Lobbying, Access Points, and the Protection of Human Rights in Democracies

IF 1.5 3区 社会学 Q2 INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS
Sean D. Ehrlich, Kimberly R. Frugé, Jillienne Haglund
{"title":"Lobbying, Access Points, and the Protection of Human Rights in Democracies","authors":"Sean D. Ehrlich, Kimberly R. Frugé, Jillienne Haglund","doi":"10.1080/03050629.2023.2254461","DOIUrl":null,"url":null,"abstract":"AbstractWhy do some democracies better protect human rights than other democracies? Although research shows that democracies engage in fewer human rights abuses than nondemocracies, we know less about what explains the variation in respect for rights among democracies. Using Access Point Theory, we argue that the number of points of access for interest groups in democracies leads to better protection of physical integrity rights but has weaker or no effects on worker rights. By increasing the amount of access provided to interest groups, lobbying becomes cheaper which enables human rights organizations to lobby for better rights protection but, on worker rights, also enables businesses to lobby against those protections. We examine these expectations using data on all democracies from 1980 to 2002, as well as a new latent measure of worker rights constructed using item response theory.¿Por qué algunas democracias protegen mejor los derechos humanos que otras? Aunque la investigación muestra que las democracias cometen menos abusos contra los derechos humanos que las no democracias, existe una menor cantidad de información referente a los motivos que explican la variación en el respeto de los derechos entre las democracias. Argumentamos, mediante el uso de la teoría del punto de acceso, que el número de puntos de acceso existentes para los grupos de interés en las democracias provoca una mejor protección de los derechos en materia de integridad física, pero que tiene efectos más débiles, o incluso nulos, sobre los derechos de los trabajadores. Al aumentar el grado de acceso que se proporciona a los grupos de interés, la presión política se vuelve menos onerosa, lo que permite a las organizaciones de derechos humanos presionar en favor de una mejor protección de los derechos. Sin embargo, en lo que se refiere a los derechos de los trabajadores, esto también permite a las empresas presionar contra esas protecciones. Estudiamos estas expectativas utilizando tanto datos procedentes de todas las democracias desde 1980 hasta 2002, como una nueva medida, latente, de derechos económicos que fue creada utilizando la teoría de respuesta al ítem.Pourquoi certaines démocraties protègent-elles mieux les droits de l’Homme que d’autres? Bien que la recherche montre que les démocraties présentent moins de violations des droits de l’Homme que les pays non démocratiques, nous ne savons pas très bien expliquer les variations relatives aux droits dans les démocraties. À l’aide de la théorie des points d’accès (Access Point Theory), nous affirmons que plus le nombre de points d’accès des groupes d’intérêts dans les démocraties augmente, meilleure est la protection de l’intégrité physique des droits, mais que les effets sur les droits des travailleurs sont minimes, voire inexistants. En augmentant l’accès fourni aux groupes d’intérêts, le lobbying coûte moins cher. Les organisations des droits de l’Homme peuvent donc promouvoir plus facilement la protection des droits, mais, s’agissant des droits des travailleurs, les entreprises peuvent également faire pression contre ces protections. Nous analysons ces prédictions à l’aide de données sur toutes les démocraties entre 1980 et 2002, ainsi qu’une nouvelle mesure latente des droits économiques créée à l’aide de la théorie des réponses aux items.Keywords: Access pointsdemocracyhuman rights Notes1 Figure 1 presents a box plot summarizing the PIR scores for OECD democracies from Fariss (Citation2014).2 As currently constructed, APT applies only to democracies. Future work might extend it to nondemocracies where we might expect it to have similar effects among those countries.3 Human rights violation in democracies are often described as a result of principal-agent problems where agents violate rights despite policy makers not wanting them to do so, as in Conrad and Moore (Citation2010). However, policymaking is still relevant both because democratic principals do sometimes order rights violations and because the legislature is involved in oversight of agents.4 Access points are typically created by constitutional provisions or elements of the electoral law. That these features create access points are incidental to their existence. It is unlikely that there is endogeneity between number of access points and human rights since countries’ decisions on such institutional elements are typically based on broader concerns than human rights protection.5 We assume here for simplicity that all access points are equal in power and receptivity to different interests and in different issue areas. Ehrlich (Citation2011, 40–43) discusses how APT can generalize to different levels of power and receptivity for different access points.6 An exception may exist during times of conflict where pro-national security groups may lobby for a reduction in PIR to better fight the conflict. Conrad and Moore (Citation2010) find democracies torture more during times of conflict, though they do not ascribe this to lobbying. We control for conflict in our empirical models below to take this into account. There could be another exception in multiethnic societies where racism or xenophobia might drive calls for abuses of minorities. We do not directly control for this, though, as Conrad and Moore mention, these calls will likely be more intense when a conflict with these groups exist.7 We also reconducted all of the analyses after using multiple imputation on the 1980–2000 data. Results were robust to this strategy as reported in the supplementary analyses.8 In the online appendix, we conduct many robustness checks, including using year fixed effects, accounting for uncertainty in the latent variables, and using different dependent variables, such as the component measures in the two latent variables and splitting the latent worker’s rights variable into different de jure and de facto rights. The effect of access points on PIR is robust, remaining significant in all specifications. The effect of access points on workers’ rights is more fragile and is insignificant in many of these tests, reinforcing the finding that access points has less influence on these rights.","PeriodicalId":51513,"journal":{"name":"International Interactions","volume":null,"pages":null},"PeriodicalIF":1.5000,"publicationDate":"2023-09-23","publicationTypes":"Journal Article","fieldsOfStudy":null,"isOpenAccess":false,"openAccessPdf":"","citationCount":"0","resultStr":null,"platform":"Semanticscholar","paperid":null,"PeriodicalName":"International Interactions","FirstCategoryId":"1085","ListUrlMain":"https://doi.org/10.1080/03050629.2023.2254461","RegionNum":3,"RegionCategory":"社会学","ArticlePicture":[],"TitleCN":null,"AbstractTextCN":null,"PMCID":null,"EPubDate":"","PubModel":"","JCR":"Q2","JCRName":"INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS","Score":null,"Total":0}
引用次数: 0

Abstract

AbstractWhy do some democracies better protect human rights than other democracies? Although research shows that democracies engage in fewer human rights abuses than nondemocracies, we know less about what explains the variation in respect for rights among democracies. Using Access Point Theory, we argue that the number of points of access for interest groups in democracies leads to better protection of physical integrity rights but has weaker or no effects on worker rights. By increasing the amount of access provided to interest groups, lobbying becomes cheaper which enables human rights organizations to lobby for better rights protection but, on worker rights, also enables businesses to lobby against those protections. We examine these expectations using data on all democracies from 1980 to 2002, as well as a new latent measure of worker rights constructed using item response theory.¿Por qué algunas democracias protegen mejor los derechos humanos que otras? Aunque la investigación muestra que las democracias cometen menos abusos contra los derechos humanos que las no democracias, existe una menor cantidad de información referente a los motivos que explican la variación en el respeto de los derechos entre las democracias. Argumentamos, mediante el uso de la teoría del punto de acceso, que el número de puntos de acceso existentes para los grupos de interés en las democracias provoca una mejor protección de los derechos en materia de integridad física, pero que tiene efectos más débiles, o incluso nulos, sobre los derechos de los trabajadores. Al aumentar el grado de acceso que se proporciona a los grupos de interés, la presión política se vuelve menos onerosa, lo que permite a las organizaciones de derechos humanos presionar en favor de una mejor protección de los derechos. Sin embargo, en lo que se refiere a los derechos de los trabajadores, esto también permite a las empresas presionar contra esas protecciones. Estudiamos estas expectativas utilizando tanto datos procedentes de todas las democracias desde 1980 hasta 2002, como una nueva medida, latente, de derechos económicos que fue creada utilizando la teoría de respuesta al ítem.Pourquoi certaines démocraties protègent-elles mieux les droits de l’Homme que d’autres? Bien que la recherche montre que les démocraties présentent moins de violations des droits de l’Homme que les pays non démocratiques, nous ne savons pas très bien expliquer les variations relatives aux droits dans les démocraties. À l’aide de la théorie des points d’accès (Access Point Theory), nous affirmons que plus le nombre de points d’accès des groupes d’intérêts dans les démocraties augmente, meilleure est la protection de l’intégrité physique des droits, mais que les effets sur les droits des travailleurs sont minimes, voire inexistants. En augmentant l’accès fourni aux groupes d’intérêts, le lobbying coûte moins cher. Les organisations des droits de l’Homme peuvent donc promouvoir plus facilement la protection des droits, mais, s’agissant des droits des travailleurs, les entreprises peuvent également faire pression contre ces protections. Nous analysons ces prédictions à l’aide de données sur toutes les démocraties entre 1980 et 2002, ainsi qu’une nouvelle mesure latente des droits économiques créée à l’aide de la théorie des réponses aux items.Keywords: Access pointsdemocracyhuman rights Notes1 Figure 1 presents a box plot summarizing the PIR scores for OECD democracies from Fariss (Citation2014).2 As currently constructed, APT applies only to democracies. Future work might extend it to nondemocracies where we might expect it to have similar effects among those countries.3 Human rights violation in democracies are often described as a result of principal-agent problems where agents violate rights despite policy makers not wanting them to do so, as in Conrad and Moore (Citation2010). However, policymaking is still relevant both because democratic principals do sometimes order rights violations and because the legislature is involved in oversight of agents.4 Access points are typically created by constitutional provisions or elements of the electoral law. That these features create access points are incidental to their existence. It is unlikely that there is endogeneity between number of access points and human rights since countries’ decisions on such institutional elements are typically based on broader concerns than human rights protection.5 We assume here for simplicity that all access points are equal in power and receptivity to different interests and in different issue areas. Ehrlich (Citation2011, 40–43) discusses how APT can generalize to different levels of power and receptivity for different access points.6 An exception may exist during times of conflict where pro-national security groups may lobby for a reduction in PIR to better fight the conflict. Conrad and Moore (Citation2010) find democracies torture more during times of conflict, though they do not ascribe this to lobbying. We control for conflict in our empirical models below to take this into account. There could be another exception in multiethnic societies where racism or xenophobia might drive calls for abuses of minorities. We do not directly control for this, though, as Conrad and Moore mention, these calls will likely be more intense when a conflict with these groups exist.7 We also reconducted all of the analyses after using multiple imputation on the 1980–2000 data. Results were robust to this strategy as reported in the supplementary analyses.8 In the online appendix, we conduct many robustness checks, including using year fixed effects, accounting for uncertainty in the latent variables, and using different dependent variables, such as the component measures in the two latent variables and splitting the latent worker’s rights variable into different de jure and de facto rights. The effect of access points on PIR is robust, remaining significant in all specifications. The effect of access points on workers’ rights is more fragile and is insignificant in many of these tests, reinforcing the finding that access points has less influence on these rights.
游说、访问点和民主国家的人权保护
康拉德和摩尔(Citation2010)发现,民主国家在冲突时期的折磨更多,尽管他们不认为这是游说造成的。我们在下面的经验模型中控制冲突以考虑到这一点。在多民族社会中可能有另一个例外,种族主义或仇外心理可能促使人们呼吁虐待少数民族。我们不能直接控制这一点,但是,正如康拉德和摩尔所提到的,当与这些群体存在冲突时,这些呼叫可能会更加激烈在对1980-2000年的数据进行多次代入后,我们也重新进行了所有的分析。在补充分析中报告了这一策略的结果在在线附录中,我们进行了许多稳健性检查,包括使用年份固定效应,考虑潜在变量的不确定性,以及使用不同的因变量,例如两个潜在变量中的成分度量,以及将潜在的工人权利变量拆分为不同的法律权利和事实权利。接入点对PIR的影响是稳健的,在所有规范中都保持显著。接入点对工人权利的影响较为脆弱,在许多此类测试中无足轻重,这进一步证实了接入点对这些权利的影响较小的结论。
本文章由计算机程序翻译,如有差异,请以英文原文为准。
求助全文
约1分钟内获得全文 求助全文
来源期刊
International Interactions
International Interactions INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS-
CiteScore
2.40
自引率
7.70%
发文量
38
期刊介绍: International Interactions is a leading interdisciplinary journal that publishes original empirical, analytic, and theoretical studies of conflict and political economy. The journal has a particular interest in research that focuses upon the broad range of relations and interactions among the actors in the global system. Relevant topics include ethnic and religious conflict, interstate and intrastate conflict, conflict resolution, conflict management, economic development, regional integration, trade relations, institutions, globalization, terrorism, and geopolitical analyses.
×
引用
GB/T 7714-2015
复制
MLA
复制
APA
复制
导出至
BibTeX EndNote RefMan NoteFirst NoteExpress
×
提示
您的信息不完整,为了账户安全,请先补充。
现在去补充
×
提示
您因"违规操作"
具体请查看互助需知
我知道了
×
提示
确定
请完成安全验证×
copy
已复制链接
快去分享给好友吧!
我知道了
右上角分享
点击右上角分享
0
联系我们:info@booksci.cn Book学术提供免费学术资源搜索服务,方便国内外学者检索中英文文献。致力于提供最便捷和优质的服务体验。 Copyright © 2023 布克学术 All rights reserved.
京ICP备2023020795号-1
ghs 京公网安备 11010802042870号
Book学术文献互助
Book学术文献互助群
群 号:481959085
Book学术官方微信