion USD, whereas global GDP is just 620 trillion USD with a 2.3% growth rate. The mitigation cost of holding the world to low temperatures would be considerably higher if economic growth rates were higher. Luckily, economists are not anticipating economic growth rates of 3%.In order to hold temperatures to 2∘C, modelers have assumed SSP1 and RCP2.6 (SSP1-RCP2.6) (IPCC 2022) (Riahi et al., 2022). These economic studies have found the least cost emission path that would hold temperatures at 2∘C. This emission path tends to decline over time, reaching net zero around 2080. Cumulative emissions would rise above the final desired level so that the final two decades are assumed to have negative emissions. Negative emissions imply carbon dioxide is drawn out of the atmosphere using afforestation, crop biomass with CCS, and direct air capture and storage. The conclusion of Working Group III in the 2022 Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC 2022) was that such emission paths were likely to cost 1.3–2.7% of global GDP each year (Riahi et al., 2022). This cost estimate implies global spending on mitigation would be 1.3–2.7 trillion USD per year this decade, rising to 8.1–22.8 trillion USD per year by the final decade of the century. That amounts to an annual cost of 164–467 USD per person this decade and 1151–2391 USD per person by 2100. This per person payment applies not only to wealthy citizens but to everyone on the planet.In order to hold temperatures to 1.5∘C, the world must engage in more dramatic and immediate emission reductions. The studies that examine the 1.5∘C target are also based on SSP1 but use the RCP1.9 emission scenario. These studies hold temperatures at 1.5∘C by reducing emissions by 50% by 2030 (seven years from now) and by 90% by 2050. This is far more expensive than the 2∘C scenario because the mitigation must be done immediately forcing a great deal of our current global capital to be prematurely retired. The conclusion of the IPCC (2022) report is that these 1.5∘C scenarios would cost 2.6–4.2% of GDP each year (Riahi et al., 2022). This translates into a cost of 2.6–4.2 trillion USD each year now and a cost of 16.1–26.0 trillion USD per year in 2100. On a global per person basis, the current annual cost is 328–530 USD rising to 2303–3720 USD by 2100.“Net Zero by 2050” is a more stringent emission path than just meeting the 1.5∘C target by 2100. After 2050, all remaining GHG emissions in a year must be offset by negative emissions that same year. The mitigation cost of “Net Zero by 2050” is likely to be higher than the 1.5∘C scenario because there is no flexibility about net emissions after 2050. Surprisingly, the cost of “Net Zero by 2050” has not been published. This Special Issue asked a number of modeling teams to estimate what “Net Zero by 2050” would cost individual countries, regions, and the world. Many economic models could not estimate these costs because the models could not organize the required investment in time for these goals to be met. However, a few bold authors attempted to determine the mitigation cost of “Net Zero by 2050” in this Special Issue.The paper by Richard Tol entitled “Costs and Benefits of the Paris Climate Targets” argues that the least cost estimate of reaching Net Zero by 2050 is optimistically going to cost 3.8–5.6% of GDP (Tol, 2023). The Tol estimates translate into a 3.8–5.6 trillion USD cost today or about 475–700 USD per person. In 2100, this would grow to 24–35 trillion USD or 3366–4960 USD per person. He estimates that the costs of these low temperature goals are unlikely to outweigh the benefits.Tol also makes a cogent argument that these least cost numbers are a floor, not a best guess. Tol argues that there is no indication that any country is going to follow a least-cost path. A great deal of the mitigation that has been undertaken to date has been very inefficient, leading to high costs per mitigated ton.Tol further notes that very few countries are even planning on reaching net zero by 2050. There is a big gap between the goals of the Paris Agreement and the mitigation plans of most countries. Finally, he notes that there is a rapidly rising cost to negative emissions, removing carbon from the atmosphere. Attempts to create ever more forestland and convert ever more cropland into biomass production are quickly going to run out of land. Direct air capture and storage could cost as much as $1000/ton implying that a gigaton would cost $trillion.The paper by Daigee Shaw, Yu-Hsuan Fu, and Ya-Qi Chen entitled “East Asia Climate Club: Pathway Towards 2050 Net-Zero” examines the emission plans for Japan, South Korea, China, and Taiwan (Shaw et al., 2023). They apply the E3ME-FTT model to assess three net-zero policy scenarios. The authors begin by noting that Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan have recently agreed to reach net zero by 2050, with China following suit by 2060. However, the detailed mitigation plans of each country would only lead to an aggregate reduction of emissions from 17.5Gt/year by 2050 to 9.9Gt/yr. In order to further reduce emissions, the authors propose the four parties create a climate club with three common programs: a uniform carbon price with revenue-neutral recycling, a carbon border adjustment mechanism (CBAM) on imports from non-club members, and a requirement to entirely phase out fossil fuel power generation without CCS by 2050. This would reduce aggregate emissions by 2050 to 6.6Gt/yr. They then propose the climate club creates a Green Fund from some of the carbon price revenues to invest in negative emission technologies to pay off the carbon debt. They find this Green Fund could cumulatively reduce emissions to 2.3Gt/yr by 2050. This is still short of Net Zero by 2050, but it gets the national plans of these four parties a lot closer to the desired goal. To fully reach the target, the governments must formulate additional net-zero strategies across sectors.The paper by Jennifer Morris, Y. H. Henry Chen, Angelo Gurgel, John Reilly, and Andrei Sokolov entitled “Net Zero Emissions of Greenhouse Gases by 2050: Achievable and at What Cost?” is the most optimistic paper in the Special Issue about reaching Net Zero by 2050 and lays out a detailed plan on how to get there (Morris et al., 2023). The analysis uses the MIT Integrated Global Systems Model (IGSM), a complete earth system-economic model to examine three scenarios: Net Zero by 2050 for the whole world, Net Zero for Europe and the United States but global emissions limited to holding temperatures at 1.5∘C by 2100, and the latter scheme with emission trading between Europe, the United States, and the rest of the world.The authors argue that a great deal of fossil fuels must be replaced in the electricity sector with renewables, biomass, and a little nuclear energy. This clean electricity replaces fossil fuels in homes, cars, and light industry. However, there will remain some hard to abate sectors, such as heavy industry (steel, cement, and chemicals), heavy transport (trucks, ships, rail, and airlines), and certain agricultural activities (livestock and rice). Substantial non-CO2 GHGs will also remain. These GHG emissions will have to be offset by negative emissions. The paper assumes these negative emissions can be achieved by switching 400Mha of managed forests into natural forests and by using 750Mha of grasslands and pasture for BECCS.Moving from Net Zero by 2050 to a 1.5∘C temperature target slightly relaxes the immediate constraints on emissions, though both policies are almost identical by the end of the century. Emission trading leads to the same aggregate target but at a slightly lower cost as the United States and Europe help China and India lower their emissions and buy credits from Latin America and Africa which both have considerable negative emissions to sell.With the Net Zero scenario, the price of carbon rises exponentially to 1200USD/ton by 2050 and then falls to about 400–700 USD/ton for the rest of the century. The 1.5∘C policy avoids this peak of carbon prices approaching 2050. The percent of global consumption lost in the Net Zero policy rises quickly after 2030 to 15% by 2050 and then falls back to 13% for the rest of the century. The 1.5∘C policy rises from 2030 to about 10% of global consumption by 2065. Net Zero by 2050 is feasible according to the model but the cost is staggering. Even holding temperatures at 1.5∘C, the cost will be almost three times higher than the IPCC (2022) report imagines (Riahi et al., 2022).In summary, the Net Zero by 2050 goal can be reached. But the sacrifice that the world must make to achieve this plan is steep. The people living between 2030 and 2060 could lose as much as 15% of their consumption. The world after 2060 could be 10% poorer. The short timeline to achieve a very large transformation will be far more disruptive to the economy than planners hope. Economics is not the only barrier. The most important barrier is likely to be political. Countries invariably will be reluctant to give up control of their land and spend so lavishly on a global benefit. Europe and the United States, who will allegedly lead this effort, could easily find themselves making deep sacrifices for very little national gain. The sacrifice will be made, but if not by all, the climate will warm anyway. The key point, though, is that 2∘C is a lot cheaper and the additional climate damage associated with 2∘C is not dramatic. References Morris, J, Y-H Henry Chen, A Gurgel, J Reilly and A Sokolov [2023] Net zero emissions of greenhouse gases by 2050: Achievable and at what cost? Climate Change Economics, 14(4), 2340002. Google Scholar Riahi, K et al. [2022] Mitigation pathways compatible with long-term goals. In IPCC, 2022: Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, PR Shuklaet al. (eds.), Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar Shaw, D, Y-H Fu and Y-Q Chen [2023] East Asia climate club: Pathway toward 2050 net-zero. Climate Change Economics, 14(4), 2340005. Google Scholar Tol, RSJ [2023] Costs and benefits of the Paris climate targets. Climate Change Economics, 14(4), 2340003. Google Scholar Remember to check out the Most Cited Articles! Be inspired by these New titles in Energy, Resource & Environmental Economics today. Featuring authors from Princeton, Columbia University, Imperial College Business School and many more! FiguresReferencesRelatedDetails Recommended Online Ready Metrics History Received 4 September 2023 Accepted 5 September 2023 Published: 30 September 2023 PDF download","PeriodicalId":45922,"journal":{"name":"Climate Change Economics","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":2.3000,"publicationDate":"2023-09-30","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"Climate Change Economics","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1142/s201000782303001x","RegionNum":4,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"0","JCRName":"ECONOMICS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

Climate Change EconomicsOnline Ready Free AccessINTRODUCTION TO THE SPECIAL ISSUE ON REACHING NET ZERO BY 2050Robert Mendelsohn, David Maddison, and Daigee ShawRobert MendelsohnYale School of the Environment, New Haven, CT, USA, David MaddisonDepartment of Economics, University of Birmingham, Birmingham, UK, and Daigee ShawInstitute of Economics, Academia Sinica, Taiwanhttps://doi.org/10.1142/S201000782303001XCited by:0 Next AboutSectionsPDF/EPUB ToolsAdd to favoritesDownload CitationsTrack CitationsRecommend to Librarian ShareShare onFacebookTwitterLinked InRedditEmail The Paris Agreement on Climate Change is a binding International Treaty signed by 196 parties (countries) in 2015. The Paris Agreement stated a desire to hold warming to well below 2.0∘C with a preferred warming target of 1.5∘C. These targets were chosen to prevent harmful global warming. In order to reach these temperature targets, global greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions need to fall toward zero this century.Several economic studies have explored the cost of holding global warming to 2∘C by 2100. Although economic studies of the damage caused by GHGs have explored a wide range of economic scenarios (SSP1 through SSP5), economic studies of the mitigation cost of holding temperatures to 2∘C or less have relied solely on a single scenario (SSP1). The economic growth rate in SSP1 is 2.3%. In contrast, the economic growth rate needed for the high emission RCP8.5 scenario is 3.1%/yr. By 2100, a 3.1% growth rate leads to a global economy of 1100 trillion USD, whereas global GDP is just 620 trillion USD with a 2.3% growth rate. The mitigation cost of holding the world to low temperatures would be considerably higher if economic growth rates were higher. Luckily, economists are not anticipating economic growth rates of 3%.In order to hold temperatures to 2∘C, modelers have assumed SSP1 and RCP2.6 (SSP1-RCP2.6) (IPCC 2022) (Riahi et al., 2022). These economic studies have found the least cost emission path that would hold temperatures at 2∘C. This emission path tends to decline over time, reaching net zero around 2080. Cumulative emissions would rise above the final desired level so that the final two decades are assumed to have negative emissions. Negative emissions imply carbon dioxide is drawn out of the atmosphere using afforestation, crop biomass with CCS, and direct air capture and storage. The conclusion of Working Group III in the 2022 Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC 2022) was that such emission paths were likely to cost 1.3–2.7% of global GDP each year (Riahi et al., 2022). This cost estimate implies global spending on mitigation would be 1.3–2.7 trillion USD per year this decade, rising to 8.1–22.8 trillion USD per year by the final decade of the century. That amounts to an annual cost of 164–467 USD per person this decade and 1151–2391 USD per person by 2100. This per person payment applies not only to wealthy citizens but to everyone on the planet.In order to hold temperatures to 1.5∘C, the world must engage in more dramatic and immediate emission reductions. The studies that examine the 1.5∘C target are also based on SSP1 but use the RCP1.9 emission scenario. These studies hold temperatures at 1.5∘C by reducing emissions by 50% by 2030 (seven years from now) and by 90% by 2050. This is far more expensive than the 2∘C scenario because the mitigation must be done immediately forcing a great deal of our current global capital to be prematurely retired. The conclusion of the IPCC (2022) report is that these 1.5∘C scenarios would cost 2.6–4.2% of GDP each year (Riahi et al., 2022). This translates into a cost of 2.6–4.2 trillion USD each year now and a cost of 16.1–26.0 trillion USD per year in 2100. On a global per person basis, the current annual cost is 328–530 USD rising to 2303–3720 USD by 2100.“Net Zero by 2050” is a more stringent emission path than just meeting the 1.5∘C target by 2100. After 2050, all remaining GHG emissions in a year must be offset by negative emissions that same year. The mitigation cost of “Net Zero by 2050” is likely to be higher than the 1.5∘C scenario because there is no flexibility about net emissions after 2050. Surprisingly, the cost of “Net Zero by 2050” has not been published. This Special Issue asked a number of modeling teams to estimate what “Net Zero by 2050” would cost individual countries, regions, and the world. Many economic models could not estimate these costs because the models could not organize the required investment in time for these goals to be met. However, a few bold authors attempted to determine the mitigation cost of “Net Zero by 2050” in this Special Issue.The paper by Richard Tol entitled “Costs and Benefits of the Paris Climate Targets” argues that the least cost estimate of reaching Net Zero by 2050 is optimistically going to cost 3.8–5.6% of GDP (Tol, 2023). The Tol estimates translate into a 3.8–5.6 trillion USD cost today or about 475–700 USD per person. In 2100, this would grow to 24–35 trillion USD or 3366–4960 USD per person. He estimates that the costs of these low temperature goals are unlikely to outweigh the benefits.Tol also makes a cogent argument that these least cost numbers are a floor, not a best guess. Tol argues that there is no indication that any country is going to follow a least-cost path. A great deal of the mitigation that has been undertaken to date has been very inefficient, leading to high costs per mitigated ton.Tol further notes that very few countries are even planning on reaching net zero by 2050. There is a big gap between the goals of the Paris Agreement and the mitigation plans of most countries. Finally, he notes that there is a rapidly rising cost to negative emissions, removing carbon from the atmosphere. Attempts to create ever more forestland and convert ever more cropland into biomass production are quickly going to run out of land. Direct air capture and storage could cost as much as $1000/ton implying that a gigaton would cost $trillion.The paper by Daigee Shaw, Yu-Hsuan Fu, and Ya-Qi Chen entitled “East Asia Climate Club: Pathway Towards 2050 Net-Zero” examines the emission plans for Japan, South Korea, China, and Taiwan (Shaw et al., 2023). They apply the E3ME-FTT model to assess three net-zero policy scenarios. The authors begin by noting that Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan have recently agreed to reach net zero by 2050, with China following suit by 2060. However, the detailed mitigation plans of each country would only lead to an aggregate reduction of emissions from 17.5Gt/year by 2050 to 9.9Gt/yr. In order to further reduce emissions, the authors propose the four parties create a climate club with three common programs: a uniform carbon price with revenue-neutral recycling, a carbon border adjustment mechanism (CBAM) on imports from non-club members, and a requirement to entirely phase out fossil fuel power generation without CCS by 2050. This would reduce aggregate emissions by 2050 to 6.6Gt/yr. They then propose the climate club creates a Green Fund from some of the carbon price revenues to invest in negative emission technologies to pay off the carbon debt. They find this Green Fund could cumulatively reduce emissions to 2.3Gt/yr by 2050. This is still short of Net Zero by 2050, but it gets the national plans of these four parties a lot closer to the desired goal. To fully reach the target, the governments must formulate additional net-zero strategies across sectors.The paper by Jennifer Morris, Y. H. Henry Chen, Angelo Gurgel, John Reilly, and Andrei Sokolov entitled “Net Zero Emissions of Greenhouse Gases by 2050: Achievable and at What Cost?” is the most optimistic paper in the Special Issue about reaching Net Zero by 2050 and lays out a detailed plan on how to get there (Morris et al., 2023). The analysis uses the MIT Integrated Global Systems Model (IGSM), a complete earth system-economic model to examine three scenarios: Net Zero by 2050 for the whole world, Net Zero for Europe and the United States but global emissions limited to holding temperatures at 1.5∘C by 2100, and the latter scheme with emission trading between Europe, the United States, and the rest of the world.The authors argue that a great deal of fossil fuels must be replaced in the electricity sector with renewables, biomass, and a little nuclear energy. This clean electricity replaces fossil fuels in homes, cars, and light industry. However, there will remain some hard to abate sectors, such as heavy industry (steel, cement, and chemicals), heavy transport (trucks, ships, rail, and airlines), and certain agricultural activities (livestock and rice). Substantial non-CO2 GHGs will also remain. These GHG emissions will have to be offset by negative emissions. The paper assumes these negative emissions can be achieved by switching 400Mha of managed forests into natural forests and by using 750Mha of grasslands and pasture for BECCS.Moving from Net Zero by 2050 to a 1.5∘C temperature target slightly relaxes the immediate constraints on emissions, though both policies are almost identical by the end of the century. Emission trading leads to the same aggregate target but at a slightly lower cost as the United States and Europe help China and India lower their emissions and buy credits from Latin America and Africa which both have considerable negative emissions to sell.With the Net Zero scenario, the price of carbon rises exponentially to 1200USD/ton by 2050 and then falls to about 400–700 USD/ton for the rest of the century. The 1.5∘C policy avoids this peak of carbon prices approaching 2050. The percent of global consumption lost in the Net Zero policy rises quickly after 2030 to 15% by 2050 and then falls back to 13% for the rest of the century. The 1.5∘C policy rises from 2030 to about 10% of global consumption by 2065. Net Zero by 2050 is feasible according to the model but the cost is staggering. Even holding temperatures at 1.5∘C, the cost will be almost three times higher than the IPCC (2022) report imagines (Riahi et al., 2022).In summary, the Net Zero by 2050 goal can be reached. But the sacrifice that the world must make to achieve this plan is steep. The people living between 2030 and 2060 could lose as much as 15% of their consumption. The world after 2060 could be 10% poorer. The short timeline to achieve a very large transformation will be far more disruptive to the economy than planners hope. Economics is not the only barrier. The most important barrier is likely to be political. Countries invariably will be reluctant to give up control of their land and spend so lavishly on a global benefit. Europe and the United States, who will allegedly lead this effort, could easily find themselves making deep sacrifices for very little national gain. The sacrifice will be made, but if not by all, the climate will warm anyway. The key point, though, is that 2∘C is a lot cheaper and the additional climate damage associated with 2∘C is not dramatic. References Morris, J, Y-H Henry Chen, A Gurgel, J Reilly and A Sokolov [2023] Net zero emissions of greenhouse gases by 2050: Achievable and at what cost? Climate Change Economics, 14(4), 2340002. Google Scholar Riahi, K et al. [2022] Mitigation pathways compatible with long-term goals. In IPCC, 2022: Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, PR Shuklaet al. (eds.), Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar Shaw, D, Y-H Fu and Y-Q Chen [2023] East Asia climate club: Pathway toward 2050 net-zero. Climate Change Economics, 14(4), 2340005. Google Scholar Tol, RSJ [2023] Costs and benefits of the Paris climate targets. Climate Change Economics, 14(4), 2340003. Google Scholar Remember to check out the Most Cited Articles! Be inspired by these New titles in Energy, Resource & Environmental Economics today. Featuring authors from Princeton, Columbia University, Imperial College Business School and many more! FiguresReferencesRelatedDetails Recommended Online Ready Metrics History Received 4 September 2023 Accepted 5 September 2023 Published: 30 September 2023 PDF download
到2050年达到净零排放的特刊简介
《2050年达到净零排放》特刊简介robert Mendelsohn、David Maddison、Daigee ShawRobert Mendelsohn、耶鲁大学环境学院(美国康涅狄格州纽黑文)、David Maddison、英国伯明翰大学经济系、中央研究院shaigee经济研究所台湾https://doi.org/10.1142/S201000782303001XCited by:0下一个关于sectionspdf /EPUB工具添加到收藏下载CitationsTrack引文推荐给图书管理员分享分享在facebook上推特链接在redditemail巴黎气候变化协定是一项具有约束力的国际条约,由196个缔约方(国家)于2015年签署。《巴黎协定》表示希望将升温控制在2.0°C以下,首选升温目标是1.5°C。选择这些目标是为了防止有害的全球变暖。为了达到这些温度目标,全球温室气体(GHG)排放量需要在本世纪降至零。几项经济研究探讨了到2100年将全球变暖幅度控制在2°C的成本。虽然对温室气体造成损害的经济研究已经探索了广泛的经济情景(SSP1到SSP5),但对将温度控制在2°C或更低的减轻成本的经济研究只依赖于单一情景(SSP1)。SSP1的经济增长率为2.3%。相比之下,高排放RCP8.5情景所需的经济增长率为3.1%/年。到2100年,3.1%的增长率将使全球经济达到1100万亿美元,而2.3%的增长率下,全球GDP只有620万亿美元。如果经济增长率更高,将世界控制在低温下的减缓成本将会高得多。幸运的是,经济学家预计经济增长率不会达到3%。为了将温度控制在2°C,建模者假定为SSP1和RCP2.6 (SSP1-RCP2.6) (IPCC 2022) (Riahi et al., 2022)。这些经济研究找到了成本最低的排放途径,使气温保持在2°C。随着时间的推移,这种排放路径趋于下降,在2080年左右达到净零。累积排放量将超过最终期望的水平,从而假设最后20年的排放量为负。负排放意味着二氧化碳是通过植树造林、采用CCS的农作物生物量以及直接的空气捕获和储存从大气中抽出的。政府间气候变化专门委员会2022年第六次评估报告(IPCC 2022)第三工作组的结论是,这些排放路径每年可能造成全球GDP的1.3-2.7%的损失(Riahi et al., 2022)。这一成本估算意味着,本十年全球每年用于减缓的支出将达到1.3-2.7万亿美元,到本世纪最后一个十年将增至每年8.1-22.8万亿美元。这相当于这个十年每人每年花费164-467美元,到2100年每人花费1151-2391美元。这种人均支付不仅适用于富裕的公民,也适用于地球上的每个人。为了将气温控制在1.5°C以下,全世界必须立即采取更大幅度的减排行动。考察1.5°C目标的研究也是基于SSP1,但使用了RCP1.9排放情景。这些研究通过到2030年(7年后)减少50%的排放量和到2050年减少90%的排放量,将气温控制在1.5°C。这比2°C的情况要昂贵得多,因为必须立即采取缓解措施,迫使我们目前的大量全球资本过早退役。IPCC(2022)报告的结论是,这些1.5°C情景每年将造成GDP的2.6-4.2%的损失(Riahi et al., 2022)。这意味着现在每年的成本为2.6-4.2万亿美元,到2100年每年的成本为16.1-26.0万亿美元。在全球范围内,目前每人每年的费用为328-530美元,到2100年将上升到2303-3720美元。“2050年净零排放”是比到2100年达到1.5°C的目标更为严格的排放路径。2050年后,一年内所有剩余的温室气体排放必须由当年的负排放抵消。“2050年净零排放”的减排成本很可能高于1.5°C情景,因为2050年之后的净排放量没有灵活性。令人惊讶的是,“2050年净零排放”的成本尚未公布。本期特刊要求一些建模团队估计“2050年净零排放”将使各个国家、地区和世界付出多少代价。许多经济模型无法估计这些成本,因为这些模型无法及时组织所需的投资以实现这些目标。然而,一些大胆的作者试图在本期特刊中确定“2050年净零排放”的减排成本。Richard Tol撰写的题为《巴黎气候目标的成本和收益》的论文认为,到2050年实现净零排放的最低成本估计乐观地将占GDP的3.8% - 5.6% (Tol, 2023)。Tol的估计值为3.8-5。 今天的成本是6万亿美元,或者说人均475-700美元。到2100年,这一数字将增长到24-35万亿美元,即人均3366-4960美元。他估计,这些低温目标的成本不太可能超过收益。Tol还提出了一个令人信服的论点,即这些最低成本数字是一个底线,而不是最佳猜测。Tol认为,没有迹象表明任何国家会走成本最低的道路。迄今为止所采取的大量缓解措施效率极低,导致每吨缓解措施的成本很高。托尔进一步指出,很少有国家计划到2050年实现净零排放。《巴黎协定》的目标与大多数国家的减缓计划之间存在很大差距。最后,他指出,从大气中去除碳的负排放成本正在迅速上升。创造更多林地和将更多农田转化为生物质生产的尝试很快就会耗尽土地。直接的空气捕获和储存每吨的成本可能高达1000美元,这意味着十亿吨的成本将达到万亿美元。由邵岱基、傅玉萱和陈亚琪合著的论文《东亚气候俱乐部:通往2050年净零排放之路》考察了日本、韩国、中国大陆和台湾的排放计划(Shaw et al., 2023)。他们应用E3ME-FTT模型来评估三种净零政策情景。作者首先指出,日本、韩国和台湾最近同意到2050年实现净零排放,中国大陆也将在2060年跟进。然而,每个国家的详细减排计划只能使总排放量从2050年的175亿吨/年减少到99亿吨/年。为了进一步减少排放,作者建议四方建立一个有三个共同项目的气候俱乐部:统一的碳价格和收入中性的回收,对非俱乐部成员进口的碳边界调整机制(CBAM),以及到2050年完全淘汰没有CCS的化石燃料发电的要求。到2050年,这将使总排放量减少到6.6亿吨/年。然后,他们建议气候俱乐部从部分碳价格收入中创建一个绿色基金,投资于负排放技术,以偿还碳债务。他们发现,到2050年,这个绿色基金可以累计将排放量减少到23亿吨/年。到2050年,这仍未达到净零,但这使这四个政党的国家计划离预期目标更近了一步。为了全面实现这一目标,各国政府必须在各个部门制定额外的净零排放战略。这份由Jennifer Morris、Y. H. Henry Chen、Angelo Gurgel、John Reilly和Andrei Sokolov撰写的论文题为《到2050年温室气体净零排放:可实现的,代价是什么?》是特刊中关于到2050年达到净零的最乐观的论文,并就如何实现这一目标制定了详细的计划(Morris et al., 2023)。该分析使用麻省理工学院综合全球系统模型(IGSM),这是一个完整的地球系统-经济模型,用来考察三种情景:到2050年全球实现净零排放;到2100年欧洲和美国实现净零排放,但全球排放被限制在1.5°C以下;后一种方案是在欧洲、美国和世界其他地区之间进行排放交易。作者认为,电力部门必须用可再生能源、生物质能和少量核能取代大量化石燃料。这种清洁电力取代了家庭、汽车和轻工业中的化石燃料。然而,仍有一些难以削减的部门,如重工业(钢铁、水泥和化学品)、重型运输(卡车、船舶、铁路和航空)和某些农业活动(牲畜和大米)。大量的非二氧化碳温室气体也将继续存在。这些温室气体排放必须用负排放来抵消。该论文假设,通过将400万公顷的管理森林转变为天然林,并将750万公顷的草原和牧场用于BECCS,可以实现这些负排放。从2050年的净零到1.5°C的温度目标略微放松了对排放的直接限制,尽管到本世纪末这两项政策几乎相同。排放交易的总目标相同,但成本略低,因为美国和欧洲帮助中国和印度降低排放,并从拉丁美洲和非洲购买碳排放额度,这两个国家都有相当多的负排放可供出售。在净零情景下,到2050年,碳的价格将呈指数级增长,达到每吨1200美元,然后在本世纪剩下的时间里下降到每吨400-700美元左右。1.5°C的政策避免了碳价格在2050年达到峰值。2030年后,净零排放政策导致的全球消费损失比例迅速上升至2050年的15%,然后在本世纪剩下的时间里回落至13%。从2030年到2065年,1.5°C的政策将上升到全球消耗量的10%左右。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
CiteScore
5.10
自引率
17.40%
发文量
36
期刊介绍: Climate Change Economics (CCE) publishes theoretical and empirical papers devoted to analyses of mitigation, adaptation, impacts, and other issues related to the policy and management of greenhouse gases. CCE is specifically devoted to papers in economics although it is understood that authors may need to rely on other fields for important insights. The journal is interested in papers examining the issue at every scale from local to global and papers from around the world are encouraged. CCE is also interested in both original research and review papers and welcomes comments discussing previous articles.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信