Summaries of Articles
IF 1.8
3区 经济学
Q2 BUSINESS, FINANCE
求助PDF
{"title":"Summaries of Articles","authors":"","doi":"10.1086/726079","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"Previous articleNext article FreeSummaries of ArticlesPDFPDF PLUSFull Text Add to favoritesDownload CitationTrack CitationsPermissionsReprints Share onFacebookTwitterLinkedInRedditEmailPrint SectionsMoreRetailer Remittance Matters: Evidence from Voluntary Collection AgreementsYeliz Kaçamak, Tejaswi Velayudhan, and Eleanor WilkingWhat are the effects of requiring online retailers to remit sales taxes, just as brick-and-mortar retailers do? Although goods purchased online have always been subject to similar sales/use tax as their brick-and-mortar counterparts, the responsibility to remit this tax has been on the consumer until recently. This issue has received considerable attention at the state and federal levels in light of the growing importance of online commerce and consequent efforts to stem base erosion. Yet there is little empirical evidence on how shifting the remittance obligation affects online and brick-and-mortar retail, and who bears the additional tax burden, if any, of imposing parity between the two retail channels. In this paper, we study VCAs — bilateral agreements between states and large online retailers to remit sales tax — enacted between 2009 and 2017. We explore how shifting the sales-tax remittance obligation on online sales to retailers achieves intended goals of retailer collection and parity between online and brick-and-mortar stores, as well as its consequences for sales-tax incidence.This paper has two main contributions. First, we document the impact of changing remittance obligations on the relative attractiveness of online and brick-and-mortar markets through their impact on the effective tax rate on online sales. We show that online retailers add sales taxes at checkout immediately following policy adoption, indicating that the agreements were binding, complied with, and measurable in our data. Shopping trips, where sales taxes were likely added, increase by 36 percent immediately after VCA adoption among large online retailers and show no change among brick-and-mortar retailers. This represents a significant change in the ability of consumers to use online retail as a means of evasion, as expenditure at these large retailers represents about half of their total online expenditure.Further, we find that consumers shift consumption to brick-and-mortar stores from online channels, suggesting that the differential remittance rules had conferred some advantage to online retailers. Consumers immediately reduce their online taxable expenditure due to VCAs at large online retailers by about 20 percent. Over time, brick-and-mortar household expenditure rises, even above the decline in online expenditure.Our second contribution is to document the incidence of the effective tax increase from increased compliance on online retail. We find that any effective tax increase was passed through to consumers, as the tax-exclusive price does not change after the VCA, suggesting that they bear the economic burden of the increased enforcement. However, among consumers, we do not find that the VCA substantially changed the distributional burden of US state sales taxes. Although online expenditure is a higher share of income among lower-income households, middle-income households tended to shift more consumption toward brick-and-mortar stores instead of reducing overall expenditure. Therefore, the change in overall taxable expenditure as a share of income due to the VCA did not vary significantly across income groups, suggesting that VCAs do not disproportionately impact low-income households. Our findings contribute to the ongoing policy debate on online retailer remittance of sales taxes.Bias in Tax Progressivity EstimatesJohannes KönigIn debates about income inequality and societal fairness, inevitably the issue of tax progressivity comes up. A tax system is progressive if marginal tax rates exceed average tax rates, so that the tax burden on the last dollar earned is larger than the burden on the first dollar. Hence, top earners will both pay more in absolute and in relative terms. Tax progressivity does not only bring about a more equal net income distribution, but it has important incentive effects: if the last dollar is taxed more than the first, individuals are going to be less willing to exert additional effort to earn the last dollar. Therefore, it is important to be able to quantify the progressivity of the tax system.In quantitative economic research — particularly structural economic models — a way to quantify tax progressivity has become immensely popular: the power function approximation. This approximation connects gross and net incomes by an exponential function with two parameters. The approximation enables researchers to calculate net incomes as well as average and marginal tax rates. Yet it has another extremely useful property: the exponent of the power function approximation captures the global progressivity of the tax system. In fact, it measures the residual income elasticity, that is, the percentage change of net income due to a percentage change in gross income. If the elasticity is smaller than one, the tax system is progressive, and if it is larger than one, it is regressive.The approximation is not only popular because it can quantify progressivity but also because it offers a very good fit to the data and is easy to estimate. The researcher only needs data on gross and net incomes. There are two ways to estimate the progressivity parameter: either directly using a nonlinear estimator or by taking the logarithm on both sides and using ordinary least squares.The latter estimation method is the most popular way to estimate the power function approximation, but it is generally biased. However, a nonlinear estimator that is equivalent to a Poisson regression gives consistent progressivity estimates. In this paper, I document the severity of this bias in several data sets and find that differences in estimates range from 6 to 14 percent. Generally, using ordinary least squares leads to an overestimation of progressivity. Further, I show that when biased progressivity estimates are used in subsequent model calculations, errors propagate and become quite severe. Finally, I offer guidance to the practitioner on how to estimate the power function approximation.The Effect of Tax Price on Donations: Evidence from CanadaRoss Hickey, Brad Minaker, A. Abigail Payne, Joanne Roberts, and Justin SmithThe tax price of a $1 donation is the after-tax cost of the donation for the donor. We estimate the tax price elasticity of giving using a large sample of Canadian tax filers from 2001 to 2016. The richness of the data allows us to control for a variety of important factors and estimate the responsiveness of Canadian households to changes in the tax treatment of donations. Canada supports charitable giving through nonrefundable tax credits, and we find take-up of these credits throughout the distribution of income. There is a kink in the credit rate schedule at $200 of donations, which makes it difficult to convincingly estimate the effect of tax credits on donations using conventional methods. We use a statistical technique from the literature to produce estimates with nice properties.We find strong evidence of responsiveness to the tax credits, estimating the tax price elasticity to be −1.9. This means that for every dollar remitted back to tax filers for their donations, donations increase by $1.90. We also estimate the responsiveness within intervals of the distribution of household income. We find strong evidence of responses throughout the distribution of income. Interestingly, the most responsive donors are at the bottom 20 percent and 21 percent–40 percent of the household income distribution. We explore whether this response is driven by donors changing their gift sizes in response to the change in tax price or by tax filers changing when to donate. We find evidence that the large responses at the bottom of the income distribution are driven by the decision to donate, while responses for the top 20 percent, top 10 percent, and top 1 percent are driven more by the decision of how much to donate.Taken together, our research shows that tax concessions for donations to charity are effective at increasing charitable giving. Our results show larger estimated effects than previously found in the literature, which we attribute to our sample including many more lower-income households with an incentive to donate.Income Guarantee Policy Design: Implications for Poverty, Income Distribution, and Tax RatesRobert Paul Hartley and Irwin GarfinkelIncome-guarantee policies featured prominently in public discourse around the 1960s, including the presidential campaigns by Richard Nixon and George McGovern as well as the writing of Nobel laureate economists Milton Friedman and James Tobin and of Nobel Peace Prize activist Martin Luther King Jr. After 50 years of the War on Poverty, guarantee designs are resurging in both the economics literature and policy proposals. The National Academies of Science have promoted a universal child allowance, which was temporarily realized as part of the American Rescue Plan in response to the COVID-19 pandemic. To inform the expected impacts on poverty, income distribution, and tax rates, this paper simulates a moderately sized $250 monthly guarantee per person financed by a fundamental tax reform that eliminates all income tax deductions and institutes proportionally higher marginal tax rates (MTRs). We assume that households may respond with changes in labor supply relative to both the guarantee benefit and the financing mechanisms. Furthermore, we consider a general framework of important questions for an income guarantee design and discuss how the major impacts would compare.For our benchmark guarantee policy, poverty would fall by about 40 percent with a 20 percent reduction in inequality between the 90th and 10th percentiles of income. Fundamental tax reform would finance 60 percent of the total cost of $948 billion, and the remaining costs could be financed by raising MTRs by 23 percent across all brackets. Under this reform, households with incomes below $200,000 would be net beneficiaries, and the top MTR would rise from 37 to 45.5 percent. Although universal, such an income guarantee would have greater relative benefits for disadvantaged groups. Children and larger families would experience the largest antipoverty effects, as would caregivers, who are often unpaid or lower income. A universal income guarantee would also reduce the Black-White poverty gap by 16 percent — more for a larger benefit size — because of disproportionate poverty rates among those racialized as Black.We explore various options for designing an income guarantee, such as generosity amount, income eligibility, interaction with means-tested transfers, and forms of income taxation. Along with fundamental tax reform, a higher income guarantee of $500 monthly per person would reduce poverty and inequality by about 70 and 35 percent, respectively, and could be financed with effective tax rates similar to those observed in the US tax code as recently as 1981. Phasing out benefits at higher incomes can meaningfully reduce inequality without diminishing poverty reduction. Reducing the program costs of a guarantee by offsetting means-tested transfers substantially limits poverty reduction impacts. We also compare a flat surtax on all taxable income as opposed to proportionally increasing MTRs, and the implications for poverty and inequality are negligible.A primary function of a guaranteed income program is the maintenance of a livable income to support families, and moderate-sized guarantees could greatly reduce poverty at tax rates consistent with those in the optimal income tax literature. Previous articleNext article DetailsFiguresReferencesCited by National Tax Journal Volume 76, Number 2June 2023 Published for: The National Tax Association Article DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1086/726079 Views: 163Total views on this site © 2023 National Tax Association. All rights reserved.PDF download Crossref reports no articles citing this article.","PeriodicalId":18983,"journal":{"name":"National Tax Journal","volume":"61 1","pages":"0"},"PeriodicalIF":1.8000,"publicationDate":"2023-06-01","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"National Tax Journal","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1086/726079","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"经济学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"BUSINESS, FINANCE","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0
引用
批量引用
Abstract
Previous articleNext article FreeSummaries of ArticlesPDFPDF PLUSFull Text Add to favoritesDownload CitationTrack CitationsPermissionsReprints Share onFacebookTwitterLinkedInRedditEmailPrint SectionsMoreRetailer Remittance Matters: Evidence from Voluntary Collection AgreementsYeliz Kaçamak, Tejaswi Velayudhan, and Eleanor WilkingWhat are the effects of requiring online retailers to remit sales taxes, just as brick-and-mortar retailers do? Although goods purchased online have always been subject to similar sales/use tax as their brick-and-mortar counterparts, the responsibility to remit this tax has been on the consumer until recently. This issue has received considerable attention at the state and federal levels in light of the growing importance of online commerce and consequent efforts to stem base erosion. Yet there is little empirical evidence on how shifting the remittance obligation affects online and brick-and-mortar retail, and who bears the additional tax burden, if any, of imposing parity between the two retail channels. In this paper, we study VCAs — bilateral agreements between states and large online retailers to remit sales tax — enacted between 2009 and 2017. We explore how shifting the sales-tax remittance obligation on online sales to retailers achieves intended goals of retailer collection and parity between online and brick-and-mortar stores, as well as its consequences for sales-tax incidence.This paper has two main contributions. First, we document the impact of changing remittance obligations on the relative attractiveness of online and brick-and-mortar markets through their impact on the effective tax rate on online sales. We show that online retailers add sales taxes at checkout immediately following policy adoption, indicating that the agreements were binding, complied with, and measurable in our data. Shopping trips, where sales taxes were likely added, increase by 36 percent immediately after VCA adoption among large online retailers and show no change among brick-and-mortar retailers. This represents a significant change in the ability of consumers to use online retail as a means of evasion, as expenditure at these large retailers represents about half of their total online expenditure.Further, we find that consumers shift consumption to brick-and-mortar stores from online channels, suggesting that the differential remittance rules had conferred some advantage to online retailers. Consumers immediately reduce their online taxable expenditure due to VCAs at large online retailers by about 20 percent. Over time, brick-and-mortar household expenditure rises, even above the decline in online expenditure.Our second contribution is to document the incidence of the effective tax increase from increased compliance on online retail. We find that any effective tax increase was passed through to consumers, as the tax-exclusive price does not change after the VCA, suggesting that they bear the economic burden of the increased enforcement. However, among consumers, we do not find that the VCA substantially changed the distributional burden of US state sales taxes. Although online expenditure is a higher share of income among lower-income households, middle-income households tended to shift more consumption toward brick-and-mortar stores instead of reducing overall expenditure. Therefore, the change in overall taxable expenditure as a share of income due to the VCA did not vary significantly across income groups, suggesting that VCAs do not disproportionately impact low-income households. Our findings contribute to the ongoing policy debate on online retailer remittance of sales taxes.Bias in Tax Progressivity EstimatesJohannes KönigIn debates about income inequality and societal fairness, inevitably the issue of tax progressivity comes up. A tax system is progressive if marginal tax rates exceed average tax rates, so that the tax burden on the last dollar earned is larger than the burden on the first dollar. Hence, top earners will both pay more in absolute and in relative terms. Tax progressivity does not only bring about a more equal net income distribution, but it has important incentive effects: if the last dollar is taxed more than the first, individuals are going to be less willing to exert additional effort to earn the last dollar. Therefore, it is important to be able to quantify the progressivity of the tax system.In quantitative economic research — particularly structural economic models — a way to quantify tax progressivity has become immensely popular: the power function approximation. This approximation connects gross and net incomes by an exponential function with two parameters. The approximation enables researchers to calculate net incomes as well as average and marginal tax rates. Yet it has another extremely useful property: the exponent of the power function approximation captures the global progressivity of the tax system. In fact, it measures the residual income elasticity, that is, the percentage change of net income due to a percentage change in gross income. If the elasticity is smaller than one, the tax system is progressive, and if it is larger than one, it is regressive.The approximation is not only popular because it can quantify progressivity but also because it offers a very good fit to the data and is easy to estimate. The researcher only needs data on gross and net incomes. There are two ways to estimate the progressivity parameter: either directly using a nonlinear estimator or by taking the logarithm on both sides and using ordinary least squares.The latter estimation method is the most popular way to estimate the power function approximation, but it is generally biased. However, a nonlinear estimator that is equivalent to a Poisson regression gives consistent progressivity estimates. In this paper, I document the severity of this bias in several data sets and find that differences in estimates range from 6 to 14 percent. Generally, using ordinary least squares leads to an overestimation of progressivity. Further, I show that when biased progressivity estimates are used in subsequent model calculations, errors propagate and become quite severe. Finally, I offer guidance to the practitioner on how to estimate the power function approximation.The Effect of Tax Price on Donations: Evidence from CanadaRoss Hickey, Brad Minaker, A. Abigail Payne, Joanne Roberts, and Justin SmithThe tax price of a $1 donation is the after-tax cost of the donation for the donor. We estimate the tax price elasticity of giving using a large sample of Canadian tax filers from 2001 to 2016. The richness of the data allows us to control for a variety of important factors and estimate the responsiveness of Canadian households to changes in the tax treatment of donations. Canada supports charitable giving through nonrefundable tax credits, and we find take-up of these credits throughout the distribution of income. There is a kink in the credit rate schedule at $200 of donations, which makes it difficult to convincingly estimate the effect of tax credits on donations using conventional methods. We use a statistical technique from the literature to produce estimates with nice properties.We find strong evidence of responsiveness to the tax credits, estimating the tax price elasticity to be −1.9. This means that for every dollar remitted back to tax filers for their donations, donations increase by $1.90. We also estimate the responsiveness within intervals of the distribution of household income. We find strong evidence of responses throughout the distribution of income. Interestingly, the most responsive donors are at the bottom 20 percent and 21 percent–40 percent of the household income distribution. We explore whether this response is driven by donors changing their gift sizes in response to the change in tax price or by tax filers changing when to donate. We find evidence that the large responses at the bottom of the income distribution are driven by the decision to donate, while responses for the top 20 percent, top 10 percent, and top 1 percent are driven more by the decision of how much to donate.Taken together, our research shows that tax concessions for donations to charity are effective at increasing charitable giving. Our results show larger estimated effects than previously found in the literature, which we attribute to our sample including many more lower-income households with an incentive to donate.Income Guarantee Policy Design: Implications for Poverty, Income Distribution, and Tax RatesRobert Paul Hartley and Irwin GarfinkelIncome-guarantee policies featured prominently in public discourse around the 1960s, including the presidential campaigns by Richard Nixon and George McGovern as well as the writing of Nobel laureate economists Milton Friedman and James Tobin and of Nobel Peace Prize activist Martin Luther King Jr. After 50 years of the War on Poverty, guarantee designs are resurging in both the economics literature and policy proposals. The National Academies of Science have promoted a universal child allowance, which was temporarily realized as part of the American Rescue Plan in response to the COVID-19 pandemic. To inform the expected impacts on poverty, income distribution, and tax rates, this paper simulates a moderately sized $250 monthly guarantee per person financed by a fundamental tax reform that eliminates all income tax deductions and institutes proportionally higher marginal tax rates (MTRs). We assume that households may respond with changes in labor supply relative to both the guarantee benefit and the financing mechanisms. Furthermore, we consider a general framework of important questions for an income guarantee design and discuss how the major impacts would compare.For our benchmark guarantee policy, poverty would fall by about 40 percent with a 20 percent reduction in inequality between the 90th and 10th percentiles of income. Fundamental tax reform would finance 60 percent of the total cost of $948 billion, and the remaining costs could be financed by raising MTRs by 23 percent across all brackets. Under this reform, households with incomes below $200,000 would be net beneficiaries, and the top MTR would rise from 37 to 45.5 percent. Although universal, such an income guarantee would have greater relative benefits for disadvantaged groups. Children and larger families would experience the largest antipoverty effects, as would caregivers, who are often unpaid or lower income. A universal income guarantee would also reduce the Black-White poverty gap by 16 percent — more for a larger benefit size — because of disproportionate poverty rates among those racialized as Black.We explore various options for designing an income guarantee, such as generosity amount, income eligibility, interaction with means-tested transfers, and forms of income taxation. Along with fundamental tax reform, a higher income guarantee of $500 monthly per person would reduce poverty and inequality by about 70 and 35 percent, respectively, and could be financed with effective tax rates similar to those observed in the US tax code as recently as 1981. Phasing out benefits at higher incomes can meaningfully reduce inequality without diminishing poverty reduction. Reducing the program costs of a guarantee by offsetting means-tested transfers substantially limits poverty reduction impacts. We also compare a flat surtax on all taxable income as opposed to proportionally increasing MTRs, and the implications for poverty and inequality are negligible.A primary function of a guaranteed income program is the maintenance of a livable income to support families, and moderate-sized guarantees could greatly reduce poverty at tax rates consistent with those in the optimal income tax literature. Previous articleNext article DetailsFiguresReferencesCited by National Tax Journal Volume 76, Number 2June 2023 Published for: The National Tax Association Article DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1086/726079 Views: 163Total views on this site © 2023 National Tax Association. All rights reserved.PDF download Crossref reports no articles citing this article.
文章摘要
上一篇文章下一篇文章免费文章摘要添加到收藏列表下载引文跟踪引文摘要转载分享在facebook twitter linkedinredditemail打印章节零售业汇款事宜:来自自愿收款协议的证据eliz kaperamak, Tejaswi Velayudhan和Eleanor wilking要求在线零售商像实体零售商那样缴纳销售税会产生什么影响?尽管网上购买的商品一直都要缴纳与实体店类似的销售/使用税,但直到最近,缴纳这种税的责任一直落在消费者身上。鉴于在线商务日益增长的重要性以及随之而来的阻止基础侵蚀的努力,这一问题在州和联邦一级受到了相当大的关注。然而,几乎没有经验证据表明,转移汇款义务对在线和实体零售有何影响,以及谁承担了两种零售渠道之间实行平价的额外税收负担(如果有的话)。在本文中,我们研究了vca -国家与大型在线零售商之间的双边协议,以缴纳销售税-在2009年至2017年间颁布。我们将探讨如何将在线销售的销售税汇款义务转移给零售商,以实现零售商收款的预期目标,以及在线和实体店之间的平价,以及其对销售税发生率的影响。本文有两个主要贡献。首先,我们通过对在线销售有效税率的影响,记录了汇款义务变化对在线和实体市场相对吸引力的影响。我们表明,在线零售商在政策采用后立即在结账时增加销售税,这表明这些协议具有约束力、得到遵守,并且在我们的数据中是可衡量的。大型在线零售商采用VCA后,购物旅行(其中可能增加了销售税)立即增加了36%,而实体零售商则没有变化。这表明消费者使用在线零售作为逃避手段的能力发生了重大变化,因为这些大型零售商的支出约占其在线总支出的一半。此外,我们发现消费者将消费从在线渠道转移到实体店,这表明差异汇款规则给在线零售商带来了一些优势。由于大型在线零售商的vca,消费者立即减少了约20%的在线应税支出。随着时间的推移,实体家庭支出上升,甚至超过了在线支出的下降。我们的第二个贡献是记录了由于在线零售合规增加而导致的有效税收增加的发生率。我们发现,任何有效的增税都传递给了消费者,因为在VCA之后,不含税的价格没有变化,这表明他们承担了加强执法的经济负担。然而,在消费者中,我们没有发现VCA实质上改变了美国州销售税的分配负担。尽管在低收入家庭中,网上消费占收入的比例较高,但中等收入家庭倾向于将更多的消费转向实体店,而不是减少总体支出。因此,由于VCA导致的总应税支出占收入的份额的变化在不同的收入群体中没有显着变化,这表明VCA不会不成比例地影响低收入家庭。我们的研究结果有助于正在进行的在线零售商汇款销售税的政策辩论。在关于收入不平等和社会公平的辩论中,不可避免地出现了税收累进性的问题。如果边际税率超过平均税率,那么税收制度就是累进的,因此最后一美元的税负大于第一美元的税负。因此,高收入者的绝对收入和相对收入都将更高。累进税制不仅带来更平等的净收入分配,而且具有重要的激励效应:如果最后一美元比第一美元被征税更多,个人将不太愿意付出额外的努力来赚取最后一美元。因此,能够量化税收制度的累进性是很重要的。在定量经济研究中——尤其是结构经济模型中——一种量化税收累进率的方法已经变得非常流行:幂函数近似。这种近似通过带有两个参数的指数函数将总收入和净收入联系起来。这种近似使研究人员能够计算出净收入以及平均税率和边际税率。然而,它还有另一个非常有用的性质:幂函数近似的指数捕捉到了税收制度的全球累进性。 实际上,它衡量的是剩余收入弹性,即由于总收入的百分比变化而导致的净收入的百分比变化。如果弹性小于1,则税收制度是累进的,如果弹性大于1,则是累退的。这种近似方法之所以流行,不仅是因为它可以量化累进性,而且还因为它提供了非常好的数据拟合,并且易于估计。研究人员只需要毛收入和净收入的数据。进步性参数的估计有两种方法:直接使用非线性估计量或在两边取对数并使用普通最小二乘。后一种估计方法是最常用的估计幂函数近似的方法,但它通常是有偏差的。然而,等效于泊松回归的非线性估计器给出一致的渐进估计。在本文中,我在几个数据集中记录了这种偏差的严重程度,并发现估计的差异在6%到14%之间。一般来说,使用普通最小二乘会导致对累进率的高估。此外,我表明,当在随后的模型计算中使用有偏差的累进性估计时,误差会传播并变得相当严重。最后,我对如何估计幂函数近似提供了指导。税收价格对捐赠的影响:来自加拿大的证据罗斯·希基、布拉德·米纳克、a·阿比盖尔·佩恩、乔安妮·罗伯茨和贾斯汀·史密斯1美元捐赠的税收价格是捐赠者的税后捐赠成本。我们使用2001年至2016年加拿大税务申报人的大样本估计了捐赠的税收价格弹性。数据的丰富性使我们能够控制各种重要因素,并估计加拿大家庭对捐赠税收待遇变化的反应。加拿大通过不可退还的税收抵免来支持慈善捐赠,我们发现这些抵免在整个收入分配中都得到了利用。在200美元的捐赠中,有一个信贷利率安排上的问题,这使得使用传统方法难以令人信服地估计税收抵免对捐赠的影响。我们使用文献中的统计技术来产生具有良好性质的估计。我们发现了对税收抵免的强烈反应,估计税收价格弹性为- 1.9。这意味着,每向纳税申报者返还一美元的捐款,捐款就会增加1.90美元。我们还估计了家庭收入分布区间内的响应性。我们在整个收入分配中发现了强有力的证据。有趣的是,反应最积极的捐助者位于家庭收入分配的底层20%和21% - 40%。我们探讨了这种反应是由捐款人根据税收价格的变化而改变他们的捐赠规模,还是由报税人改变捐赠时间所驱动的。我们发现有证据表明,收入分配底部的大部分人的反应是由捐赠的决定驱动的,而收入最高的20%、10%和1%的人的反应更多地是由捐赠多少的决定驱动的。综上所述,我们的研究表明,慈善捐赠的税收优惠对增加慈善捐赠是有效的。我们的结果显示出比先前文献中发现的更大的估计效应,我们将其归因于我们的样本中包括了更多有捐赠动机的低收入家庭。收入保障政策设计:收入保障政策在20世纪60年代左右的公共话语中占有突出地位,包括理查德·尼克松和乔治·麦戈文的总统竞选,以及诺贝尔经济学奖得主米尔顿·弗里德曼和詹姆斯·托宾以及诺贝尔和平奖活动家马丁·路德·金的著作。担保设计在经济学文献和政策建议中都重新出现。美国国家科学院(National Academies of Science)推动了一项普遍儿童津贴,作为应对COVID-19大流行的美国救援计划的一部分,该津贴暂时实现。为了了解对贫困、收入分配和税率的预期影响,本文模拟了一个中等规模的每人每月250美元的担保,由一项基本的税收改革提供资金,该改革取消了所有所得税减免,并按比例提高了边际税率(MTRs)。我们假设家庭可能会以相对于担保收益和融资机制的劳动力供给变化来应对。此外,我们考虑了收入保障设计的重要问题的一般框架,并讨论了如何比较主要影响。 按照我们的基准保障政策,贫困人口将减少约40%,收入第90和第10百分位之间的不平等将减少20%。基本的税收改革将为9480亿美元的总成本提供60%的资金,其余的成本可以通过将所有等级的mtr提高23%来筹集。在这项改革下,收入低于20万美元的家庭将成为净受益者,最高MTR税率将从37%提高到45.5%。这种收入保障虽然是普遍的,但对处境不利的群体有更大的相对好处。儿童和大家庭将体验到最大的反贫困效果,看护人也是如此,他们通常没有报酬或收入较低。全民收入保障还会将黑人与白人之间的贫困差距缩小16%——如果福利规模更大,差距还会更小——因为黑人的贫困率不成比例。我们探讨了设计收入保证的各种选择,如慷慨金额、收入资格、与经济状况调查转移的互动以及所得税的形式。加上根本性的税收改革,人均每月500美元的更高收入保障将分别减少约70%和35%的贫困和不平等,并且可以用类似于1981年美国税法中观察到的有效税率来融资。逐步取消高收入人群的福利可以在不减少贫困的情况下有效地减少不平等。通过抵消经经济状况调查的转移支付来降低担保的项目成本,大大限制了减贫效果。我们还比较了所有应税收入的固定附加税与按比例增加的mtr,对贫困和不平等的影响可以忽略不计。保障收入计划的一个主要功能是维持可生活的收入以支持家庭,中等规模的保障可以大大减少贫困,其税率与最优所得税文献中的税率一致。上一篇文章下一篇文章详细信息数字参考文献引用《国家税务杂志》第76卷,2023年6月2日出版,出版对象:国家税务协会文章DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1086/726079浏览量:163本网站总浏览量©2023国家税务协会。Crossref报告没有引用这篇文章的文章。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。